Formulating, Estimating, and Solving Dynamic Equilibrium Models: an Introduction. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Similar documents
Lars Svensson 2/16/06. Y t = Y. (1) Assume exogenous constant government consumption (determined by government), G t = G<Y. (2)

Lecture 1: Information and Structural VARs

Structural VARs II. February 17, 2016

1.2. Structural VARs

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions

Identifying SVARs with Sign Restrictions and Heteroskedasticity

Matching DSGE models,vars, and state space models. Fabio Canova EUI and CEPR September 2012

Are Structural VARs Useful Guides for Developing Business Cycle Theories? by Larry Christiano

Computational Macroeconomics. Prof. Dr. Maik Wolters Friedrich Schiller University Jena

1 Teaching notes on structural VARs.

A primer on Structural VARs

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

Quarterly Journal of Economics and Modelling Shahid Beheshti University SVAR * SVAR * **

1 Teaching notes on structural VARs.

Assessing Structural VAR s

Study of Causal Relationships in Macroeconomics

Vector Autoregressions as a Guide to Constructing Dynamic General Equilibrium Models

A Primer on Vector Autoregressions

Lecture on State Dependent Government Spending Multipliers

Assessing Structural VAR s

Bonn Summer School Advances in Empirical Macroeconomics

When Do Wold Orderings and Long-Run Recursive Identifying Restrictions Yield Identical Results?

MFx Macroeconomic Forecasting

Chapter 5. Structural Vector Autoregression

Modern Macroeconomics and Regional Economic Modeling

Introduction to Macroeconomics

Shrinkage in Set-Identified SVARs

Estimating Macroeconomic Models: A Likelihood Approach

MSc Time Series Econometrics

Assessing Structural VAR s

ECON 4160: Econometrics-Modelling and Systems Estimation Lecture 9: Multiple equation models II

Assessing Structural VAR s

LECTURE 3 The Effects of Monetary Changes: Statistical Identification. September 5, 2018

Whither News Shocks?

Identification in Structural VAR models with different volatility regimes

Stargazing with Structural VARs: Shock Identification via Independent Component Analysis

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP Measuring monetary policy deviations from the Taylor rule

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 4. VARs With Long-Run Restrictions

Nonperforming Loans and Rules of Monetary Policy

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA

Macroeconomics Theory II

Assessing Structural VAR s

Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo

Inference Based on SVARs Identified with Sign and Zero Restrictions: Theory and Applications

Animal Spirits, Fundamental Factors and Business Cycle Fluctuations

Comment on Gali and Rabanal s Technology Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations: HowWellDoestheRBCModelFitPostwarU.S.Data?

A. Recursively orthogonalized. VARs

The Econometrics of Monetary Policy: an Overview

Dynamic Factor Models and Factor Augmented Vector Autoregressions. Lawrence J. Christiano

Y t = log (employment t )

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

Disentangling Demand and Supply Shocks in the Crude Oil Market: How to Check Sign Restrictions in Structural VARs

Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Shocks in Brazil: Sign Restrictions versus a New Hybrid Identification Approach *

Bonn Summer School Advances in Empirical Macroeconomics

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1 Solutions. Problem I An AD-AS Model

A framework for monetary-policy analysis Overview Basic concepts: Goals, targets, intermediate targets, indicators, operating targets, instruments

Identifying Aggregate Liquidity Shocks with Monetary Policy Shocks: An Application using UK Data

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics

Gaussian Mixture Approximations of Impulse Responses and the Non-Linear Effects of Monetary Shocks

Structural VAR Models and Applications

Do Long Run Restrictions Identify Supply and Demand Disturbances?

Structural Vector Autoregressions with Markov Switching. Markku Lanne University of Helsinki. Helmut Lütkepohl European University Institute, Florence

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case.

Evaluating FAVAR with Time-Varying Parameters and Stochastic Volatility

MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model

Inference Based on SVARs Identified with Sign and Zero Restrictions: Theory and Applications

The Price Puzzle: Mixing the Temporary and Permanent Monetary Policy Shocks.

