Why exergy economics is right and the neoclassical duality of quantities and prices is wrong

Similar documents
The Productive Power of Energy and its Taxation

Thermodynamic Laws, Economic Methods and the Productive Power of Energy

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

ECON 582: The Neoclassical Growth Model (Chapter 8, Acemoglu)

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Endogenous Growth Theory

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

From Difference to Differential Equations I

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Topic 5: The Difference Equation

Theoretical premises of the Keynesian approach

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

A Note on the Ramsey Growth Model with the von Bertalanffy Population Law

Input-biased technical progress and the aggregate elasticity of substitution: Evidence from 14 EU Member States

Solution to Homework 2 - Exogeneous Growth Models

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

Lecture 5: The neoclassical growth model

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

A Summary of Economic Methodology

Cointegration of output, capital, labor, and energy

Chapter 9. Natural Resources and Economic Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

14.05: Section Handout #1 Solow Model

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

Endogenous Growth: AK Model

Business Cycles: The Classical Approach

Modern Urban and Regional Economics

Source: US. Bureau of Economic Analysis Shaded areas indicate US recessions research.stlouisfed.org

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Chapter 9 Solow. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos. Computational Economics: a concise introduction

Macroeconomic models with physical and monetary dimension based on constrained dynamics

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies:

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Equilibrium Conditions for the Simple New Keynesian Model

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Macroeconomics Theory II

THE SOLOW-SWAN MODEL WITH A NEGATIVE LABOR GROWTH RATE

Foundation of (virtually) all DSGE models (e.g., RBC model) is Solow growth model

EC9A2 Advanced Macro Analysis - Class #1

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Online Appendix I: Wealth Inequality in the Standard Neoclassical Growth Model

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 2: Dynamics in Aggregate Demand and Supply

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

On Returns to Scale Assumption in Endogenous Growth

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

The Solow Model. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. January 26, Econ520

Rice University. Fall Semester Final Examination ECON501 Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Writing Period: Three Hours

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

Economic Growth

Chapter 9. Natural Resources and Economic Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital. Lawrence J. Christiano

DYNAMIC LECTURE 1 UNIVERSITY OF MARYLAND: ECON 600

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Real Business Cycle Models. Jordi Galí. Universitat Pompeu Fabra Spring 2018

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

A Generalized Solow Nonautonomous Model with Delay and Bounded Population Growth

Macroeconomics I. University of Tokyo. Lecture 12. The Neo-Classical Growth Model: Prelude to LS Chapter 11.

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Problem 1 (30 points)

Advanced Macroeconomics

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Chapter 3 Task 1-4. Growth and Innovation Fridtjof Zimmermann

Monetary Policy and Equilibrium Indeterminacy in a Cash in Advance Economy with Investment. Abstract

1 The Basic RBC Model

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Schumpeterian Growth Models

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0

The welfare cost of energy insecurity

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

Market Structure and Productivity: A Concrete Example. Chad Syverson

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

General motivation behind the augmented Solow model

Notes on Econ 102 Sect. 2, Fall 2005

Dynamic Problem Set 5 Solutions

Chapter 12 Ramsey Cass Koopmans model

ECON 186 Class Notes: Derivatives and Differentials

Learning and Global Dynamics

Aggregate Production Function. Production. Mark Huggett. Georgetown University. January 11, 2018

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Foundations of the Sticky Wage Approach and a Critical Commentary

Lagrange Principle and the Distribution of Wealth

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Thus necessary and sufficient conditions for A to be positive definite are:

3 GROWTH AND CAPITAL ACCUMULATION: THE SOLOW MODEL

Transcription:

Why exergy economics is right and the neoclassical duality of quantities and prices is wrong Reiner Kümmel, Tobias Winkler Institute for Theoretical Physics and Astrophysics, University of Würzburg, Germany in cooperation with Florian Weiser and Dietmar Lindenberger Institute of Energy Economics, University of Cologne, Germany International Exergy-Economics Workshop University of Sussex, Brighton, UK, 13-15 July 2016 Why exergy economics is right p.1/24

Program 1. Energy, entropy, and exergy 2. Energy and economic growth 3. How technological constraints destroy the neoclassical cost share theorem 4. Summary Details in: R. K., The Second Law of Economics: Energy, Entropy, and the Origins of Wealth. Springer, New York, Dordrecht, Heidelberg, London, 2011; R. K., D. Lindenberger, F. Weiser, The economic power of energy and the need to integrate it with energy policy, Energy Policy 86, 833-843 (2015). Why exergy economics is right p.2/24

