Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme?

Similar documents
Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme?

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Oil price and macroeconomy in Russia. Abstract

Inference in VARs with Conditional Heteroskedasticity of Unknown Form

Shortfalls of Panel Unit Root Testing. Jack Strauss Saint Louis University. And. Taner Yigit Bilkent University. Abstract

Cross-regional Spillover Effects in the Korean Housing Market

Identifying SVARs with Sign Restrictions and Heteroskedasticity

The PPP Hypothesis Revisited

Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions

Computational Macroeconomics. Prof. Dr. Maik Wolters Friedrich Schiller University Jena

APPLIED TIME SERIES ECONOMETRICS

DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS

ECON 4160, Autumn term 2017 Lecture 9

Bias Correction and Out of Sample Forecast Accuracy

TOPICS IN ADVANCED ECONOMETRICS: SVAR MODELS PART I LESSON 2. Luca Fanelli. University of Bologna.

A Non-Parametric Approach of Heteroskedasticity Robust Estimation of Vector-Autoregressive (VAR) Models

A Comparison of Business Cycle Regime Nowcasting Performance between Real-time and Revised Data. By Arabinda Basistha (West Virginia University)

Research Statement. Zhongwen Liang

Forecasting Levels of log Variables in Vector Autoregressions

Labor-Supply Shifts and Economic Fluctuations. Technical Appendix

New Information Response Functions

The Price Puzzle: Mixing the Temporary and Permanent Monetary Policy Shocks.

When Do Wold Orderings and Long-Run Recursive Identifying Restrictions Yield Identical Results?

Finite Sample Properties of Impulse Response Intervals in SVECMs with Long-Run Identifying Restrictions

Structural Vector Autoregressions with Markov Switching. Markku Lanne University of Helsinki. Helmut Lütkepohl European University Institute, Florence

Are PPP Tests Erratically Behaved? Some Panel Evidence

Time Series Analysis for Macroeconomics and Finance

SHSU ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER

Shyh-Wei Chen Department of Finance, Dayeh University. Abstract

Bayesian Graphical Models for Structural Vector AutoregressiveMarch Processes 21, / 1

International Monetary Policy Spillovers

Long- versus Medium-Run Identification in Fractionally Integrated VAR Models

Foreign and Domestic Growth Drivers in Eastern Europe

1. Shocks. This version: February 15, Nr. 1

Macroeconometric Modelling

Discussion of Bootstrap prediction intervals for linear, nonlinear, and nonparametric autoregressions, by Li Pan and Dimitris Politis

Introduction to Macroeconomics

A Theory of Data-Oriented Identification with a SVAR Application

MFx Macroeconomic Forecasting

TRINITY COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER 15-08

Vector autoregressions, VAR

Vector Autoregression Analysis: Estimation and Interpretation

A. Recursively orthogonalized. VARs

Permanent and Transitory Components of GDP and Stock Prices: Further Analysis

Stock Prices, News, and Economic Fluctuations: Comment

Dynastic Altruism, Population Growth, and Economic Prosperity

Identification of Economic Shocks by Inequality Constraints in Bayesian Structural Vector Autoregression

ARDL Cointegration Tests for Beginner

Joint Confidence Sets for Structural Impulse Responses

A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED

Examining the Evidence for Purchasing Power Parity Under the. Current Float by Recursive Mean Adjustment

ERC Working Papers in Economics 01/05 November Dynamics of the Trade Balance: The Turkish J-Curve

Multivariate forecasting with VAR models

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING

Nonperforming Loans and Rules of Monetary Policy

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Structural Inference With. Long-run Recursive Empirical Models

Multivariate Time Series Analysis and Its Applications [Tsay (2005), chapter 8]

Financial Econometrics

Nonlinear Relation of Inflation and Nominal Interest Rates A Local Nonparametric Investigation

Inflation Revisited: New Evidence from Modified Unit Root Tests

Applied Econometrics and International Development Vol.9-1 (2009)

Markov-Switching Models with Endogenous Explanatory Variables. Chang-Jin Kim 1

Financial Econometrics

A primer on Structural VARs

Unit Roots, Nonlinear Cointegration and Purchasing Power Parity

Identifying Monetary Policy Shocks via Changes in Volatility 1

Identifying Aggregate Liquidity Shocks with Monetary Policy Shocks: An Application using UK Data

Stargazing with Structural VARs: Shock Identification via Independent Component Analysis

The profit function system with output- and input- specific technical efficiency

Volume 29, Issue 1. On the Importance of Span of the Data in Univariate Estimation of the Persistence in Real Exchange Rates

1 Teaching notes on structural VARs.

Title. Description. var intro Introduction to vector autoregressive models

The Geometric Meaning of the Notion of Joint Unpredictability of a Bivariate VAR(1) Stochastic Process

Purchasing power parity over two centuries: strengthening the case for real exchange rate stability A reply to Cuddington and Liang

IDENTIFICATION OF THE EQUILIBRIUM EXCHANGE RATE PASS-THROUGH EFFECT IN COINTEGRATED VAR WITH AN APPLICATION TO THE EURO AREA*

EUI Working Papers DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECO 2009/24 DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS FORECASTING LEVELS OF LOG VARIABLES IN VECTOR AUTOREGRESSIONS

News Shocks: Different Effects in Boom and Recession?