Assessing Structural Convergence between Romanian Economy and Euro Area: A Bayesian Approach

Inference about Non- Identified SVARs

Evaluating Structural Vector Autoregression Models in Monetary Economies

Macroeconomics Theory II

COMMENT ON DEL NEGRO, SCHORFHEIDE, SMETS AND WOUTERS COMMENT ON DEL NEGRO, SCHORFHEIDE, SMETS AND WOUTERS

News, Noise, and Fluctuations: An Empirical Exploration

Economic and VAR Shocks: What Can Go Wrong?

Inference when identifying assumptions are doubted. A. Theory B. Applications

Factor models. March 13, 2017

Inference when identifying assumptions are doubted. A. Theory. Structural model of interest: B 1 y t1. u t. B m y tm. u t i.i.d.

An Anatomy of the Business Cycle Data

Key classical macroeconomic hypotheses specify that permanent

Are Policy Counterfactuals Based on Structural VARs Reliable?

DSGE Model Restrictions for Structural VAR Identification

Robust Bayes Inference for Non-Identified SVARs

Inflation traps, and rules vs. discretion

BEAR 4.2. Introducing Stochastic Volatility, Time Varying Parameters and Time Varying Trends. A. Dieppe R. Legrand B. van Roye ECB.

New meeting times for Econ 210D Mondays 8:00-9:20 a.m. in Econ 300 Wednesdays 11:00-12:20 in Econ 300

Identification of Economic Shocks by Inequality Constraints in Bayesian Structural Vector Autoregression

Time Series Analysis for Macroeconomics and Finance

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Monetary Models with Nominal Rigidities. Jordi Galí Universitat Pompeu Fabra April 2018

Structural Inference With. Long-run Recursive Empirical Models

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018

Identifying Monetary Policy Shocks via Changes in Volatility 1

VARs and factors. Lecture to Bristol MSc Time Series, Spring 2014 Tony Yates

Lecture 4: Bayesian VAR

Estimating and Accounting for the Output Gap with Large Bayesian Vector Autoregressions

On the maximum and minimum response to an impulse in Svars

Class 4: VAR. Macroeconometrics - Fall October 11, Jacek Suda, Banque de France

A Theory of Data-Oriented Identification with a SVAR Application

Solution Methods. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde. University of Pennsylvania. March 16, 2016

Transcription:

Formulating, Estimating, and Solving Dynamic Equilibrium Models: an Introduction Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania 1

Models Tradition in macroeconomics of using models: 1. Policy Analysis. 2. Forecasting. 3. Counterfactuals. This course reviews the recent advances in macroeconometric modelbuilding. 2

Why Models? Organize our thinking. Reproducibility. Accumulation of capital within organizations. Ex-ante versus ex-post analysis. Counterfactuals. New circumstances. 3

A Brief History of Macroeconometric Models: A Promising Beginning Old idea of economists: Quesnay, Walras. Pioneers: Tinbergen (1939, Noble Prize 1969), Haavelmo (1943, Noble Prize 1989). Klein-Goldberger model (1955). Big models of the 1960s: Brookings, MIT-FRB-Penn, Wharton. 4

A Brief History of Macroeconometric Models: Disappointment 1970s and 1980s were the decades of disappointment Problems: 1. Fit (Nelson, 1972). 2. Nonstationarity (Granger, 1981). 3. Economic Foundations (Lucas, 1972). 5

A Brief History of Macroeconometric Models: Renewed Hopes 1980s: Real Business Cycle theory: advances and difficulties. Late 1990s, early 2000s: revival. Why? 1. Advances in economic theory: second generation equilibrium models. 2. Advances in econometrics: simulation methods. 6

Why Dynamic Equilibrium Models? Explicit microeconomic foundation. Robust to Lucas critique. Welfare analysis. Design of optimal policy. 7

A Brief History of Macroeconometric Models: References R.G. Bodking, L.R. Klein, and K. Marwah: A History of Macroeconometric Model-Building, Edward Elgar, 1991. T.J. Sargent: Expectations and the Nonneutrality of Lucas, Journal of Monetary Economics, 1996. 8