Energy, entropy, and exergy Nothing happens in the world without energy conversion and entropy production. First and Second Law of Thermodynamics Why exergy economics is right p.3/24

Energy, entropy, and exergy Nothing happens in the world without energy conversion and entropy production. First and Second Law of Thermodynamics First Law: Energy = Exergy + Anergy= const. Exergy: valuable part of energy, convertible into useful work. Anergy: useless; e.g. heat dumped into the environment. Why exergy economics is right p.3/24

Energy, entropy, and exergy Nothing happens in the world without energy conversion and entropy production. First and Second Law of Thermodynamics First Law: Energy = Exergy + Anergy= const. Exergy: valuable part of energy, convertible into useful work. Anergy: useless; e.g. heat dumped into the environment. Second Law: unavoidable entropy production 1) destroys exergy, enhances useless anergy: the technologies of energy conversion determine, how much exergy one gets from primary energy limits to improvements of energy efficiency! 2) results in polluting emissions of particles (NO X, SO 2, greenhouse gases) and heat: entropy production density in a non-equilibrium system of N different sorts of particles k: σ S,dis ( r,t) = N k=1 j k[ (µ k /T) + f k /T] + j Q (1/T)> 0. j k = particle current density, j Q = heat current density, ( : gradient, T = temperature, µ k = chemical potentials, f k = external forces.) Why exergy economics is right p.3/24

Global consumption of primary (en/ex)ergy Source: International Energy Agency KeyWorld Statistics 2015 Why exergy economics is right p.4/24

Oil price shocks Development of the price of one barrel of crude oil since 1861 in inflation-corrected US 2014 (upper curve) and in dollar prices of the day (lower curve). Why exergy economics is right p.5/24

Pre-analytic vision Capital (stock) = all energy-conversion devices and information processors, and all buildings and installations necessary for their protection and operation. From: The Impact of Energy on Industrial Growth, Energy 7, 189-203 (1982). Why exergy economics is right p.6/24

KLEC model Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 13 415-433 (2002) Journal of Non-Equilibrium Thermodynamics 35 145-179 (2010) New Journal of Physics 16 125008 (2014) Energy Policy 86 833-843 (2015) Output (value added) and inputs at time t, normalized to their quantities Y 0,K 0,L 0,E 0 in the base year t 0 : y(t) = Y (t)/y 0 (normalized output), k(t) = K(t)/K 0 (normalized capital stock), l(t) = L(t)/L 0 (normalized labor), e(t) = E(t)/E 0 (normalized energy input). Creativity causes an explicit time dependence of the production function y = y(k,l,e;t), which is a state function, i.e. it depends only on the actual magnitudes of k,l,e at time t, and not on the history of the system. Why exergy economics is right p.7/24

Growth equation Infinitesimal changes of output, dy, are related to those of capital, dk, labor, de and time, dt by the growth equation (which is obtained from the total differential of the production function): dy y = αdk k + βdl l + γ de e + δ dt t t 0. The output elasticities (productive powers) α(k,l,e) k y y k, β(k,l,e) l y y l, γ(k,l,e) e y y e, δ t t 0 y y t give the weights, with which relative changes of the production factors k,l,e and of time time t contribute to the relative change of output. Textbook economics: α 0.25, β 0.7, γ 0.05 (from unconstrained optimization) + technological progress Why exergy economics is right p.8/24

Solow Residual in FR Germany and USA Difference between empirical output (black) and theoret. output (red) ( Solow Residual) at cost-share weighting of production factors in the energy-dependent Cobb-Douglas production function is attributed to technological progress by textbook economics. Why exergy economics is right p.9/24

Diff. equations for output elasticities Standard requirement on production functions (PF) is twice differentiability with respect to k, l, e second-order mixed derivatives of PF must be equal. Furthermore: α + β + γ = 1 at any fixed time t k α k + l α l + e α e k β k + l β l + e β e = 0, = 0, l α l = k β k. The most general solutions of these equations are: α = A(l/k,e/k), β = l k A l dk + J(l/e). Why exergy economics is right p.10/24

Special solutions: Output elasticities Trivial solutions: constants α 0,β 0,γ 0 = 1 α 0 β 0. Simplest non-trivial solutions, satisfying asymptotic technical-economic boundary conditions: α = a l+e k (Law of diminishing returns: α 0, if (l + e)/k 0 ), β = a(c l e l k ) (Substitution of capital and energy for labor as automation increases: β 0, if k k m and e ck m ), γ = 1 α β (At a given point in time the weights with which capital, labor and energy contribute to the growth of output add up to 100 % ). The output elasticities of neoclassical production functions, e.g. CES functions, are solutions, too; see: Energy and the State of Nations, Energy 36 6010-6018 (2011) Why exergy economics is right p.11/24

