Mathematical Economics: Lecture 16

Similar documents
EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Lecture Notes. Course Outline

EC /11. Math for Microeconomics September Course, Part II Problem Set 1 with Solutions. a11 a 12. x 2

ARE211, Fall 2005 CONTENTS. 5. Characteristics of Functions Surjective, Injective and Bijective functions. 5.2.

The general programming problem is the nonlinear programming problem where a given function is maximized subject to a set of inequality constraints.

Boston College. Math Review Session (2nd part) Lecture Notes August,2007. Nadezhda Karamcheva www2.bc.

Review of Optimization Methods

7) Important properties of functions: homogeneity, homotheticity, convexity and quasi-convexity

Lecture 4: Optimization. Maximizing a function of a single variable

Mathematical Preliminaries for Microeconomics: Exercises

Nonlinear Programming (NLP)

CHAPTER 2: CONVEX SETS AND CONCAVE FUNCTIONS. W. Erwin Diewert January 31, 2008.

EC400 Math for Microeconomics Syllabus The course is based on 6 sixty minutes lectures and on 6 ninety minutes classes.

MATHEMATICAL ECONOMICS: OPTIMIZATION. Contents

Mathematical Economics. Lecture Notes (in extracts)

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions.

Chapter 13. Convex and Concave. Josef Leydold Mathematical Methods WS 2018/19 13 Convex and Concave 1 / 44

Week 4: Calculus and Optimization (Jehle and Reny, Chapter A2)

Mathematical Foundations II

Mathematical Economics: Lecture 3

Week 10: Theory of the Firm (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 3)

Monotone Function. Function f is called monotonically increasing, if. x 1 x 2 f (x 1 ) f (x 2 ) x 1 < x 2 f (x 1 ) < f (x 2 ) x 1 x 2

Static Problem Set 2 Solutions

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

Lecture 3: Basics of set-constrained and unconstrained optimization

Concave programming. Concave programming is another special case of the general constrained optimization. subject to g(x) 0

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics

. This matrix is not symmetric. Example. Suppose A =

Mathematical Economics: Lecture 9

Paul Schrimpf. October 18, UBC Economics 526. Unconstrained optimization. Paul Schrimpf. Notation and definitions. First order conditions

1 Convexity, concavity and quasi-concavity. (SB )

Optimization Theory. Lectures 4-6

CHAPTER 4: HIGHER ORDER DERIVATIVES. Likewise, we may define the higher order derivatives. f(x, y, z) = xy 2 + e zx. y = 2xy.

Index. Cambridge University Press An Introduction to Mathematics for Economics Akihito Asano. Index.

Functions of Several Variables

Chapter 2: Unconstrained Extrema

Microeconomics I. September, c Leopold Sögner

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32

Recitation 2-09/01/2017 (Solution)

Preferences and Utility

a = (a 1; :::a i )

MATHEMATICS FOR ECONOMISTS. Course Convener. Contact: Office-Hours: X and Y. Teaching Assistant ATIYEH YEGANLOO

Solution Methods. Richard Lusby. Department of Management Engineering Technical University of Denmark

Math (P)refresher Lecture 8: Unconstrained Optimization

z = f (x; y) f (x ; y ) f (x; y) f (x; y )

Lecture Notes for Chapter 12

Optimization. A first course on mathematics for economists

MATH529 Fundamentals of Optimization Unconstrained Optimization II

Euler s Theorem for Homogeneous Functions

UNDERGROUND LECTURE NOTES 1: Optimality Conditions for Constrained Optimization Problems

Chapter 3: Constrained Extrema

Workshop I The R n Vector Space. Linear Combinations

Seminars on Mathematics for Economics and Finance Topic 5: Optimization Kuhn-Tucker conditions for problems with inequality constraints 1

E 600 Chapter 4: Optimization

Session: 09 Aug 2016 (Tue), 10:00am 1:00pm; 10 Aug 2016 (Wed), 10:00am 1:00pm &3:00pm 5:00pm (Revision)

Optimization. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () Optimization 1 / 50

Convex Functions and Optimization

Introduction to Real Analysis Alternative Chapter 1

Generalized Convexity in Economics

Notes I Classical Demand Theory: Review of Important Concepts

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand

Mathematical Economics: Lecture 2

Econ 101A Problem Set 1 Solution

GARP and Afriat s Theorem Production

4) Univariate and multivariate functions

Solutions to selected exercises from Jehle and Reny (2001): Advanced Microeconomic Theory

Lecture 2: Convex Sets and Functions

II. An Application of Derivatives: Optimization

STUDY MATERIALS. (The content of the study material is the same as that of Chapter I of Mathematics for Economic Analysis II of 2011 Admn.