Structural VAR Models and Applications

Do Long Run Restrictions Identify Supply and Demand Disturbances?

Asymmetric Exchange Rate Pass-through: Evidence from Nonlinear SVARs

Unit Roots and Structural Breaks in Panels: Does the Model Specification Matter?

Using all observations when forecasting under structural breaks

Estimates of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve for the USA with the General to Specific Method

ECON 4160: Econometrics-Modelling and Systems Estimation Lecture 9: Multiple equation models II

International Symposium on Mathematical Sciences & Computing Research (ismsc) 2015 (ismsc 15)

Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo

The Contribution of Growth and Interest Rate Differentials to the Persistence of Real Exchange Rates

growth in a time of debt evidence from the uk

Are the Responses of the U.S. Economy Asymmetric in Energy Price Increases and Decreases?

Factor models. March 13, 2017

Gold Rush Fever in Business Cycles

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 4. VARs With Long-Run Restrictions

Identification in Structural VAR models with different volatility regimes

Are US Output Expectations Unbiased? A Cointegrated VAR Analysis in Real Time

1. Introduction. Hang Qian 1 Iowa State University

Lecture 4: Bayesian VAR

Financial Factors in Economic Fluctuations. Lawrence Christiano Roberto Motto Massimo Rostagno

B y t = γ 0 + Γ 1 y t + ε t B(L) y t = γ 0 + ε t ε t iid (0, D) D is diagonal

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA

Transcription:

Auburn University Department of Economics Working Paper Series Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme? Hyeongwoo Kim Auburn University AUWP 2012-04 This paper can be downloaded without charge from: http://cla.auburn.edu/econwp/ http://econpapers.repec.org/paper/abnwpaper/

Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme? Hyeongwoo Kim Auburn University July 2012 Abstract This note discusses a pitfall of using the generalized impulse response function (GIRF) in vector autoregressive (VAR) models (Pesaran and Shin, 1998). The GIRF is general because it is invariant to the ordering of the variables in the VAR. The GIRF, in fact, is extreme because it yields a set of response functions that are based on extreme identifying assumptions that contradict each other, unless the covariance matrix is diagonal. With a help of empirical examples, the present note demonstrates that the GIRF may yield quite misleading economic inferences. Keywords: Generalized Impulse Response Function; Orthogonalized Impulse Response Function; Vector Autoregressive Models JEL Classification: C13; C32; C51 A thank goes to Michael Stern for helpful comments. Madeline Kim provided excellent research assistance. Department of Economics, Auburn University, Auburn, AL 36849. Tel: 334-844-2928. Fax: 334-844-4615. Email: gmmkim@gmail.com 1

1 Introduction Notwithstanding its popularity, the orthogonalized impulse response function (OIRF; Sims, 1980) analysis of structural vector autoregressive (VAR) models is subject to the so-called Wold-ordering problem. 1 That is, when one changes the order of the VAR with an alternative identifying assumption, she may obtain dramatically different response functions (Lütkepohl, 1991). Pesaran and Shin (1998) propose the generalized impulse response function (GIRF), an orderinginvariant approach, based on the work of Koop et al. (1996). The GIRF has been employed by many researchers: Boyd et al. (2001), Cheung et al. (2004), and Huang et al. (2008), to name a few. This note shows, however, that the GIRF may results in misleading inferences caused by its extreme identification schemes. The remainder of this note is organized as follows. Section 2 analytically demonstrates why the GIRF actually can be considered extreme in perspective of its identification method. In Section 3, I provide two empirical examples that highlights substantial differences between the GIRF and the OIRF. Section 4 concludes. 2 A Pitfall of the GIRF This section provides a simple analytical explanation on a pitfall in using the GIRF, which demonstrates potentially serious problems of using the GIRF. Let ( ) and ( ) denote the GIRF and the OIRF at time +, respectively, when there is one standard error shock at time to the th variable in an -variate VAR with y = [ 1 2 ] 0. Pesaran and Shin s (1998) Proposition 3.1 implies 1 ( ) = 1 ( ). 2 Define ( ) as the OIRF when is ordered first in y.byconstruction, 1 ( ) = 1 ( ). Nowre-order the vector so that y =[ 2 1 3 ] 0,whichyields 2 ( ) = 2 ( ) by the proposition 1 The OIRF recursively identifies the structural shocks by using the Choleski decomposition factor of the covariance matrix, which yields a unique lower triangular matrix. This scheme, therefore, assumes that the variable ordered first in the VAR is contemporaneously unaffected by all other variables. 2 That is, the GIRF and the OIRF coincide for the shock to the first variable in y. 2