Production functions The production function is the integral of the growth equation: y(k, l, e; t) = y 0 (t) exp { k,l,e k 0,l 0,e 0 [ α dk k + β dl l + γ de ] } ds. e Why exergy economics is right p.12/24

Production functions The production function is the integral of the growth equation: y(k, l, e; t) = y 0 (t) exp { k,l,e k 0,l 0,e 0 [ α dk k + β dl l + γ de ] } ds. e The constants α 0, β 0, γ 0 yield the energy-dependent Cobb-Douglas production function y CDE = y 0 k α 0l β 0e γ 0. Neoclassical cost-share weighting: α 0 0.25, β 0 0.70, γ 0 0.05 Solow residual. Why exergy economics is right p.12/24

Production functions The production function is the integral of the growth equation: y(k, l, e; t) = y 0 (t) exp { k,l,e k 0,l 0,e 0 [ α dk k + β dl l + γ de ] } ds. e The constants α 0, β 0, γ 0 yield the energy-dependent Cobb-Douglas production function y CDE = y 0 k α 0l β 0e γ 0. Neoclassical cost-share weighting: α 0 0.25, β 0 0.70, γ 0 0.05 Solow residual. The non-trivial α = a l+e k, β = a(c l e l k ), γ = 1 α β yield the time-dependent LinEx production function: [ y L1 (t) = y 0 (t)eexp a(t)(2 l + e k ) + a(t)c(t)( l ] e 1) a(t) = capital-effectiveness parameter, c(t) = energy-demand parameter, modeled by logistics or taylor series, determined by nonlinear (Levenberg-Marquardt) OLS fitting of y L1 (t) to y empirical (t), subject to the restrictions: α 0, β 0, γ 0.. Why exergy economics is right p.12/24

FR Germany, Total Economy Left: Empirical time series of capital, labor, and (primary) energy. Right: Growth of output; black: empirical, red: computed with LinEx function y L1 (t) = y 0 (t)eexp [ a(t)(2 l+e k ) + a(t)c(t)( l e 1)]. The technology parameters (a, c) become time-dependent, when creativity acts. If time series of exergy inputs are available, (a, c) may be constant. Why exergy economics is right p.13/24

FR Germany, Industry Left: Empirical time series of capital, labor, and (primary) energy. Right: Growth of output; black: empirical, red: computed with LinEx function. Why exergy economics is right p.14/24

Japan, Industries Total Economy k, l, e 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 Production Factors, Japan, Industries Capital Stock, K 1965 = 85084 Bill. Yen 1985 Labor, L 1965 = 72 Bill. h/year Energy, E 1965 = 6354 PJ/year 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 Year k e l q(t)=q(t)/q 1965 4,5 4,0 3,5 3,0 2,5 2,0 1,5 q Lt (t) Output, Japan, Industries q empirical (t) Q 1965 =97751 Bill. Yen 1985 a(t) Logistic Function c(t) Logistic Function 1,0 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 Year Left: Empirical time series of capital, labor, and (primary) energy. Right: Growth of output; black: empirical, red: computed with LinEx function. Why exergy economics is right p.15/24

USA, Total Economy 3,0 2,5 Production Factors, USA, Total Economy Capital Stock, K 1960 = 2685 Bill. $ 1992 Labor, L 1960 = 118 Bill. h/years Energy, E 1960 = 39051 PJ/years k 3,0 2,5 Output, USA, Total Economy q Lt (t) q emprical (t) Q 1960 =2263 Bill. $ 1992 k, l, e 2,0 1,5 1,0 e l q=q(t)/q 1960 2,0 1,5 1,0 a(t), c(t) Logistic Functions q 0, 1 (1960-1965)=1.046 q 0, 2 (1966-1996)=1.115 1960 1970 1980 1990 Year 1960 1970 1980 1990 Year Left: Empirical time series of capital, labor, and (primary) energy. Right: Growth of output; black: empirical, red: computed with LinEx function. Why exergy economics is right p.16/24

Output elasticities: FR Germany Time-averaged output elasticities in the total economy (top) and in the industrial sector (bottom) of the FR Germany; creativity without reunification peak. Why exergy economics is right p.17/24

Output elasticities: Japan Time-averaged output elasticities in the Japanese sector Industries, which produces about 90% of Japanese GDP. Why exergy economics is right p.18/24