Here each term has degree 2 (the sum of exponents is 2 for all summands). A quadratic form of three variables looks as

Lakehead University ECON 4117/5111 Mathematical Economics Fall 2002

SECTION 5.1: Polynomials

Additional questions for Chapter 1 - solutions: 1. See Varian, p.20. Notice that Varian set a1=a2. 2. See Varian, p.20.

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Supermodular Games

1 Theory of the Firm: Topics and Exercises

Nonlinear Programming and the Kuhn-Tucker Conditions

Properties of Walrasian Demand

GENERALIZED CONVEXITY AND OPTIMALITY CONDITIONS IN SCALAR AND VECTOR OPTIMIZATION

Lecture 8: Basic convex analysis

Econ Slides from Lecture 14

Tutorial 3: Optimisation

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

CONSTRAINED OPTIMALITY CRITERIA

Convex analysis and profit/cost/support functions

DEPARTMENT OF MANAGEMENT AND ECONOMICS Royal Military College of Canada. ECE Modelling in Economics Instructor: Lenin Arango-Castillo

Lagrangian Duality. Richard Lusby. Department of Management Engineering Technical University of Denmark

Hicksian Demand and Expenditure Function Duality, Slutsky Equation

Caculus 221. Possible questions for Exam II. March 19, 2002

Generalization to inequality constrained problem. Maximize

Extreme Abridgment of Boyd and Vandenberghe s Convex Optimization

MATH Max-min Theory Fall 2016

1 Functions and Graphs

EconS 301. Math Review. Math Concepts

ECON2285: Mathematical Economics

STATIC LECTURE 4: CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION II - KUHN TUCKER THEORY

E 600 Chapter 3: Multivariate Calculus

ARE202A, Fall Contents

x +3y 2t = 1 2x +y +z +t = 2 3x y +z t = 7 2x +6y +z +t = a

ECON 5111 Mathematical Economics

HW1 solutions. 1. α Ef(x) β, where Ef(x) is the expected value of f(x), i.e., Ef(x) = n. i=1 p if(a i ). (The function f : R R is given.

Midterm Exam, Econ 210A, Fall 2008

Transcription:

Mathematical Economics: Lecture 16 Yu Ren WISE, Xiamen University November 26, 2012

Outline 1 Chapter 21: Concave and Quasiconcave Functions

New Section Chapter 21: Concave and Quasiconcave Functions

Concave and convex functions Definition A real-valued function f defined on a convex subset U of R n is concave if for all X, Y in U and for all t between 0 and 1, f (tx + (1 t)y ) tf (X) + (1 t)f (Y ). Figure 21.2 A real-valued function f defined on a convex subset U of R n is convex if for all X, Y in U and for all t between 0 and 1, f (tx + (1 t)y ) tf (X) + (1 t)f (Y ). Figure 21.3

Concave and convex functions f is concave if and only if f is convex

Concave and convex functions Different with convex set: whenever X and Y are points in U, the line segment joining X to Y l(x, Y ) {tx + (1 t)y : 0 t 1} is also in U. Figure 21.1

Concave and convex functions A function f of n variables is concave if and only if any secant line connecting two points on the graph of f lies below the graph. A function f of n variables is convex if and only if any secant line connecting two points on the graph of f lies above the graph.

Concave and convex functions Theorem 21.1 Let f be a function defined on a convex subset U of R n. Then, f is concave (convex) if and only if its restriction to very line segment in U is a concave (convex) function of one variable.

Concave and convex functions Calculus Criteria for Concavity: Theorem 21.2 Let f be a C 1 function on an interval I in R. Then, f is concave on I if and only if f (y) f (x) f (x)(y x) for all x, y I. The function f is convex on I if and only if f (y) f (x) f (x)(y x) for all x, y I.

