--Manuscript Draft-- without Convexity and Compactness Assumptions. IESEG School of Management Lille, FRANCE. Guoqiang Tian, Ph.D.

Similar documents
Existence of Equilibrium in Minimax Inequalities, Saddle Points, Fixed Points, and Games without Convexity Sets

Minimax Inequalities and Related Theorems for Arbitrary Topological Spaces: A Full Characterization

Full characterizations of minimax inequality, fixed point theorem, saddle point theorem, and KKM principle in arbitrary topological spaces

Could Nash equilibria exist if the payoff functions are not quasi-concave?

Constructive Proof of the Fan-Glicksberg Fixed Point Theorem for Sequentially Locally Non-constant Multi-functions in a Locally Convex Space

Essential equilibria in normal-form games

On the Existence of Price Equilibrium in Economies with Excess Demand Functions

On the Existence of Strong Nash Equilibria

Application of Fixed point Theorem in Game Theory

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 1 Apr 2013

ELEMENTS OF THE KKM THEORY ON ABSTRACT CONVEX SPACES

Existence of Equilibria in Games with Arbitrary Strategy Spaces and Preferences: A Full Characterization

NEW MAXIMUM THEOREMS WITH STRICT QUASI-CONCAVITY. Won Kyu Kim and Ju Han Yoon. 1. Introduction

Coincidence and Fixed Points on Product Generalized Convex Spaces

W-GPH-KKM THEOREMS IN PSEUDO H-SPACES AND THEIR APPLICATIONS

Journal of Inequalities in Pure and Applied Mathematics

Yuqing Chen, Yeol Je Cho, and Li Yang

On the existence of Nash equilibrium in discontinuous games

On the existence of price equilibrium in economies with excess demand functions

A second look at minsup points and the existence of pure Nash equilibria. Adib Bagh Departments of Economics and Mathematics University of Kentucky.

Stability of efficient solutions for semi-infinite vector optimization problems

Mircea Balaj. Comment.Math.Univ.Carolinae 42,4 (2001)

ON GENERAL BEST PROXIMITY PAIRS AND EQUILIBRIUM PAIRS IN FREE GENERALIZED GAMES 1. Won Kyu Kim* 1. Introduction

ON BERGE EQUILIBRIUM

Symmetric strong vector quasiequilibrium problems in Hausdorff locally convex spaces

SOME ELEMENTARY GENERAL PRINCIPLES OF CONVEX ANALYSIS. A. Granas M. Lassonde. 1. Introduction

Research Article Existence and Duality of Generalized ε-vector Equilibrium Problems

Solvability of System of Generalized Vector Quasi-Equilibrium Problems

1 Topology Definition of a topology Basis (Base) of a topology The subspace topology & the product topology on X Y 3

Introduction to Correspondences

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory Winter 2018

Existence results for quasi-equilibrium problems

Tijmen Daniëls Universiteit van Amsterdam. Abstract

Geometric Properties and Coincidence Theorems with Applications to Generalized Vector Equilibrium Problems 1

Lower Semicontinuity of the Efficient Solution Mapping in Semi-Infinite Vector Optimization

arxiv: v2 [math.oc] 17 Jul 2017

A Relaxed Explicit Extragradient-Like Method for Solving Generalized Mixed Equilibria, Variational Inequalities and Constrained Convex Minimization

A Note on Discrete Convexity and Local Optimality

EXISTENCE OF PURE EQUILIBRIA IN GAMES WITH NONATOMIC SPACE OF PLAYERS. Agnieszka Wiszniewska Matyszkiel. 1. Introduction

THE KNASTER KURATOWSKI MAZURKIEWICZ THEOREM AND ALMOST FIXED POINTS. Sehie Park. 1. Introduction

Coalitional Equilibria of Strategic Games

Condensing KKM maps and its applications. Ivan D. Arand - elović, Z.Mitrović

Applied Mathematics Letters

Graph Convergence for H(, )-co-accretive Mapping with over-relaxed Proximal Point Method for Solving a Generalized Variational Inclusion Problem

General Convexity, General Concavity, Fixed Points, Geometry, and Min-Max Points

On the existence of Berge s strong equilibrium

General KKM Theorem with Applications to Minimax and Variational Inequalities 1

SOME RESULTS CONCERNING THE MULTIVALUED OPTIMIZATION AND THEIR APPLICATIONS

Many of you got these steps reversed or otherwise out of order.

Existence theorems for generalized Nash equilibrium problems: an analysis of assumptions

Continuous Functions on Metric Spaces

A remark on discontinuous games with asymmetric information and ambiguity

Mathematics for Economists

1 Introduction The study of the existence of solutions of Variational Inequalities on unbounded domains usually involves the same sufficient assumptio

EQUILIBRIUM FOR PERTURBATIONS OF MULTIFUNCTIONS BY CONVEX PROCESSES

MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES. Contents. 1. Sets Functions Countability Axiom of choice Equivalence relations 9

Mathematics II, course

Some Applications of Fixed Point Theorem in Economics and Nonlinear Functional Analysis

Journal of Inequalities in Pure and Applied Mathematics

Abstract. The connectivity of the efficient point set and of some proper efficient point sets in locally convex spaces is investigated.

Remark on a Couple Coincidence Point in Cone Normed Spaces

Generalized vector equilibrium problems on Hadamard manifolds

Research Article Equivalent Extensions to Caristi-Kirk s Fixed Point Theorem, Ekeland s Variational Principle, and Takahashi s Minimization Theorem

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 21 Mar 2015

Research Article On Abstract Economies and Their Applications

A Minimal Point Theorem in Uniform Spaces

Fixed Point Theorems for Condensing Maps

A Direct Proof of Caristi s Fixed Point Theorem

Topology, Math 581, Fall 2017 last updated: November 24, Topology 1, Math 581, Fall 2017: Notes and homework Krzysztof Chris Ciesielski

Upper sign-continuity for equilibrium problems

Metric Spaces and Topology

Fixed and Common Fixed Point Theorems in Metric Spaces

THE UNIQUE MINIMAL DUAL REPRESENTATION OF A CONVEX FUNCTION

Topology. Xiaolong Han. Department of Mathematics, California State University, Northridge, CA 91330, USA address:

KAKUTANI S FIXED POINT THEOREM AND THE MINIMAX THEOREM IN GAME THEORY

Chapter 2. Metric Spaces. 2.1 Metric Spaces

Convex Analysis and Economic Theory Winter 2018

Discussion Paper Series

INVERSE FUNCTION THEOREM and SURFACES IN R n

Technical Results on Regular Preferences and Demand

Problem Set 2: Solutions Math 201A: Fall 2016

ON GENERALIZED-CONVEX CONSTRAINED MULTI-OBJECTIVE OPTIMIZATION

Fixed Point Theorems in Hausdorff Topological Vector Spaces and Economic Equilibrium Theory

Maths 212: Homework Solutions

EC9A0: Pre-sessional Advanced Mathematics Course. Lecture Notes: Unconstrained Optimisation By Pablo F. Beker 1

Lecture Notes in Advanced Calculus 1 (80315) Raz Kupferman Institute of Mathematics The Hebrew University

Economics Noncooperative Game Theory Lectures 3. October 15, 1997 Lecture 3

A Constructive Proof of the Nash Bargaining Solution

6.891 Games, Decision, and Computation February 5, Lecture 2

Some Properties of the Augmented Lagrangian in Cone Constrained Optimization

Functional Analysis. Franck Sueur Metric spaces Definitions Completeness Compactness Separability...