WhyMonetaryModels? Is price stability a good idea? If so, at what price? How do we implement monetary policy? Does monetary policy have a role in stock market booms/busts? What do we in the wake of a monetary crisis? Why did inflation take off during the 1970s? Was the Great Depression caused by bad monetary policy? 9

Is Money Important? At a basic level yes. Lenin is said to have declared that the best way to destroy the Capitalist System was to debauch its currency... Lenin was certainly right. J.M. Keynes (1919), The Economic Consequences of the Peace. Experiences of hyperinflation. 10

Money and the Business Cycle At a more moderate level, the question is surprisingly difficult to answer. Two observations : 1. Relation between Output and Money growth. 2. Phillips Curve. Where do these observations come? 11

Conventional Wisdom Old tradition in economics: Hume, Of Money, 1752. Friedman and Schwartz, A Monetary History of the US, 1963. Volcker s recessions. Evidence from Structural Vector Autoregressions. 12

Structural Vector Autoregression SVARs have become a common tool among economists. Introduced by Sims (1980) SVARs make explicit identifying assumptions to isolate estimates of policy and/or private agents behavior and its effects on the economy, while keeping the model free of the many additional restrictive assumptions needed to give every parameter a behavioral interpretation. 13

Uses of SVARs 1. The effects of money on output (Sims and Zha, 2005). 2. The relative importance of supply and demand shocks on output (Blanchard and Quah, 1989), 3. The effects of fiscal policy (Rotemberg and Woodford, 1992). 4. The relation between technology shocks and hours (Gaĺı, 1999). 14

Economic Theory and the SVAR Representation Dynamic economic models can be viewed as restrictions on stochastic processes. An economic theory is a mapping between a vector of k economic shocks w t and a vector of n observables y t of the form y t = D ³ w t Interpretation. 15

Mapping The mapping D ( ) is the product of the equilibrium behavior of the agents in the model, implied by their optimal decision rules and the consistency conditions like resource constraints and market clearing. The construction of the mapping D ( ) is the sense in which economic theory tightly relates shocks and observables. The mapping D ( ) can be interpreted as the impulse response of the model to an economic shock. 16

A Linear Mapping We restrict our attention to linear mappings of the form: where L is the lag operator. y t = D (L) w t w t N (0, Σ). More involved structures? 17

Invertibility If k = n, i.e., we have as many economic shocks as observables, and D (L) has all its roots outside the unit circle, we can invert the mapping D (L) (Fernández-Villaverde, Rubio-Ramírez, and Sargent, 2005). Meaning of invertibility. Example of non-invertibility: y t = w t +2w t 1 18

SVAR Representation We obtain: A (L) y t = w t where A (L) =A 0 Σ k=1 A kl k is a one-sided matrix lag polynomial that embodies all the (usually non-linear) cross-equation restrictions derived by the equilibrium solution of the model. In general, A (L) isofinfinite order. This representation is known as the SVAR representation. 19

Reduced Form Representation Consider now the case where a researcher does not have access to the SVAR representation. Instead, she has access to the VAR representation of y t : y t = B 1 y t 1 + B 2 y t 2 +... + a t, where Ey t j a t =0forallj and Ea t a 0 t = Ω. This representation is known as the Reduced form representation. Can the researcher recover the SVAR representation using the Reduced form representation? 20

Identification by Theory I Fernández-Villaverde, Rubio-Ramírez, and Sargent (2005) show that, given a strictly invertible economic model, there is one and only one identification scheme to recover the SVAR from the reduced form. In addition, a t = A 1 0 w t. Hence, if we knew A 1 0, we could recover the SVAR representation from the reduced from representation noticing that A j = A 0 B j for all j and w t = A 0 a t. 21

Identification by Theory II Fernández-Villaverde, Rubio-Ramírez, and Sargent s identification requires the specification of an explicit dynamic economic model. Can we avoid this step? Unfortunately, the answer is in general no, because knowledge of the reduced form matrices B i s and Ω does not imply, by itself, knowledge of the A i s and Σ. Why: normalization and identification. 22