Concave and convex functions Theorem 21.3 let f be a C 1 function on a convex subset U of R n. Then, f is concave on U if and only if for all X, Y in U: f (Y ) f (X) Df (X)(Y X). Similarly, f is convex on U if and only if for all X, Y in U: f (Y ) f (X) Df (X)(Y X) for all X, Y in U.

Concave and convex functions Corollary 21.4 If f is a C 1 concave function on a convex set U and if X 0 U, then Df (X 0 )(Y X 0 ) 0 implies f (Y ) f (X 0 ). In particular, if Df (X 0 )(Y X 0 ) 0 for all Y U, then X 0 is a global max of f.

Concave and convex functions Theorem 21.5 Let f be a C 2 function on an open convex subset U of R n. Then, f is a concave function on U if and only if the Hessian D 2 f (X) is negative semidefinite for all X in U. The function f is a convex function on U if and only if D 2 f (X) is positive semidefinite for all X in U.

Example 21.1 Example 21.1 Let us apply the test of Theorem 21.3 to show that f (x 1, x 2 ) = x1 2 + x 2 2 is convex on R n. The function f is convex if and only if ( ) (y1 2 + y1 2 ) (x1 2 + x2 2 y1 x 1 ) (2x 1 2x 2 ) y 2 x 2 = 2x 1 y 1 2x1 2 + 2x 2 y 2 2x2 2

Example 21.1 if and only if y1 2 + y1 2 + x1 2 + x2 2 2x 1 y 1 2x 2 y 2 0 if and only if (y 1 x 1 ) 2 + (y 2 x 2 ) 2 0 which is true for all (x 1, x 2 ) and (y 1, y 2 ) in R 2.

Example 21.2 Example 21.2 The Hessian of the function f (x, y) = x 4 + x 2 y 2 + y 4 3x 8y is D 2 f (x, y) = ( 12x 2 + 2y 2 4xy 4xy 12x 2 + 2y 2 For (x, y) (0, 0), the two leading principal minors, 12x 2 + 2y 2 and 24x 4 + 132x 2 y 2 + 24y 4, are both positive, so f is a convex function on all R n. )

Example 21.2 Example 21.2 The Hessian of the function f (x, y) = x 4 + x 2 y 2 + y 4 3x 8y is D 2 f (x, y) = ( 12x 2 + 2y 2 4xy 4xy 12x 2 + 2y 2 For (x, y) (0, 0), the two leading principal minors, 12x 2 + 2y 2 and 24x 4 + 132x 2 y 2 + 24y 4, are both positive, so f is a convex function on all R n. )

Example 21.2 Example 21.2 The Hessian of the function f (x, y) = x 4 + x 2 y 2 + y 4 3x 8y is D 2 f (x, y) = ( 12x 2 + 2y 2 4xy 4xy 12x 2 + 2y 2 For (x, y) (0, 0), the two leading principal minors, 12x 2 + 2y 2 and 24x 4 + 132x 2 y 2 + 24y 4, are both positive, so f is a convex function on all R n. )

Example 21.3 Example 21.3 A commonly used simple utility or production function is F(x, y) = xy. Its Hessian is ( ) D 2 0 1 F(x, y) = 1 0 whose second order principal minor is detd 2 F (x, y) = 1. Since this second principal minor is negative, D 2 F is indefinite and F is neither concave nor convex.

Example 21.4 Example 21.4 Consider the monotonic transformation of the function F in the previous example by the function g(z) = z 1/4 : G(x, y) = x 1/4 y 1/4, defined only on the positive quadrant R 2 +. The Hessian of G is D 2 G(x, y) = ( 3 16 x 7/4 y 1/4 1 16 x 3/4 y 3/4 1 16 x 3/4 y 3/4 3 16 x 1/4 y 7/4 )

Example 21.4 Example 21.4 Consider the monotonic transformation of the function F in the previous example by the function g(z) = z 1/4 : G(x, y) = x 1/4 y 1/4, defined only on the positive quadrant R 2 +. The Hessian of G is D 2 G(x, y) = ( 3 16 x 7/4 y 1/4 1 16 x 3/4 y 3/4 1 16 x 3/4 y 3/4 3 16 x 1/4 y 7/4 )

Example 21.4 For x > 0, y > 0, the first order leading principal minor is negative and the second order leading principal minor, x 3/2 y 3/2 /128, is positive. Therefore, D 2 G(x, y) is negative definite on R 2 + and G is a concave function on R 2 +.