REMARKS ON SOME VARIATIONAL INEQUALITIES

g 2 (x) (1/3)M 1 = (1/3)(2/3)M.

Generalized Monotonicities and Its Applications to the System of General Variational Inequalities

FROM WEIERSTRASS TO KY FAN THEOREMS AND EXISTENCE RESULTS ON OPTIMIZATION AND EQUILIBRIUM PROBLEMS. Wilfredo Sosa

Relaxed Quasimonotone Operators and Relaxed Quasiconvex Functions

Pure Strategy Equilibria in Symmetric Two-Player Zero-Sum Games

(convex combination!). Use convexity of f and multiply by the common denominator to get. Interchanging the role of x and y, we obtain that f is ( 2M ε

Mathematical Methods in Economics (Part I) Lecture Note

WEAK CONVERGENCE OF RESOLVENTS OF MAXIMAL MONOTONE OPERATORS AND MOSCO CONVERGENCE

Transcription:

Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications Existence of Solution of Minimax Inequalities, Equilibria in Games and Fixed Points without Convexity and Compactness Assumptions --Manuscript Draft-- Manuscript Number: Full Title: Article Type: Keywords: Corresponding Author: JOTA-D--000R Existence of Solution of Minimax Inequalities, Equilibria in Games and Fixed Points without Convexity and Compactness Assumptions Original Papers minimax inequality, saddle points, fixed points, coincidence points, discontinuity, non-quasiconcavity, non-convexity, and non-compactness. Rabia Nessah, Ph.D. IESEG School of Management Lille, FRANCE Corresponding Author Secondary Information: Corresponding Author's Institution: IESEG School of Management Corresponding Author's Secondary Institution: First Author: Rabia Nessah, Ph.D. First Author Secondary Information: Order of Authors: Rabia Nessah, Ph.D. Guoqiang Tian, Ph.D. Order of Authors Secondary Information: Abstract: This paper characterizes the existence of equilibria in minimax inequalities without assuming any form of quasi-concavity of functions and convexity or compactness of choice sets. A new condition, called local dominatedness property, is shown to be necessary and further, under some mild continuity condition, sufficient for the existence of equilibrium. We then apply the basic result obtained in the paper to generalize the existing theorems on the existence of saddle points, fixed points, and coincidence points without convexity or compactness assumptions. As an application, we also characterize the existence of pure strategy Nash equilibrium in games with discontinuous and nonquasiconcave payoff functions and nonconvex and/or noncompact strategy spaces. Response to Reviewers: Powered by Editorial Manager and Preprint Manager from Aries Systems Corporation

Manuscript Click here to download Manuscript: Minimax-Inequality-Nessah-Tian--0-0.pdf Click here to view linked References 0 0 0 0 0 0 Existence of Solution of Minimax Inequalities, Equilibria in Games and Fixed Points without Convexity and Compactness Assumptions Rabia Nessah Guoqiang Tian Communicated by Suliman Saleh Al-Homidan Received: date / Accepted: date Abstract This paper characterizes the existence of equilibria in minimax inequalities without assuming any form of quasi-concavity of functions and convexity or compactness of choice sets. A new condition, called local dominatedness property, is shown to be necessary and further, under some mild continuity condition, sufficient for the existence of equilibrium. We then apply the basic result obtained in the paper to generalize the existing theorems on the existence of saddle points, fixed points, and coincidence points without convexity or compactness assumptions. As an application, we also characterize the existence of pure strategy Nash equilibrium in games with discontinuous and nonquasiconcave payoff functions and nonconvex and/or noncompact strategy spaces. 00 Mathematical subject classification: K, 0C, M0 and A0 Keywords Minimax inequality Saddle points Fixed points Coincidence points Discontinuity Non-quasiconcavity Non-convexity Non-compactness. Financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (NSFC-00) and the Program to Enhance Scholarly and Creative Activities at Texas A&M University as well as from Cheung Kong Scholars Program at the Ministry of Education of China is gratefully acknowledged. Rabia Nessah IESEG School of Management CNRS-LEM (UMR ) rue de la Digue 000 Lille France Corresponding author: Tel.: 000 Fax: 000 E-mail: r.nessah@ieseg.fr Guoqiang Tian Department of Economics Texas A&M University College Station, Texas USA E-mail: gtian@tamu.edu

0 0 0 0 0 0 Introduction The minimax inequality [] is one of the most important tools in nonlinear analysis and in mathematical economics. Indeed, it allows one to derive many practical and theoretical results in a wide variety of fields. In many situations, the Ky Fan inequality is more flexible and adaptable than other basic theorems in nonlinear analysis, such as fixed point theorems and variational inequalities. [] remarked that it is often easier to reduce an equilibrium existence problem to a minimax inequality problem rather than to transform it into a fixed point problem. Therefore, weakening its conditions further enlarges its domain of applicability. The many applications of minimax inequality in different areas (such as general equilibrium theory, game theory, and optimization theory) attracted researchers to weaken the conditions on the existence of its solution. Lignola [] relaxed the assumption on the compactness and the semicontinuity. [,,] weakened the condition of quasiconcavity of the function. Many other results were also obtained, such as those in [,,,,,,, 0]. Equilibrium problems were studied in both mathematics and economics, such as those in [-,-0,-,,], among which [, ] generalized the Ky Fan inequality to different sets. However, all the work mentioned above is assumed that the set is convex. In many practical situations, a choice set may not be convex and/or not compact so that the existing theorems cannot be applied. In this paper, we provide characterization results on the existence of solution to the minimax inequality without any form of quasi-concavity of function or convexity and compactness of choice sets. We introduce a new condition, called local-dominatedness property. It is shown that the local dominatedness condition is necessary and further, under some mild continuity condition, sufficient for the existence of a solution to a minimax inequality. We then apply the basic result to study the existence of saddle points, fixed points, and coincidence points. As an application of our basic result, we study the existence of equilibria for a noncooperative game without quasi-concavity of payoff functions and convexity or compactness of strategy spaces. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section, we give basic terminologies used in our study. We introduce the concepts of local-dominatedness property, transfer quasi-concavity, and transfer continuity. We also provide sufficient conditions for these conditions to be true. Section is dedicated to the development of existence theorems on minimax inequality for a function defined on cartesian product of two different sets without the convexity and/or compactness assumptions. In Section, we apply our results on the minimax inequality to offers new existence theorems on saddle points without assuming convexity and/or compactness of choice sets. In Section, we provide necessary and sufficient conditions for the existence of fixed points and coincidence points. We introduce the concept of f-separability that can be used to characterize the existence of fixed point of a function without the convexity assumption. Section considers the existence of coincidence points. In Section, we consider the existence of equilibria in games discontinuous and non-quasiconcavity of payoff functions and convexity and/or compactness of strategy spaces. Concluding remarks are offered in Section. Notations and Definitions Let Y be a nonempty subset of a topological space F. Denote by Y be the family of all nonempty subsets of Y and Y the set of all finite subsets of Y. Let S Y, denote by int S the relative interior of S in Y and by cl S the relative closure of S in Y.