and because the GIRF is invariant to the ordering of the variables in y. Repeat this procedure until we get ( ) = ( ). Collecting these response functions, the GIRF for the entire system is, ( ) = n 1 ( ) o 2 ( ) ( ) The GIRF, therefore, is not general in effect because it employs extreme identifying assumptions that each variable is ordered first. More seriously, ( ) and ( ) are not consistent with each other when 6= unless the covariance matrix is diagonal. For instance, ( ) assumes that is not contemporaneously affected by all other variables including,while ( ) needs an assumption that is not contemporaneously affected by all other variables including. 3 Hence, the GIRFs conflict each other. This result also trivially applies to vector error correction models. In the next section, I show that such inconsistency may lead to misleading economic inferences. 3 Empirical Examples This section provides empirical illustration to compare the implications of the GIRF with those of the OIRF. I first use a quadvariate VAR model of the US per capita investment ( ), consumption ( ), real GDP ( ), and the government expenditure share ( ) relative to the real GDP, measured in logarithms. The data frequency is quarterly and the observations span from 1948Q1 to 2008Q4, obtained from the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis FRED data base. I report the ordering-free GIRF and the OIRF with an ordering [ ] to a government expenditure shock in Figure 1. 4 Both response functions display a decrease in, whichmaybe consistent with the crowding-out effect. However, responses of and exhibit noticeably different dynamic adjustments. For example, the GIRF implies a significant decrease in at the 5% level over a year, while the OIRF implies significantly positive responses of for about a year. Since 3 If it is diagonal, there is no gain of using a structural VAR model, because it coincides with a reduced-form VAR, in other words, equation-by-equation least squares estimations. 4 95% confidence bands are obtained from 5,000 nonparametric bootstrap simulations. 3

includes not only private but also public sector outputs, it is surprising to see a substantial decreases in in the short-run as we seen from the GIRF. 5 Similarly, the GIRF implies a significant decrease in for about a year, while the OIRF displays slow positive adjustments of which are insignificant. Figure 1 about here I implement another example to better understand why there may be such differences between thegirfandtheoirf.forthis,iuseatrivariatevarmodelof,, and from the previous exercise, which was also employed by Pesaran and Shin (1998). Note that the GIRFs to (one standard error) investment shock (Panel 2-a in Figure 2) coincide with the OIRFs to an -shock when is assumed to be contemporaneously unaffected by other two variables, and (Panel 2-b). Note also that under this assumption, the OIRFs to a -shock are very different from the corresponding GIRFs. However, the GIRFs to a -shock are identical to the OIRFs when is ordered first in the VAR (Panel 2-d) by construction. Again, the other OIRFs under that assumption are quite different from the corresponding GIRFs. Likewise, the GIRFs to a -shock are identical only to the OIRFs to a -shock when is ordered first (Panel 2-c). Basedonthesefindings, it seems important to estimate and report response functions based on the underlying economic model. For example, if one interprets -shocks as an output (supply) shock, while -shocks and -shocks are treated as expenditure (demand) shocks, she may employ an ordering [ ] assuming that does not contemporaneously respond to demand shocks. Then, she will report the response functions to an -shock, for instance, that are very different from the GIRFs both quantitatively and qualitatively. If one believes that is primarily driven by animal spirit, shemayemploy[ ] instead and report quite smaller responses of to a -shock than the corresponding GIRF. Figure 2 about here 5 For this, private sector activities should decrease by more than an increase in the increases in the public sector. 4

4 Conclusion This note points out that there is a pitfall in using the GIRF. Economic inferences based on the GIRF can be misleading because the GIRF employs a set of extreme identifying assumptions that contradict each other unless the covariance matrix is diagonal. Our empirical example demonstrates that this is by no means a negligible matter. In such cases, it would be more reasonable to use identifying assumptions that consistently describes the underlying economic model. 5

References 1. Boyd, Derick, Gugielmo M. Caporale, Ron Smith (2001), "Real Exchange Rate Effects on the Balance of Trade: Cointegration and the Marshall-Lerner Condition," International Journal of Finance and Economics 6, 187 200. 2. Cheung, Yin-Wong, Kon S. Lai, and Michael Bergman (2004), "Dissecting the PPP Puzzle: The Unconventional Roles of Nominal Exchange Rate and Price Adjustments," Journal of International Economics 64, 135-150. 3. Huang, Ying, Salih N. Neftci, and Feng Guo (2008), "Swap Curve Dynamics Across Markets: Case of US Dollar versus HK Dollar," Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions, and Money 18, 79-93. 4. Koop, Gary, M. Hashem Pesaran, and Simon Potter (1996), "Impulse Response Analysis in Nonlinear Multivariate Models," Journal of Econometrics 74, 119-147. 5. Lütkephol, Helmut (1991), Introduction to Multiple Time Series Analysis, Springer-Verlag, Berlin, Germany. 6. Pesaran, M. Hashem and Yongcheol Shin (1998), "Generalized Impulse Response Analysis in Linear Multivariate Models," Economics Letters 58, 17-29., 7. Sims, Christopher (1980), "Macroeconomics and Reality," Econometrica 48, 1-48. 6

Firgue 1. Response Functions to a Government Share Shock Note: Solid lines are point estimates. Dashed lines are 95% nonparametric confidence bands from 5,000 bootstrap simulations. 7

Firgue 2. Further Comparisons of Impulse Response Functions 8