Example 21.5 Example 21.5 Now, consider the general Cobb-Douglas function on R+ 2 : U(x, y) = x a y b. Its Hessian is ( D 2 a(a 1)x U(x, y) = a 2 y b abx a 1 y b 1 abx a 1 y b 1 b(b 1)x a y b 2 )

Example 21.5 Example 21.5 Now, consider the general Cobb-Douglas function on R+ 2 : U(x, y) = x a y b. Its Hessian is ( D 2 a(a 1)x U(x, y) = a 2 y b abx a 1 y b 1 abx a 1 y b 1 b(b 1)x a y b 2 )

Example 21.5 whose determinant is detd 2 U(x, y) = ab(1 a b)x 2a 2 y 2b 2. In order for U to be concave on R 2 +, we need a(a 1) < 0 and ab(1 a b) > 0; that is, we need 0 < a < 1, 0 < b < 1, and a + b 1. In summary, a Cobb-Douglas production function on R 2 + is concave if and only if it exhibits constant or decreasing returns to scale.

Properties of Concave functions Theorem 21.6 Let f be a concave (convex) function on an open convex subset U of R n. If x 0 is a critical point of f, that is, Df (x 0 ) = 0, then x 0 U is a global maximizer (minimizer) of f on U.

Properties of Concave functions Theorem 21.7 Let f be a C 1 function defined on a convex subset U of R n. If f is a concave function and if x 0 is a point in U which satisfies Df (x 0 )(y x 0 ) 0 for all y U, then x 0 is a global maximizer of f on U.

Example 21.6 Example 21.6 If f is a C 1 increasing, concave function of one variable on the interval [a,b], then f (b)(x b) 0 for all x [a, b]. By Theorem 21.7, b is the global maximizer of f on [a,b].

Example 21.7 Example 21.7 Consider the concave function U(x, y) = x 1/4 y 1/4 on the (concave) triangle B = {(x, y) : x 0, y 0, x + y 2}. By symmetry, we would expect that (x 0, y 0 ) = (1, 1) is the maximizer of U on B. To prove this, use Theorem 21.7. Let (x,y) be an arbitrary point in B.

Example 21.7 U x U (1, 1)(x 1) + (1, 1)(y 1) y = 1 4 (x 1) + 1 (y 1) 4 = 1 (x + y 2) 4 0 since x + y 2 0 for (x,y) in the constraint set B. By Theorem 21.7, (1,1) is the global maximizer of U on B.

Example 21.8 Example 21.8 Consider the problem of maximizing profit for a firm whose production function is y = g(x), where y denotes output and x denotes the input bundle. If p denotes the price of the output and w i is the cost per unit of input i, then the firm s profit function is Π(x) = pg(x) (w 1 x 1 + + w n x n )

Example 21.8 As can easily be checked, Π will be a concave function provided that the production function is a concave function. In this case, the first order condition p g x i = w i for i = 1, 2,..., n, which says marginal revenue product equals the factor price for each point, is both necessary and sufficient for an interior profit maximizer.

Example 21.8 If one wants to study the effect of changes in w i or p on the optimal input bundle, one would apply the comparative statics analysis to system. Since profit is concave for all p and w, the solution to system will automatically be the optimal input for all choices of p and w.

Properties of Concave functions Theorem 21.8 Let f 1., f k be concave (convex) functions. each defined on the same convex subset U of R n. Let a 1,, a k be positive numbers. Then, a 1 f 1 + + a k f k is a concave (convex) function on U.

Properties of Concave functions Theorem 21.9 let f be a function defined on a convex set U in R n. If f is concave, then for every x 0 in U, the set C + x 0 {x U : f (x) f (x 0 )} is a convex set. If f is convex, then for every x 0 in U, the set C x 0 {x U : f (x) f (x 0 )} is a convex set.