0 0 0 0 0 0 A function f : Y R is upper semicontinuous on Y iff, the set {x Y, f(x) c} is closed for all c R; f is lower semicontinuous on Y iff, f is upper semicontinuous on Y ; f is continuous on Y iff, f is both upper and lower semicontinuous on Y. Let F be a vector space and Y a convex set. A function f : Y R is quasiconcave on Y iff, for any y, y in Y and for any θ [0, ], min {f(y ), f(y )} f(θy +( θ)y ), and f is quasiconvex on Y iff, f is quasiconcave on Y. A function f : Y Y R is diagonally quasiconcave in y iff, for any finite points y,..., y m Y and any y co{y,..., y m }, min k m f(y, y k ) f(y, y). A function f : Y Y R is α-diagonally quasiconcave in y iff, for any y,..., y m Y and y co{y,..., y m }, min k m f(y, y k ) α. Definition.. (α-local-dominatedness) Let α R. A function Ψ : X Y R is said to be α-locally-dominated in y iff, for any A Y, there exists x X such that: maxψ(x, y) α. y A The term localness reflects to choose finite subsets from Y. Dominatedness refers to the fact that Ψ(x, y) is dominated by α. α-local-dominatedness property says that, given any finite set A Y, there exists a corresponding candidate point x X such that Ψ(x, y) is dominated by α for all points in A. We will see from Theorem. below that α-localdominatedness condition is necessary, and further, under some mild condition, sufficient for the existence of solution to the minimax inequality. Remark.. Let H(y) = {x X : Ψ(x, y) α} for y Y. Then, the function Ψ(x, y) is α-locally-dominated in y if and only if the family sets {H(y), y Y } has the finite intersection property. Example.. Consider the following function. f : R R R, (x, y) f(x, y) = x x y. It is obvious that, if x < 0, the function y f(x, y) is not quasiconcave in y. However, it is 0-locally-dominated in y. To see this, let y,..., y n R. Then there exists x = max y i i=,...,n such that yi x for all i n. Thus, xyi x, and f(x, y i ) = x xyi 0 for all i n. The following Definition generalizes the γ-generalized quasiconcave in [] and the transfer quasiconcavity in [] to a function defined in the product of different sets. Definition.. (α-transfer quasiconcavity) Let X be a nonempty and convex subset of a vector space E and let Y be a nonempty set. A function Ψ : X Y R is said to be α-transfer quasiconcave in y iff, for any finite subset {y,..., y m } Y, there exists a corresponding finite subset {x,..., x m } X such that, for any subset L {,,..., m} and any x co{x h : h L}, we have min f(x, h L yh ) α. Remark.. When X = Y, a sufficient condition for a function Ψ : X Y R to be α-transfer quasiconcave in y is that it is α-diagonally quasiconcave in y. The following Proposition characterizes the α-local-dominatedness property if X is convex and Ψ is lower semi-continuous in x.

0 0 0 0 0 0 Proposition.. Let X be a nonempty, convex and compact subset in a topological vector space E, and let Y be a nonempty set. Suppose function Ψ(x, y) is lower semi-continuous in x. Then Ψ(x, y) is α-locally-dominated in y if and only if it is α-transfer quasiconcave in y. Proof. Necessity: Suppose that Ψ(x, y) is α-locally-dominated in y, i.e., Then, for each B Y, there exists x X such that supψ( x, y) α. Let {y,..., y m } Y. Then there y B exists a corresponding finite subset {x,..., x m } X, where x =... = x m = x such that, for each J {,..., m}, x co{x j : j J} = { x}, inf Ψ(x, j J yj ) supψ(x, y j ) α, j J i.e., Ψ(x, y) is α-transfer quasiconcave in y. Sufficiency: Suppose that Ψ(x, y) is α-transfer quasiconcave in y. By Remark., Ψ(x, y) is α-locally-dominated in y if and only if {G(y) = {x X : Ψ(x, y) α}, y Y } has the finite intersection property. Suppose that this family does not have the finite intersection property. Then, there exists B = {y,..., y m } Y such that G(y) =, i.e., for each y B x X, there exists y B such that x / G(y). Let A = {x,..., x m } X be the corresponding points in X such that, for each M k {,,..., m} and any x co{x h, h M k }, we have min Ψ(x, y h ) α. Let Z = co(a) and L = span(a) = span{x,..., x m }. Since h M k G(y) is closed, we can define a continuous function g : Z [0, [ by g(x) = m d(x, G(y i ) L), i= where d is the Euclidean metric on L. Since G(y) =, then g(x) > 0 for each x X. y B Define another continuous function f : Z Z by f(x) := m i= d(x, G(y i ) L) x i. g(x) By Brouwer fixed point Theorem, there exists x Z such that x = f(x) = m i= d(x, G(y i ) L) x i. () g(x) Let J = {i {,..., m} : (x, G(y i ) L) > 0}. Then, for each i J, x / G(y i ) L. Since x L, x / G(y i ) for any i J. Thus, we have inf i J Ψ(x, yi ) > α. () From (), x co{x i : i J}, and then by α-transfer quasiconcavity, we obtain inf i J Ψ(x, yi ) α, which contradicts (). Therefore, the function y Ψ(x, y) is α-locally-dominated. Ansari et al. [] defined the following concept of continuity.

0 0 0 0 0 0 Definition.. (α-transfer lower semicontinuity) Let X be a nonempty subset of a topological space, and Y be a nonempty subset. A function f : X Y R is said to be α-transfer lower semicontinuous in x with respect to Y iff, for (x, y) X Y, f(x, y) > α implies that there exists some point y Y and some neighborhood V(x) X of x such that f(z, y ) > α for all z V(x). The α-transfer lower semicontinuity in x with respect to Y says that, if a point x in X is dominated by another point y in Y comparing to α, then there is an open set of points containing x, all of which can be dominated by a single point y. Here, transfer lower semicontinuity in x with respect to Y refers to the fact that y may be transferred to some y in order for the inequality to hold for all points in a neighborhood of x. The usual notion of lower semicontinuity would require that the first inequality hold at y for all points in a neighborhood of x. Thus, α-transfer lower semicontinuity is weaker than the notions of continuity used in the literature. We have the following Proposition. Proposition.. Any one of the following conditions is sufficient for f(x, y) to be α-transfer lower semicontinuous in x with respect to Y : (a) f(x, y) is continuous in x; (b) f(x, y) is lower semicontinuous in x. Remark.. Proposition. still hold when lower semicontinuity is weakened to transfer lower semicontinuity. Minimax Inequality without Convexity and/or Compactness In this Section, we present theorems on the existence of equilibrium in the minimax inequality for a function defined on cartesian product of two different sets X and Y without any form of quasiconcavity of function and/or convexity and compactness of sets. Theorem.. Let X be a nonempty and compact subset of a topological space E, and Y a nonempty set. Suppose Ψ is a real-valued function on X Y such that Ψ(x, y) is α-transfer lower semicontinuous in x with respect to Y. Then, there exists x X such that if and only if Ψ is α-locally-dominated in y. Ψ(x, y) α, y Y () Proof. Necessity: Let x X be a solution of the minimax inequality (). Then, we have max Ψ(x, y) α for any subset A = y A {y,..., y m } Y. Hence Ψ(x, y) is α-locallydominated in y. Sufficiency: If Ψ(x, y) is α-transfer lower semicontinuous in x with respect to Y, then H(y) = cl H(y), where H(y) = {x X : Ψ(x, y) α}. Indeed, let us consider x cl H(y) but not in H(y). Then, there exists y Y such that x / H(y), i.e., Ψ(x, y) > α. By the α-transfer lower semicontinuity of Ψ in x with respect to Y, there exists y Y and a neighborhood V(x) of x such that Ψ(z, y ) > α for all z V(x). Thus, x / cl H(y ), a contradiction. The condition that y Ψ(x, y) is α-locally-dominated in y implies that {cl H(y) : Y } has the finite intersection property. Since {cl H(y) : y Y }