Output elasticities: USA Time-averaged output elasticities in the total US economy. Why exergy economics is right p.19/24

Profit optimization, constraints, duality Production factors X 1 K, X 2 L, X 3 E. Exogeneously given prices per factor unit (p 1, p 2, p 3 ) p. Total factor cost is p(t) X(t) = 3 i=1 p i(t)x i (t). Technological constraints f η (X, t) = 0 = f ρ (X, t). Economic equilibrium: Maximize profit function [ Y (X; t) G(X,p, t) Y (X, t) p X ] 3 p i (t)x i (t) + µ η f η (X, t) + µ ρ f ρ (X, t) i=1 = 0, Y f η (X, t) f ρ (X, t) p i + µ η + µ ρ = 0, i = 1, 2, 3. X i X i X i Without constraints µ η = 0 = µ ρ. Profit-maximizing equilibrium values would be X 1M (p), X 2M (p), X 3M (p). With X M (p) the profit function would turn into the only price-dependent Legendre transform of the PF Y (X, t) (i.e duality of quantities and prices): G(X M (p),p) = Y (X M (p)) p X M (p) g(p). Non-existent, because of the technological constraints. Why exergy economics is right p.20/24

Cost share theorem? Technological constraints: 1) the degree of capacity utilization η(k, L, E) 1; 2) degree of automation ρ(k, L, E) ρ T (t) 1. With slack variables f η (X, t) = 0, f ρ (X, t) = 0. Optimization of profit yields equilibrium conditions for the X i : ǫ i X i Y Y X i = X i [p i + s i ] 3 i=1 X i [p i + s i ], s i µ η f η X i µ ρ f ρ X i. ǫ i = output elasticity of Faktor X i, p i = market price of unit of X i ; s i = shadow price of X i. µ η, µ ρ are Lagrange multipliers, depend upon ǫ i. Output elasticities are not equal to factor cost shares. Technological constraints: Binding, if the state of the economy were exclusively determined by profit maximization a) At least one non-zero component of s i, b) less than 3 independent factors. Non-binding, if the real-world state of the economy is not exclusively determined by profit maximization a) equilibrium not at boundary, b) 3 independent factors. Why exergy economics is right p.21/24

Path in the cost mountain Barrier from the limit to capacity utilization, η = 1, and neg. cost gradients along the path of Germany s industrial sector in the cost mountain between 1960 and 1989, projected onto the l k e k plane. Why exergy economics is right p.22/24

Summary Energy (exergy) conversion drives industrial growth. It is coupled to entropy production, which, in turn, results in exergy destruction and emissions. Why exergy economics is right p.23/24

Summary Energy (exergy) conversion drives industrial growth. It is coupled to entropy production, which, in turn, results in exergy destruction and emissions. In modern economies, energy s output elasticity far outweighs its small cost share, while for labor just the opposite is true. This contradicts standard economics. The long-term growth of the capital stock, whose furnaces, heat engines, and information processors are activated by energy conversion, determines the long-term growth of output. Why exergy economics is right p.23/24

Summary Energy (exergy) conversion drives industrial growth. It is coupled to entropy production, which, in turn, results in exergy destruction and emissions. In modern economies, energy s output elasticity far outweighs its small cost share, while for labor just the opposite is true. This contradicts standard economics. The long-term growth of the capital stock, whose furnaces, heat engines, and information processors are activated by energy conversion, determines the long-term growth of output. Barriers from technological constraints prevent industrial economies from reaching the state where output elasticities would equal factor cost shares. No duality of quantities and prices. Real-life economies evolve at some distance from the barriers, observing also soft constraints due to entrepreneurial preference for flexibility according to customer demand, and social and legal obligations as well. Why exergy economics is right p.23/24

Change of market s legal framework In order to fight increasing unemployment (and state indebtedness) and stimulate energy conservation and emission mitigation the disequilibrium between the output elasticities and cost shares of labor and energy should be reduced by: shifting the burden of taxes and levies from labor to energy so that these factors cost shares come closer to the factors output elasticities; tax and levy shares: labor 10-20%, capital 30-40%, energy 40-50%, increasing the tax per energy unit according to progress in energy conservation so that revenues remain constant. Border tax adjustments according to the energy required for production and transportation of border-crossing goods prevent competitive disadvantages in relation to not-energy-taxing economies. No recessions like that due to oil price shocks: the wealth created by energy is not transferred abroad but only redistributed within the country. BBC World Service Poll (2007): People will accept higher energy taxes, if the total tax bill stayed the same. Why exergy economics is right p.24/24