Quasiconcave and Quasiconvex Definition: a function f defined on a convex subset U of R n is quasiconcave if for every real number a, C a + {x U : f (x) a} is a convex set. Similarly, f is quasiconvex if for every real number a, Ca {x U : f (x) f (x 0 )} is a convex set. Figure 21.9

Quasiconcave and Quasiconvex Theorem 21.12 Let f be a function defined on a convex set U in R n. Then, the following statements are equivalent to each other: (a) f is a quasiconcave function on U (b) For all X, Y U and all t [0, 1] f (X) f (Y ) implies f (tx + (1 t)y ) f (Y ) (c) For all X, Y U and all t [0, 1] f (tx + (1 t)y ) min{f (Y ), f (X)}.

Example 21.9 Example 21.9 Consider the Leontief or fixed-coefficient production function Q(x, y) = min{ax, by} with a, b > 0. The level sets of Q are drawn in Figure 21.7. Certainly, the region above and to the right of any of this function s L-shaped level sets is a convex set. Q is quasiconcave.

Extra Theorem Theorem 21.* Any monotonic transformation of a concave function is quasiconcave.

Quasiconcave and Quasiconvex Theorem 21.13 Every Cobb-Douglas function F (x, y) = Ax a y b with A, a and b all positive is quasiconcave.

Example 21.10 Example 21.10 Consider the constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production function Q(x, y) = (a 1 x r 1 + a 2 x r 2) 1/r, where 0 < r < 1. By Theorem 21.8 and Exercise 21.4, (a 1 x r 1 + a 2x r 2 ) is concave. Since g(z) = z1/r is a monotonic transformation, Q is a monotonic transformation of a concave function and therefore is quasiconcave.

Example 21.11 Example 21.11 Let y = f (x) be any increasing function on R 1, as in Figure 21.8. For any x, {x : f (x) f (x )} is just the interval [x, ), a convex subset of R 1. So, f is quasiconcave. On the other hand, {x : f (x) f (x )} is the concave set (, x ]. Therefore, an increasing function on R 1 is both quasiconcave and quasiconvex. The same argument applies to decreasing function.

Example 21.12 Example 21.12 Any function on R 1 which rises monotonically until it reaches a global maximum and then monotonically falls, such as y = x 2 or the bell-shaped probability density function y = ke x 2, is a quasiconcave function, as Figure 21.9 indicates. For any x 1 as in Figure 21.9, there is a x 2 such that f (x 1 ) = f (x 2 ). Then, {x : f (x) f (x 1 )} is the convex interval [x 1, x 2 ].

Quasiconcave and quasiconvex Calculus Criteria: Theorem 21.14 Suppose that F is a C 1 function on an open convex subset U of R n. Then, F is quasiconcave on U if and only if F (y) F(x) implies that DF (x)(y x) 0; F is quasiconvex on U if and only if F (y) F (x) implies that DF (x)(y x) 0;

Quasiconcave and quasiconvex Theorem 21.15 Suppose that F is a real-valued positive function defined on a convex cone C in R n. If F is homogeneous of degree one and quasiconcave on C, it is concave on C.

Pseudoconcave and Pseudoconvex Definition : Let U be an open convex subset of R n. A C 1 function F : U R is pseudoconcave at x U if DF (x )(y x ) 0 implies F (y) F(x ) for all y U. The function F is pseudoconcave on U if (15) holds for all x U. To define a pseudoconvex function on U, one simply reverses all inequalities.

Pseudoconcave and Pseudoconvex Theorem 21.16 Let U be a convex subset of R n, and let F : U R be a C 1 pseudoconcave function. If x U has the property DF (x )(y x ) 0 for all y U, for example, DF (x ) = 0, then x is a global max of F on U. An analogous result holds for pseudoconvex functions.

Pseudoconcave and Pseudoconvex Theorem 21.17 Let U be a convex subset of R n. Let F : U R be a C 1 function. Then, (a) if F is pseudoconcave on U, F is quasiconcave on U, and (b) if U is open and if F(x) 0 for all x U, then F is pseudoconcave on U if and only if F is quasiconcave on U.