0 0 0 0 0 0 is a compact family in the compact set X. Thus, H(y). Hence, there exists x X such that Ψ(x, y) α for y Y. This completes the proof. Remark.. The above result generalizes the existing results without assuming any form of quasiconcavity or X = Y. Note that, in Example., if the function f is defined on [, ] [, ], then the existing results cannot be applicable since the function f(x, y) is not quasiconcave in y on [, ] for all x [, ]. However, there exists a solution since Ψ is α-locally-dominated in y. The following is an example. Example.. Let X = Y = ([/, ] [/, ]), x = (x, x ), y = (y, y ), and F (x, y) := x y x y x x + x x. The function F is continuous over X X. For any subset {(y,, y, ),..., (y,k, y,k )} of X X, let x = (x, x ) X such that x = max y,h and x = min y,h. h=,...,k h=,...,k Then, y,h x and y,h x, for each h =,..., k. Thus, x y,h x x, and x y,h x x for each h =,..., k. Therefore, F (x, y h ) F (x, x) 0, h =,..., k. The other conditions of Theorem. are obviously satisfied. Thus, the minimax inequality has a solution. Since X is not convex, the results in [,,,,,] on the existence of a solution to the Ky Fan inequality are not applicable. When X is convex, Proposition. and Theorem. imply the following corollary. Corollary.. Let X be a nonempty, convex and compact subset of a topological vector space E, and Y a nonempty set. Let Ψ : X Y R be α-transfer lower semicontinuous in x with respect to Y. Then, the minimax inequality () has at least one solution if and only if Ψ(x, y) is α-transfer quasiconcave in y. Theorem. can be generalized to the case where X is not compact. Theorem.. Let X be a nonempty subset of a topological space E, and Y a nonempty set. Suppose Ψ is a real-valued function on X Y such that: (a) Ψ(x, y) is α-transfer lower semicontinuous in x with respect to Y ; (b) there exists a finite subset {y,..., y k } Y such that G α(y i ) is compact, where i=,...,k G α(y) = {x X : Ψ(x, y) α}. Then, there exists x X such that if and only if Ψ is α-locally-dominated in y. Ψ(x, y) α, y Y () Proof. The necessity is the same as that of Theorem.. We only need to prove the sufficiency. For each y Y, let G α(y) = {x X : Ψ(x, y) α}. Then, by condition (a) of Theorem., we have G α(y) = cl G α(y). The condition that y Ψ(x, y) is α-locally-dominated implies that {cl G α(y) : y Y } has the finite intersection property, and therefore {G α(y) G α(y i ) : y Y } has the finite intersection property. For i=,...,k each y Y, the set G α(y) G α(y i ) is compact. Thus, G α(y). Hence, there i=,...,k exists x X such that Ψ(x, y) α for all y Y. This completes the proof.

0 0 0 0 0 0 Theorem.. Let X be a nonempty subset of a topological space E, and Y a nonempty set. Let Ψ(x, y) be a real-valued function on X Y. Then, the minimax inequality () has at least one solution if and only if there exists a nonempty compact subset X 0 of X such that: (a) Ψ X0 Y (x, y) is α-transfer lower semicontinuous in x with respect to Y ; (b) there exists ȳ Y such that G(ȳ) is compact, where G(y) = {x X 0 : Ψ(x, y) α}; (c) the function y Ψ X0 Y (x, y) is α-locally-dominated in x on X 0. Proof. Necessity: Suppose that the minimax inequality () has a solution x X. Let X 0 = {x}. Then, the set X 0 is nonempty and compact, and the restricted function Ψ X0 Y is α-transfer lower semicontinuous in x with respect to Y. The set G(y) = {x X 0 : Ψ(x, y) α} is compact for each y X, and for each A Y, x = x X 0 such that maxψ(x, y) maxψ(x, y) α (because x is a solution of the y A minimax inequality ()). Sufficiency: For each y Y, let G(y) = {x X : Ψ(x, y) α}. Then by condition (a) of Theorem., we have G(y) = cl G(y). Condition (c) of Theorem. implies that {cl G(y) : y Y } has the finite intersection property, and therefore the family {G(y) G(ȳ) : y Y } has the finite intersection property. For each y Y, the set G(y) G(ȳ) is compact. Thus, = G(y) G(ȳ) = G(y). Hence, there exists x X 0 such that for each y Y, Ψ(x, y) α. This completes the proof. Existence of Saddle Point Saddle point is an important tool in variational problems and game theory. Much work has been dedicated to the problem of weakening its existence conditions. Almost all these results assume that a function is defined on convex sets. In this Section, we present existence theorems on saddle point without any form of convexity conditions. Consider two players, Juba and Massi with strategy sets X and Y, respectively. If Juba chooses a strategy a X and Massi chooses a strategy b Y, the payoff is given by f(a, b) := gain by Massi = loss by Juba (e.g. in euro). We allow f(a, b) to be negative, and, if this is the case, then player Massi can obtain a negative gain, that is, a loss of f(a, b) euro. Definition.. A pair (x, y) in X Y is called a saddle point of f in X Y, iff, f(x, y) f(x, y) f(x, y) for all x X and y Y. This definition reflects the fact that each player is individualistic. Before we give our new results, we state two classical results on saddle point. Theorem.. (von Neumann Theorem). Let X and Y be nonempty, compact and convex subsets in a Hausdorff locally convex vector spaces E and F, respectively, and f a real valued function defined on X Y. Suppose that (a) the function x f(x, y) is lower semicontinuous and quasiconvex on X, (b) the function y f(x, y) is upper semicontinuous and quasiconcave on Y. Then, f has a saddle point.