Normalization Reversing the signs of two rows or columns of the A i s does not matter for the B i s. Thus, without the correct normalization restrictions, statistical inference about the A i s is essentially meaningless. Waggoner and Zha (2003) provide a general normalization rule that maintains coherent economic interpretations. 23

Identification I If we knew A 0, each equation B i = A 1 0 A i would determine A i given some B i. But in Ω = A 0 ΣA 0 0 we n (3n +1)/2 unknowns (the n2 distinct elements of A 0 and the n (n +1)/2 distinct elements of Σ) forn 2 knows (the n (n +1)/2 distinctelementsofω). Thus,werequiren 2 identification restrictions. 24

Identification II Since can set the diagonal elements of A 0 equal to 1 by scaling, we are left with the need of n (n 1) additional identification restrictions. Alternatively, we could scale the shocks such that the diagonal of Σ is composed of ones and leave the diagonal of A 0 unrestricted. These identification restrictions are dictated by the economic theory being studied. 25

Identification III What about identification restrictions compatible with a large class of models? Robustness versus efficiency. Discussion of trade-off. 26

Identification IV Most common identification restrictions: Σ is diagonal. Why? Since this assumption imposes n (n 1) /2 restrictions, we still require n (n 1) /2 additional restrictions. 27

Short-Run Identification I Sims (1980) pioneered the first approach when he proposed to impose zeroes on A 0. Why? Natural timing in the effect of economic shocks. Example: we can use the intuition that monetary policy cannot respond contemporaneously to a shock in the price level because of informational delays to place a zero on A 0. Similarly, institutional constraints, like the timing of tax collections, can be exploited for identification (Blanchard and Perotti, 2002). 28

Short-Run Identification II Sims (1980) ordered variables in such a way that A 0 is lower triangular. Sims and Zha (2005) present a non-triangular, identification scheme on an eight-variable SVAR. We will come back to Sims and Zha (2005). 29

Long-Run Identification I Blanchard and Quah (1989). Restriction imposed on A (1) = A 0 Σ k=1 A k. Since A 1 (1) = D (1), long-run restrictions are restrictions on the long-run effects of economic shocks, usually on the first difference of an observable. 30

Long-Run Identification II Blanchard and Quah (1989): demand shock has no effect long-run effect on unemployment or output while supply shock has no long-run on unemployment, but may have a long-run effect on output. Gaĺı (1999): technology shocks has no effect long-run effect on hours and but it has on productivity. 31

New Identification Schemes Uhlig (2005): sign restrictions. Identifies a contractionary monetary policy shock as one that does not lead to an increase in prices or in nonborrowed reserves and does not lead to a decrease in the federal funds rate. Faust, Swanson, and Wright (2004) identify the effects if a monetary shock in a SVAR using the prices of federal funds futures contracts. 32

Estimable Equation Why is the previous discussion of the relation between the reduced and structural form of a VAR relevant? Because the reduced form can be easily estimated. An empirically implementable version of the reduced form representation truncates the number of lags at the p-th order: where Ea t a 0 t = Ω. y t = B 1 y t 1 +... + B py t p + a t 33

Effects of Truncation Bad: Chari, Kehoe, McGrattan (2005). Not too bad: Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Vigfusson (2005). Problems with infinite dimensional estimation: 1997). Faust and Leeper, 34

Estimation Classical: GMM, ML, OLS. Bayesian. Why Bayesian? Overparametrization and priors. We will talk about these issues later. 35

Estimation Point estimates B i for i =1,.., p and Ω Then, we find estimates of A i and Σ by solving Bi i =1,...,p,andΩ = A 0 ΣA 0 0. = A 1 i A i for Finally, w t = A 0 a t. 36

An Example: Sims and Zha (2005) A simple, model-based SVAR. U.S. Quarterly Data 1964-1994. 8variables. We will need at least (8 7) /2 = 28 identification restrictions. 37

Variables R: federal funds rate. M: M2. Py: GNP deflator. y: realgnp. W : average hourly earnings of non-agricultural workers. Pim: producers price index. Tbk: bankruptcy filings, personal and business. Pcm: producer price index for intermediate goods. 38