Pseudoconcave and Pseudoconvex Theorem 21.18 Let U be an open convex subset of R n. Let F : U R be a C 1 function on U. Then, F is pseudoconcave on U if and only if for each x in U, x is the solution to the constrained maximization problem max F(x) s.t C x {y U : DF (x )(y x ) 0}.

Pseudoconcave and Pseudoconvex Theorem 21.19 Let F be a C 2 function on an open convex subset W in R n. Consider the bordered Hessian H (a) If the largest (n-1) leading principal minors of H alternate in sign, for all x W, with the smallest of these positive, then F is pseudoconcave, and therefore quasiconcave, on W. (b) If these largest (n-1) leading principal minors are all negative for all x W, then F is pseudoconvex, and therefore quasiconvex, on W.

Pseudoconcave and Pseudoconvex Theorem 21.20 Let F be a C 2 function on a convex set W in R 2. Suppose that F is monotone in that F x > 0 and F y > 0 on W. If the determinant (18) is positive for all (x, y) W, then F is quasiconcave on W. If the determinant (19) is negative for all (x, y) W, then F is quasiconvex on W. Conversely, if F is quasiconcave on W, then the determinant (19) is positive; if F is quasiconvex on W, then the determinant (19) is 0 for all (x, y) W.

Example 21.13 Example 21.13 Theorem 21.13 implies that the Cobb-Douglas function U(x, y) = x a y b is quasiconcave on R+ 2 for a, b > 0 since it is a monotone transformation of a concave function. Let s use Theorem 21.20 to prove the quasiconcavity of U. The bordered Hessian is 0 ax a 1 y b bx a y b 1 ax a 1 y b a(a 1)x a 1 y b abx a 1 y b 1 bx a y b 1 abx a 1 y b 1 b(b 1)x a y b 2

Example 21.13 whose determinant is (ab + ab 2 + a 2 b)x 3a 2 y 3b 2, which is always positive for x > 0, y > 0, a > 0, b > 0. By Theorem 21.20, U is pseudoconcave, and therefore quasiconcave.

Concave Programming Unconstrained Problems : Theorem 21.21 Let U be a convex subset of R n. Let f : U R be a C 1 concave (convex) function on U. Then, x is a global max of f on U if and only if Df (x )(x x ) 0 for all x U. In particular, if U is open, or if x is an interior point of U, then x is a global max(min) of f on U if and only if Df (x ) = 0

Concave Programming Constrained Problem : Theorem 21.22 Let U be a convex open subset of R n. Let f : U R be a C 1 pseudoconcave function on U. Let g 1,, g k : U R be C 1 quasiconvex functions. If (x, λ ) satisfy the Lagrangian conditions, x is a global max of f on the constraint set.

Concave Programming Theorem 21.23 let f, g 1,, g k be as in the hypothesis of Theorem 21.22. (a) For any fixed b = (b 1,, b k ) R k, let Z (b) denote the set of x C b that are global maximizers of f on C b. Then, Z (b) is a convex set. (b) For any b R k, let V (b) denote the maximal value of the objective function f in problem (20). If f is concave and the g i are convex, then b V (b) is a concave function of b.

Concave Programming Saddle Point: Definition: Let U be a convex subset of R n. Consider the Lagrangian function (21) for the programming problem (20), as a function of x and λ. Then, (x, λ) is saddle point of L if L(x, λ ) L(x, λ ) L(x, λ) for all λ 0 and all x U. Usually, U = R n or U = R n +, the positive orthant of R n. In the latter case, we say that (x, λ ) is a nonnegative saddle point of L

Concave Programming Theorem 21.24 If (x, λ ) is a (nonnegative) saddle point for L in Problem (20), then x maximizes f on C b (C b R n +).

Concave Programming Theorem 21.25 Suppose that U = R n + or that U is an open convex subset of R n. Suppose that f is a C 1 concave function and that g 1,, g k are C 1 convex functions on U. Suppose that x maximizes f on the constraint set C b as defined in (20). Suppose further that one of the constraint qualifications in Theorem 19.12 holds. Then, there exists λ > 0 such that (X, λ ) is a saddle point of the Lagrangian (21)