0 0 0 0 0 0 Theorem.. (Kneser Theorem) Let X be a nonempty and convex subset in a Hausdorff topological vector space E, and Y a nonempty, compact and convex subset of a Hausdorff topological vector space F. Let f be a real valued function defined on X Y. Suppose that (a) the function x f(x, y) is concave on X, (b) the function y f(x, y) is lower semicontinuous and convex on Y. Then, min sup x X f(x, y) = sup minf(x, y). x X By relaxing the convexity of function, we obtain the following Theorem. Theorem.. (Saddle-point without convexity) Let X and Y be two nonempty, compact subsets in topological spaces E and G, respectively. Let f : X Y R be a real valued function defined on X Y such that f(x, y ) f(x, y) is 0-transfer lower semicontinuous in (x, y) with respect to X Y. Then, the function f has a saddle point if and only if, for all {(a i, b i ) : i =,..., n} X Y, there exists (x, y) X Y such that f(x, b i ) f(a i, y), for all i =,..., n. Proof. Necessity: Let (x, y) X Y be a saddle point of f. Then, f(x, y) f(x, y) f(x, y) for all x X and y Y. () Suppose that there exists A = {(a i, b i ), i =,..., n} X Y, such that (x, y) X Y, i =,..., n such that f(x, b i ) > f(a i, y). () Let x = x and y = y in (). Then there exists (ã, b) A such that f(x, b) > f(ã, y). Now choose x = ã and y = b. Inequality () becomes: f(x, b) f(x, y) f(ã, y). Thus, we have f(x, b) f(ã, y) < f(x, b), which is a contradiction. Therefore, for all {(a i, b i ) : i =,..., n} X Y, there exists (x, y) X Y such that f(x, b i ) f(a i, y) for all i =,..., n. Sufficiency: Let F : Z Z R, where Z = X Y and F (z, t) = f(x, y ) f(x, y), z = (x, y) Z and t = (x, y ) Z. It is easy to verify that all conditions of Theorem. are satisfied for the F (z, t). Then, there exists z = (x, y) Z such that maxf (z, t) 0. () t Z Now we prove that z = (x, y) is a saddle point of the function f(x, y). From () we get (x, y) X Y, f(x, y) f(x, x). () Letting x = x in (), we have y Y, f(x, y) f(x, y). Letting y = y in (), we have x X, f(x, y) f(x, y). Therefore, for all (x, y) X Y, we have f(x, y) f(x, y) f(x, y), i.e., (x, y) is a saddle point of the function f(x, y).

0 0 0 0 0 0 When X is convex, Proposition. and Theorem. imply the following Corollary. Corollary.. Let X and Y be two nonempty, compact and convex subsets in topological spaces E and G, respectively. Let f : X Y R be a real valued function defined on X Y such that f(x, y ) f(x, y) is 0-transfer lower semicontinuous in (x, y) with respect to X Y. Then, the function f has a saddle point if and only if f(x, y ) f(x, y) is 0-transfer quasiconcave in (x, y ). Theorem. can be generalized by relaxing the compactness of X and Y. Theorem.. Let X and Y be two nonempty subsets in topological spaces E and G, respectively. Let f : X Y R such that: (a) f(x, y ) f(x, y) is 0-transfer lower semicontinuous in (x, y) with respect to X Y ; (b) there exists {(x, y ),..., (x k, y k )} X Y such that G(x i, y i ) is compact, i=,...,k where G(u, v) = {(x, y) X Y : f(x, v) f(u, y)}. Then, the function f has a saddle point if and only if, for all {(a i, b i ) : i =,..., n} X Y, there exists (x, y) X Y such that f(x, b i ) f(a i, y), for all i =,..., n. Proof. The necessity part of the proof is the same as that of Theorem., and the sufficiency part of the proof is the same as that of Theorem.. Remark.. The function f(x, y ) f(x, y) is 0-transfer lower semicontinuous in (x, y) with respect to X Y if (a) x f(x, y) is lower semicontinuous function in x and (b) y f(x, y) is upper semicontinuous function in y. Existence of Fixed Point This Section provides necessary and sufficient conditions for the existence of fixed point of a function defined on a set that may not be compact or convex. A correspondence C, defined from Y into F, has a fixed point x Y iff, x C(x). If C is a single-valued function, then a fixed point x of C is characterized by x = C(x). We start by considering the following example of a fixed point problem: Example.. Define a function f : X = [0, ] R by f(x) := x + x +. Since max f (x) =, f is a -Lipschitz. Moreover, since f([0, ]) = [, ] [0, ], all x [0,] the classical fixed point Theorems (Banach s, Brouwer-Schauder-Tychonoff s, Halpern- Bergman s, Kakutani-Fan-Glicksberg s,... []) are not applicable. Banach Fixed Point Theorem: Let (K, d) be a complete metric space and let f : K K be a d- contraction (d [0, [). Then, f has a unique fixed point. Brouwer-Schauder-Tychonoff Fixed Point Theorem: Let K be a nonempty, compact and convex subset of a locally convex Hausdorff space, and let f : K K be a continuous function. Then the set of fixed points of f is compact and nonempty. Halpern-Bergman Fixed Point Theorem: Let K be a nonempty, compact and convex subset of a locally convex Hausdorff space X, and let C : K X be an inward pointing upper demicontinuous mapping with nonempty, closed and convex values. Then C has a fixed point. Kakutani-Fan-Glicksberg Fixed Point Theorem: Let K be a subset nonempty, compact and convex of a locally convex Hausdorff space, and let C : K K have closed graph and nonempty and convex values. Then the set of fixed points of C is nonempty and compact.

0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Let (E, d) be a metric space. The subset B(a, r) is defined by B(a, r) := {x E : d(x, a) < r}, where a X and r R +, is called open ball centered at a point a with radius r. Definition.. Let X be a nonempty set in a metric space (E, d) and f be a function defined on X into E. The set X is called f-separate iff, at least one of the following conditions holds: (a) for all A X, there exists x X such that: A B(x, d(f(x), x)) = ; (b) for all A f(x), there exists x X such that: A x B(x,r) Fig. X is f-separate r A B(f(x), d(f(x), x)) =. r = d(f(x),x) The geometric interpretation that X being f-separate is that any finite subset A of X (or of f(x)) can be separated from some single point x (or f(x)) of X by an open ball centered in x (or in f(x)) with radius r(x) = d(f(x), x). By relaxing the convexity of set, we have the following theorem. Theorem.. (Fixed-point without convexity assumption) Let X be a nonempty and compact subset of a metric space (E, d) and f be a continuous function over X into E. Then, f has a fixed point if and only if X is f-separate. Proof. Necessity: Let x X be a fixed point of f. Then f(x) = x, i.e., d(f(x), x) = 0. Suppose that X is not f-separate. We distinguish two cases: ) There exists A = {y,..., y n} X such that A B(x, d(f(x), x)) for all x X. Then, x X there exists y(x) A such that y(x) B(x, d(f(x), x)), i.e., d(f(x), x) > d(x, y(x)). Let x = x in the last inequality. Then there exists y(x) A such that d(f(x), x) > d(x, y(x)). We have d(f(x), x) = 0, and 0 > d(x, y(x)), which is impossible. Thus, X is f-separate. X (E,d)