Identification Scheme on A 0 R M Py y W Pim Tbk Pcm R 0 0 0 0 M 0 0 0 0 Py 0 0 0 y 0 0 0 0 0 W 0 0 0 0 Pim 0 0 Tbk 0 0 0 0 0 0 Pcm 39

Comments on Identification Sims and Zha impose exactly 28 identification restrictions. Motivated by an economic model. Intuition guides the choice of model. 40

Impulse Reponses: M2 Model Pcm MD MS Pim Py W y Tbk Pcm (309e-4) M (771e-5) R (566e-5) Response of Pim (173e-4) Py (432e-5) W (499e-5) y (715e-5) Tbk (356e-4)

0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 M Decomposition, M2 Model Forecast Errors PCM MD

0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 M Decomposition, M2 Model MS PIM PY

0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 M Decomposition, M2 Model W Y TBK

0.08 R Decomposition, M2 Model 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 Forecast Errors 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 PCM 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 MD

0.08 R Decomposition, M2 Model 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 MS 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 PIM 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 PY

0.08 R Decomposition, M2 Model 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 W 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 Y 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 TBK

0.06 Py Decomposition, M2 Model 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 Forecast Errors 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 PCM 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 MD

0.06 Py Decomposition, M2 Model 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 MS 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 PIM 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 PY

0.06 Py Decomposition, M2 Model 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 W 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 Y 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00-0.02-0.04 TBK

0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 y Decomposition, M2 Model Forecast Errors PCM MD

0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 y Decomposition, M2 Model MS PIM PY

0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 0.064 0.048 0.032 0.016 0.000-0.016-0.032-0.048-0.064 y Decomposition, M2 Model W Y TBK

0.27 0.18 0.09-0.00-0.09-0.18-0.27 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.00-0.01-0.02-0.03 0.054 0.036 0.018 0.000-0.018-0.036-0.054-0.072 0.015 0.010 0.005 0.000-0.005-0.010-0.015-0.020-0.025-0.030 Time Series of Structural Disturbances: M2 Model Pcm MD MS Pim

0.0050 0.0025 0.0000-0.0025-0.0050-0.0075-0.0100 0.010 0.008 0.006 0.004 0.002 0.000-0.002-0.004-0.006 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.00-0.01-0.02-0.03 0.075 0.050 0.025 0.000-0.025-0.050-0.075 Time Series of Structural Disturbances: M2 Model W Py y Tbk

Fixed R Policy: M2 Model Pcm MD MS Pim Py W y Tbk Pcm (296e-4) M (110-5) R (558e-5) Response of Pim (160e-4) Py (415e-5) W (456e-5) y (679e-5) Tbk (237e-4)

Fixed M Policy: M2 Model Pcm MS MD Pim Py W y Tbk Pcm (278e-4) M (700-5) R (518e-5) Response of Pim (153e-4) Py (364e-5) W (373e-5) y (577e-5) Tbk (287e-4)

Assessment and Criticisms of SVARs SVARs offer an attractive approach to estimation. They promise to coax interesting patterns from the data that will prevail across a set of incompletely specified dynamic economic model with a minimum of identifying assumptions. Moreover, SVAR are easy to estimate. SVAR have contributed to the understanding of aggregate fluctuations, to clarify the importance of different economic shocks, and to generate fruitful debates among macroeconomists. 41

Criticisms of SVARs I Economic shocks recovered from a SVAR do not resemble the shocks measured by other mechanisms, like market expectations (Rudebusch, 1998). Shocks recovered from a SVAR may reflect variables omitted from the model. If these omitted variables correlate with the included variables, the estimated economic shocks will be biased. Example price puzzle : early SVARs found that inflation increased after a contractionary monetary policy shock. Sims (1992): the Fed looks forward when it sets the federal fund rate. Solution? 42

Criticisms of SVARs II Many SVAR exercises, even simple ones, are sensitive to the identification restrictions, Stock and Watson (2001). Many of the identification schemes are the product of an specification search in which researchers look for reasonable answers. If an identification scheme matches the conventional wisdom is called successful, if it does not is called a puzzle or, even worse, a failure (Uhlig, 2005). 43