0 0 0 0 0 0 ) There exists A = {y,..., y n} f(x) such that, for A B(f(x), d(f(x), x)) for all x X. Then, x X there exists y(x) A such that y(x) B(f(x), d(f(x), x)), i.e., d(f(x), x) > d(f(x), y(x)). Let x = x in the last inequality. Then there exists y(x) A such that d(f(x), x) > d(f(x), y(x)). We have d(f(x), x) = 0, and therefore 0 > d(f(x), y(x)), a contradiction. Thus, for all A f(x), there exists x X such that A B(f(x), d(f(x), x)) =. Hence, X is f-separate. Sufficiency: Suppose that X is f-separate. Then, one of the following conditions holds: ) For all A X, there exists x X such that A B(x, d(f(x), x)) =. Consider the following real-valued function ϕ defined on X X and by (x, y) ϕ(x, y) := d(f(x), x) d(x, y). The function x ϕ(x, y) is then continuous over X, y X. Thus, for all A X, there exists x X such that A B(x, d(f(x), x)) =, and then, for all y A, d(x, y) d(f(x), x), i.e., maxϕ(x, y) 0. By Theorem., there exists x X such y A that sup y X ϕ(x, y) 0. Then, for each y X, we have d(x, f(x)) d(x, y). Letting y = x in last inequality, we obtain d(x, f(x)) = 0, which means x = f(x). Then, f has a fixed point. ) For all C f(x), there exists x X such that C B(f(x), d(f(x), x)) =. Consider the following real-valued function ϕ defined on X f(x) and by (x, y) ϕ(x, y) := d(f(x), x) d(f(x), y). The function x ϕ(x, y) is continuous over X, y f(x). Thus, for all y C, d(f(x), y) d(f(x), x), i.e., maxϕ(x, y) 0. Therefore by Theorem., there exists y C x X such that sup ϕ(x, y) 0. Then, for each y f(x), d(x, f(x)) d(f(x), y). y f(x) Letting y = f(x) in last inequality, we obtain d(x, f(x)) = 0, which means x = f(x). Then, f has a fixed point. Remark.. If X is compact in a metric space, then the two conditions (a) and (b) in Definition. are equivalent. Example.. (Continued) Let us again consider Example.. The function f is defined by f : X = [0, ] R x f(x) = x+ x+. The point x = is a fixed point of f in [0, ], then the set [0, ] is f-separate. Theorem. can be generalized by relaxing the compactness of X. Theorem.. (Fixed-point without convexity or compactness) Let X be a nonempty subset of a metric space (E, d) and f a continuous function over X into E. Suppose that there exist {y,..., y k } X such that G(y i ) is compact, where G(y) = i=,...,k { {x X, d(f(x), x) d(x, y)}, if condition ) in Definition. is satisfied, {x X, d(f(x), x) d(f(x), y)}, if condition ) in Definition. is satisfied. Then, f has a fixed point if and only if X is f-separate.

0 0 0 0 0 0 Proof. The necessity is the same as that of Theorem.. We only need to prove the sufficiency in the case where condition ) in Definition. is satisfied. For each y Y, let G(y) = {x X : d(f(x), x) d(x, y)}. Since f is continuous, G(x) is a closed set. Furthermore, the condition that X is f-separate implies that the famlily {G(y) : y X} has the finite intersection property, and therefore {G(y) G(y i ) : y X} has the finite intersection property. For each y Y, G(y) i=,...,k G(y i ) is compact. Thus, G G(y i ) = G(y). Hence, i=,...,k y X i=,...,k y X there exists x X such that each y X, d(f(x), x) d(x, y). Then, letting y = x, we obtain f(x) = x. This completes the proof. The following Proposition provides a sufficient condition for a set X to be f-separate. Proposition.. Let X be a nonempty, compact and convex subset of a normed space (E,. ) and f a continuous function over X into E such that X f(x) and the function z f(z) x is quasiconvex over X, for all x X. Then, X is f-separate and thus it has a fixed point. Proof. Let A = {y, y,..., y n} be any set in X. Suppose that x X, y A such that x y < f(x) x, () i.e., X is not f-separate. Consider the following multi-valued function C : X X, defined by x C(x) = {z X : min x y f(z) x }. y A ) The condition X f(x) implies that, for each x X, C(x). ) The continuity of f and the compactness of X imply that C is upper semicontinuous over X and, for each x X, the set C(x) is closed in X. ) The quasiconvexity of function z f(z) x implies that C(x) is convex in X, for each x X. From )-), we conclude that the function C satisfies all the conditions of Kakutani s fixed point theorem in []. Consequently, x X such that x C( x), i.e., min x y f( x) x. y A Let x = x in (). Then there exists y( x) A such that x y( x) < f( x) x. Therefore, f( x) x min x y x y( x) < f( x) x, a contradiction. Thus, X is y A f-separate. The following Example illustrate Proposition.. Example.. Let f be the following function f : X = [0, ] R defined as follows: x f(x) = x. Then, max f (x) =, and so f is a -Lipschitz. Moreover, since x [0,] f([0, ]) = [, ] [0, ], all the classical fixed point Theorems (Banach s, Brouwer- Schauder-Tychonoff s, Halpern-Bergman s, Kakutani-Fan-Glicksberg s,...) are not applicable. However, since z z x is quasiconvex over [0, ], x [0, ] (see Fig. ), by Proposition., f has a fixed point in [0, ]. Indeed, x = ( + )/ is such a point.

0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0,,,, Fig. The graph of function z z x, x [0, ] In the following Theorem, we show the existence of fixed point without the quasiconvexity of z f(z) x or the convexity of X. Theorem.. Let (E,. ) be a normed space and f a function over E into E. Suppose that there exists a compact set X in E such that: (a) The restriction of f on X is continuous; (b) f(x) is convex in E; and (c) X f(x). Then, f has a fixed point. Proof. Consider the following function: φ : X f(x) R defined by (x, y) φ(x, y) = f(x) x x y. The function x φ(x, y) is continuous over X, for each y f(x). The function y φ(x, y) is quasiconcave over f(x), for each x X. Suppose that x X, there exists y f(x), such that φ(x, y) > 0. (0) Then, f(x) can be covered by the sets θ y = { f(x) f(x) : φ(x, y) > 0}, y f(x). Since θ y is open in f(x) and f(x) is compact, it can be covered by a finite number r of subsets {int θ y,..., int θ yr } of type θ y. Consider a continuous partition of unity {h i } i=,...,r associated to this finite covering, and the following function: α : f(x) f(x), such that α(y) = r h i (y)y i. The function α is continuous over the compact convex f(x) into f(x). Then, by Brouwer Fixed-Point Theorem, there exists ỹ = f( x) f(x) such that ỹ = f( x) = r h i (ỹ)y i. Let J = {i =,..., r : h i (ỹ) > 0}. i= i=

0 0 0 0 0 0 The quasiconcavity of y φ(x, y) implies that: min φ( x, y i) 0. () i J If i J, ỹ supp(h i ) θ yi. Thus, φ( x, y i ) > 0 for each i J. Therefore, min φ( x, y i) > 0. () i J Then inequalities () and () imply 0 < min i J φ( x, y i) 0, which is impossible. Thus, supposition in (0) is not true, i.e., x X, such that y f(x), we have φ(x, y) = f(x) x x y 0. Hence, f(x) x x y for each y f(x). By condition (c) of Theorem, we have X f(x). Thus, letting y = x, we obtain f(x) x = 0 in last inequality, which means x is a fixed point of f in X. We have the following Corollary. Corollary.. Let f be a continuous function over a compact interval X R into R such that X f(x). Then, f has a fixed point. Proof. By Theorem., it suffices to show that f(x) is convex. If f(x) is reduced to a singleton, then the proof is obvious. Suppose that f(x) is not reduced to a singleton. Let y, y f(x) and t [0, ]. Then there exist x, x X such that y = f(x ) and y = f(x ). Let g be a function defined as follows: g(x) = f(x) ty ( t)y. Thus, g is continuous over the compact interval X and g(x ) g(x ) 0. Therefore, by intermediate value Theorem, there exists c [x, x ] X such that g(c) = 0. Hence, ty + ( t)y = f(c) f(x), i.e. f(x) is convex. The following Examples illustrate Theorem. and Corollary.. Example.. Let f be the following function f : R R x f(x) = x + x x +. Let X = [0, ]. We have max x [0,] f (x) = so that f is a -Lipschitz. Moreover, since f([0, ]) = [f min, ] [0, ] where f min.00, all the classical fixed point theorems are not applicable. We have f(0) = and f() = ; then the intermediate value theorem can not be applied. However, since the restriction of f on [0, ] is continuous, f([0, ]) is convex and f([0, ]) = [f min, ] [0, ] with f min.00, then, by Theorem., f has a fixed point in [0, ]. Example.. Let f be the following function Let X = [, ]. We then have f : R R x f(x) = x x+. max x [,] f (x) = so that f is a -Lipschitz. Moreover, since f([, ]) = [, /] [, ], the function z f(z) x is not

0 0 0 0 0 0 quasiconvex in z and thus all the classical fixed point Theorems and Proposition. are not applicable. However, since the restriction of f on [, ] is continuous, f([, ]) is convex and f([, ]) = [, /] [, ], then, by Theorem., f has a fixed point in [, ]. Indeed, x = + is such a point. The following Theorem generalizes the existence theorems on fixed point to a multifunction mapping. Theorem.. Let X be a nonempty and compact subset of a metric space E and C a multifunction mapping defined on X into E such that the function x d(x, C(x)) is lower semicontinuous over X. Then, C has a fixed point if and only if, for each A X, there exists x X such that d(x, C(x)) d(x, A). Proof. It is a consequence of Theorem. by defining Ψ(x, y) = d(x, C(x)) d(x, y). Theorem.. Let X be a nonempty and compact subset of a metric space E and Y a nonempty subset of a metric space (F, d), and let C be a multifunction mapping defined on X into Y such that the function x d(g(x), C(x)) is lower semicontinuous over X, where g is a continuous function defined from X into Y. Then, C has a g-fixed point (i.e., x X such that g( x) C( x)) if and only if, for each A g(x), there exists x X such that d(g(x), C(x)) d(g(x), A). Proof. It is a consequence of Theorem. by defining Ψ(x, y) = d(g(x), C(x)) d(g(x), y). Theorem.. Let X be a nonempty and compact subset of a metric space (E, d ), and Y a nonempty subset of a metric space (F, d ). Let C be a multifunction mapping defined on X into Y such that the function x d (g(x), C(x)) is lower semicontinuous over X, where g is a continuous function defined from X into Y. Then, C has a g-fixed point if and only if, for each A X, there exists x X such that d (g(x), C(x)) d (x, A). Proof. It is a consequence of Theorem. by defining Ψ(x, y) = d (g(x), C(x)) d (x, y). Existence of Coincidence Points This Section provides a necessary and sufficient conditions for the existence of coincidence points of two functions defined on a set that may not be compact or convex. Definition.. Let X be a nonempty and compact subset of a metric space (E, d ), and let f and g be two continuous functions over X into a metric space (F, d ). Then, f and g are said to have a coincidence point iff, there exists x X such that f(x) = g(x). Definition.. Let X be a nonempty set in a metric space (E, d ), and let f and g be two functions from X into a metric space (F, d ). The set X is called fg-separate iff, one of the following conditions holds: ) for all A X, there exists x X such that A B(x, d (f(x), g(x))) = ;

0 0 0 0 0 0 ) for all A f(x), there exists x X such that A B(f(x), d (f(x), g(x))) =. ) for all A g(x), there exists x X such that A B(g(x), d (f(x), g(x))) =. Theorem.. (Coincidence point without convexity assumption) Let X be a nonempty and compact subset of a metric space (E, d ), and let f and g be two continuous functions over X into a metric space (F, d ). Then, f and g have a coincidence point if and only if X is fg-separate. Proof. Necessity: It is the same as that of Theorem.. Sufficiency: If the first condition in Definition. is satisfied, let φ : X X R, (x, y) φ(x, y) = d (f(x), g(x)) d (x, y). If the second condition of Definition. is satisfied, let φ : X f(x) R, (x, y) φ(x, y) = d (f(x), g(x)) d (f(x), y). If the third condition of Definition. is satisfied, let φ : X g(x) R, (x, y) φ(x, y) = d (f(x), g(x)) d (g(x), y). The remaining proof of the sufficiency is the same as that in the proof of Theorem.. Theorem.. Let E be a topological space and (F,. ) a normed space. Let f and g be two functions over E into F. Suppose that there exists a compact set X in E such that the restriction of f and g on X are continuous and { (a) f(x) is convex in F ; (b) g(x) f(x), Then, f and g has a coincidence point. Proof. If Conditions (a)-(b) are satisfied, let or { (a ) g(x) is convex in F ; (b ) f(x) g(x). φ : X f(x) R, (x, y) φ(x, y) = f(x) g(x) F g(x) y F. If Conditions - are satisfied, let φ : X g(x) R, (x, y) φ(x, y) = f(x) g(x) F f(x) y F. The remaining proof of the sufficiency is the same as that in the proof of Theorem.. We have the following Corollary. Corollary.. Let f and g be two continuous functions over a compact interval X R into R such that g(x) f(x) or f(x) g(x). Then, f and g has a coincidence point. Proof. See the proof of Corollary..

0 0 0 0 0 0 Existence of Nash Equilibrium As an application of our basic result on the minimax inequality, in this section we provide a result on the existence of pure strategy Nash equilibrium without assuming the convexity of strategy spaces and any form of quasiconcavity of payoff functions. Consider the following noncooperative game in normal form: G = (X i, f i ) i I, () where I = {,..., n} is the finite set of players, X i is player i s strategy space which is a nonempty subset of a topological space E i, and f i : X R is the payoff function of player i. Denote by X = X i the set of strategy profiles of the game and f := (f, f,..., f n) the i I profile of payoff functions. For each player i I, denote by i := {j I such that j i} the set of all players rather than player i. Furthermore, denote by X i = X j the set of j i strategies of the players in coalition i. Definition.. A strategy profile x X is said to be a pure strategy Nash equilibrium of game () iff, i I, y i X i, f i (x i, y i ) f i (x). The aim of each player is to choose a strategy in X i that maximizes his payoff function. Define a function Ψ : X X R by Ψ(x, y) := n {f i (x i, y i ) f i (x)}, (x, y) X X. i= The following theorem generalized Theorem in [] by relaxing the convexity of strategy spaces and 0-transfer quasiconcavity of payoff function. Theorem.. (Nash equilibrium without convexity assumption) Let I = {,..., n} be an indexed finite set, let X i be a nonempty and compact subset of a topological space E i. Suppose that the function Ψ(x, y) is 0-transfer lower semicontinuous in x with respect to X. Then, the game G = (X i, f i ) i I has a Nash equilibrium if and only if, for all A X, there exists x X such that, for each i I, we have f i (y i, x i ) f i (x), for each y A. () Proof. Note that the condition () is equivalent to the function y Ψ(x, y) is 0-locallydominated. Then it is a straightforward consequence of Theorem. and definition of Ψ. Example.. Suppose that in game (), n =, I = {, }, X = X = [, ] [, ], x = (x, x ) and f (x) = x x, f (x) = x x. In this example, X i is not convex, i I, and the function y i f i (x i, y i ) is not quasiconcave for i =, so that the existing theorems on Nash equilibrium, such as in [-,0,-,,] are not applicable. However, we can show the existence of Nash equilibrium by applying Theorem.. Indeed, for each x = (x, x ) and y = (y, y ), Ψ(x, y) = x y x y.

0 0 0 0 0 0 The function Ψ is continuous on X X. For any subset {( y, y ),..., ( k y, k y )} of X, let x = (x, x ) X such that x = max h=,...,k i y and x = min h=,...,k i y. Then, we have Thus, { iy x, i =,..., k, iy x. { x i y x x, i =,..., k, x i y x x. Therefore, Ψ(x, i y) Ψ(x, x), i =,..., k. According to Theorem., this game has a Nash equilibrium. Theorem. can be generalized by relaxing the compactness of X. Theorem.. (Nash aquilibrium without convexity and compactness of strategy sets) Let I = {,..., n} be an indexed finite set and let X i be a nonempty subset of a topological space E i. Suppose that function Ψ : X X R { } satisfies the following conditions: (a) Ψ(x, y) is 0-transfer lower semicontinuous in x with respect to X; (b) there exists {y,..., y k } X such that G(y i ) is compact, where i=,...,k G(y) = {x X : n [f i (x i, y i ) f i (x)] 0}. i= Then, the game G = (X i, f i ) i I has a Nash equilibrium if and only if, for each A X, there exists x X such that, for each i I, we have f i (y i, x i ) f i (x), y A. Conclusion In this paper, we introduced a new condition, called local-dominatedness property, that can be used to characterize existence of equilibria in many problems which may have nonconvex and/or compact sets and have non-quasiconcave functions. We first investigated the existence of equilibrium in minimax inequalities under the local-dominatedness condition. We proved that the local-dominatedness condition is necessary, and further under mild continuity condition, sufficient for the existence of solution in minimax inequality. The basic results on the minimax inequality are then used to get new theorems on the existence of saddle points, fixed points, and coincidence points of functions. As an application of our basic result, we also characterize the existence of pure strategy Nash equilibrium in games with discontinuous and nonquasiconcave payoff functions and nonconvex and noncompact strategy spaces. Acknowledgements The authors would like to thank the two anonymous referees for insightful comments which have substantially improved the quality of the paper

0 0 0 0 0 0 References. Aliprantis, C.B., Border, K.C.: Infinite Dimensional Analysis. Springer-Verlag, New York (). Ansari, Q.H., Lin, Y.C., Yao, J.C.: General KKM Theorem with Applications to Minimax and Variational Inequalities. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications, 0, (000). Ansari, Q.H., Wong, N.C., Yao, J.C.: The Existence of Nonlinear Inequalities. Applied Mathematics Letters,, (). Aubin, J.P., Ekeland, I.: Applied Nonlinear Analysis. Wiley Interscience, New York (). Baye, M.R., Tian, G., Zhou, J.: Characterizations of the Existence of Equilibria in Games with Discontinuous and Non-Quasiconcave Payoffs. The Review of Economic Studies, 0, (). Dasgupta, P., Maskin, E.: The Existence of Equilibrium in Discontinuous Economic Games, I: Theory. The Review of Economic Studies,, (). Debreu, G.: A Social Equilibrium Existence Theorem. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the U. S. A., (). Ding, X.P., Park, S.: Existence of Solutions for Nonlinear Inequalities in G-Convex Spaces. Applied Mathematics Letters,, (). Ding, X.P., Tan, K.K.: A Minimax Inequality with Application to Existence of Equilibrium Points and Fixed Point Theorems. Colloque Mathematics,, () 0. Iusem, A.N., Soca, W.: New Existence Results for Equilibrium Problems. Nonlinear Analysis,, (00). Georgiev, P.G., Tanaka, T.: Vector-Valued Set-Valued Variants of Ky Fan s Inequality. Journal of Nonlinear and Convex Analysis,, (000). Fan, K.: Minimax Inequality and Applications. In: O. Shisha (Ed.), Inequality, vol. III, Academic Press, New York 0 (). Kakutani, S.: A Generalization of Bouwer s Fixed Point Theorem. Duke Mathemtical Journal,, (). Lignola, M.B.: Ky Fan Inequalities and Nash Equilibrium Points without Semicontinuity and Compactness. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications,, (). Lin, L.J.: Applications of a Fixed Point Theorem in G-Convex Space. Nonlinear Analysis,, 0 0 (00). Lin, L.J., Ansari, Q.H., Yu, Z.T., Lai, L.P.: Fixed Point and Maximal Element Theorems with Applications to Abstract Economies and Minimax Inequalities. Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications,, - (00). Lin, L.J., Ansari, L.J.: Collective Fixed Points and Maximal Elements with Applications to Abstract Economies. Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications,, (00). Lin, L.J., Chang, T.H.: S-KKM Theorems, Saddle Points and Minimax Inequalities. Nonlinear Analysis,, (). Lin, L.J., Park, S.: On Some Generalized Quasi-Equilibrium Problems. Journal Mathematics Analysis and Applications,, () 0. Nash, J.F.: Noncooperative Games. Annals of Maths,, (). Nessah, R., Larbani, M.: g-maximum Equality. In W. Takahashi and T. Tanaka (eds.), Nonlinear Analysis and Convex Analysis (Hinshu 00), Yokohama, Yokohama Publishers, 00 (00). Nessah, R., Chu, C.: Quasivariational Equation. Mathematical Inequalities and Applications,, 0 (00). Nishimura, K., Friedman, J.: Existence of Nash Equilibriumin n-person Games without Quasi- Concavity. International Economic Review,, (). Reny, J.P.: On the Existence of Pure and Mixed Strategy Nash Equilibria in Discontinuous Games. Econometrica,, 0 0 (). Rosen, J.B.: Existence and Uniqueness of Equilibrium Point for Concave n-person Games. Econometrica,, 0 (). Simons, S.: Two Function Minimax Theorem and Variational Inequalities for Functions on Compact and Noncompact Sets, with some Comments on Fixed-Point Theorems. Proceedings of Symposia in Pure Mathematics,, (). Tian, G., Zhou, Z.: Quasi-Inequalities without the Concavity Assumption. Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications,, (). Yao, J.C.: Nash Equilibria in n-person Games without Convexity. Applied Mathematics letters,, (). Yu, J., Yuan, X.Z.: The Study of Pareto Equilibria for Multiobjective Games by Fixed Point Theorems and Ky Fan Minimax Inequality Methods. Research Report, no /, Department of institute of mathematics, Guizhou Institute of technology, China () 0. Yuan, X.Z.: KKM Principal, Ky Fan Minimax Inequalities and Fixed Point Theorems. Nonlinear World,, ()