Lecture 4: Bayesian VAR

Similar documents
Computational Macroeconomics. Prof. Dr. Maik Wolters Friedrich Schiller University Jena

Estimating and Accounting for the Output Gap with Large Bayesian Vector Autoregressions

Warwick Business School Forecasting System. Summary. Ana Galvao, Anthony Garratt and James Mitchell November, 2014

Bayesian Compressed Vector Autoregressions

doi /j. issn % % JOURNAL OF CHONGQING UNIVERSITY Social Science Edition Vol. 22 No.

New Information Response Functions

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Relationships Among Prices of Rubber in ASEAN: Bayesian Structural VAR Model

Dynamic Factor Models and Factor Augmented Vector Autoregressions. Lawrence J. Christiano

Identifying SVARs with Sign Restrictions and Heteroskedasticity

Analyzing and Forecasting Output Gap and Inflation Using Bayesian Vector Auto Regression (BVAR) Method: A Case of Pakistan

Forecasting the Polish Inflation Using Bayesian VAR Models with Seasonality

LARGE TIME-VARYING PARAMETER VARS

Assessing Structural Convergence between Romanian Economy and Euro Area: A Bayesian Approach

Identifying Aggregate Liquidity Shocks with Monetary Policy Shocks: An Application using UK Data

Structural VAR Models and Applications

Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo

Dimitrios P. Louzis* Steady-state priors and Bayesian variable selection in VAR forecasting

Forecasting with Bayesian Vector Autoregressions

Large Vector Autoregressions with asymmetric priors and time varying volatilities

Lecture 1: Information and Structural VARs

Identification of Economic Shocks by Inequality Constraints in Bayesian Structural Vector Autoregression

Class 4: VAR. Macroeconometrics - Fall October 11, Jacek Suda, Banque de France

Structural Interpretation of Vector Autoregressions with Incomplete Identification: Revisiting the Role of Oil Supply and Demand Shocks

Bayesian Graphical Models for Structural Vector AutoregressiveMarch Processes 21, / 1

Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme?

A Primer on Vector Autoregressions

Using VARs and TVP-VARs with Many Macroeconomic Variables

A primer on Structural VARs

Reducing Dimensions in a Large TVP-VAR

A Mixed Frequency Steady-State Bayesian Vector Autoregression: Forecasting the Macroeconomy

Bayesian Macroeconometrics

Do BVAR Models Forecast Turkish GDP Better Than UVAR Models?

IN this paper, we study the choice of the informativeness of

Modern Macroeconomics and Regional Economic Modeling

Introduction to Macroeconomics

CENTRE FOR CENTRAL BANKING STUDIES

1. Shocks. This version: February 15, Nr. 1

Large time varying parameter VARs for macroeconomic forecasting

BEAR 4.2. Introducing Stochastic Volatility, Time Varying Parameters and Time Varying Trends. A. Dieppe R. Legrand B. van Roye ECB.

Assessing Monetary Policy Models: Bayesian Inference for Heteroskedastic Structural VARs

Combining Macroeconomic Models for Prediction

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

Working Paper Series

Estimating Macroeconomic Models: A Likelihood Approach

Katsuhiro Sugita Faculty of Law and Letters, University of the Ryukyus. Abstract

Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme?

Oil price and macroeconomy in Russia. Abstract

Multivariate forecasting with VAR models

Inference in VARs with Conditional Heteroskedasticity of Unknown Form

1. Introduction. Hang Qian 1 Iowa State University

1.2. Structural VARs

MFx Macroeconomic Forecasting

Formulating, Estimating, and Solving Dynamic Equilibrium Models: an Introduction. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Vector Autoregressive Model. Vector Autoregressions II. Estimation of Vector Autoregressions II. Estimation of Vector Autoregressions I.

STRATHCLYDE DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS FORECASTING WITH MEDIUM AND LARGE BAYESIAN VARS GARY KOOP NO

Multiple Time Series Priors

Forecasting with Bayesian Global Vector Autoregressive Models

Shrinkage in Set-Identified SVARs

WORKING PAPER NO EVALUATING REAL-TIME VAR FORECASTS WITH AN INFORMATIVE DEMOCRATIC PRIOR

Bayesian Structural VAR models: an extended approach. February 28, PRELIMINARY DO NOT CIRCULATE (most recent version available here)

Inference Based on SVARs Identified with Sign and Zero Restrictions: Theory and Applications

Bayesian Compressed Vector Autoregressions

Stochastic Search Variable Selection in Vector Error Correction Models with an Application to a Model of the UK Macroeconomy

Optimal Monetary Policy in a Data-Rich Environment

Macroeconometric Modelling

Evaluating FAVAR with Time-Varying Parameters and Stochastic Volatility

MODERN FORECASTING MODELS IN ACTION: IMPROVING MACROECONOMIC ANALYSES AT CENTRAL BANKS

Structural Vector Autoregressions with Markov Switching. Markku Lanne University of Helsinki. Helmut Lütkepohl European University Institute, Florence

Structural VARs II. February 17, 2016

Regime-Switching Cointegration

WERE THERE REGIME SWITCHES IN US MONETARY POLICY? I. INTRODUCTION

Time-Varying Vector Autoregressive Models with Structural Dynamic Factors

Labor-Supply Shifts and Economic Fluctuations. Technical Appendix

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Bayesian modelling of real GDP rate in Romania

Identification of SVAR Models by Combining Sign Restrictions With External Instruments *

DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS

Methods for Computing Marginal Data Densities from the Gibbs Output

Inference in Bayesian Proxy-SVARs

Real-Time Nowcasting with a Bayesian Mixed Frequency Model with Stochastic Volatility

Nonperforming Loans and Rules of Monetary Policy

Title. Description. var intro Introduction to vector autoregressive models

Identification in Structural VAR models with different volatility regimes

Inference when identifying assumptions are doubted. A. Theory B. Applications

Stargazing with Structural VARs: Shock Identification via Independent Component Analysis

Inference when identifying assumptions are doubted. A. Theory. Structural model of interest: B 1 y t1. u t. B m y tm. u t i.i.d.

Common Time Variation of Parameters in Reduced-Form Macroeconomic Models

Time Series Analysis for Macroeconomics and Finance

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations?

Restrictions Search for Panel Vector Autoregressive Models

ECON 4160: Econometrics-Modelling and Systems Estimation Lecture 9: Multiple equation models II

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING

Staff Working Paper No. 756 Bayesian vector autoregressions

Prior Selection for Vector Autoregressions

Working Paper SerieS. Granger-Causal-Priority and Choice of Variables in Vector Autoregressions. NO 1600 / october 2013

Time-varying sparsity in dynamic regression models

A Theory of Data-Oriented Identification with a SVAR Application

2.5 Forecasting and Impulse Response Functions

A quasi-bayesian nonparametric approach to time varying parameter VAR models Job Market Paper

Transcription:

s Lecture 4: Bayesian VAR Hedibert Freitas Lopes The University of Chicago Booth School of Business 5807 South Woodlawn Avenue, Chicago, IL 60637 http://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/hedibert.lopes hlopes@chicagobooth.edu

s 1 VAR s 2 3 4 5 Outline

s Del Negro and Schorfheide (2011) says VAR at a glance VARs appear to be straightforward multivariate generalizations of univariate autoregressive models. They turn out to be one of the key empirical tools in modern macroeconomics. Sims (1980) proposed that VARs should replace large-scale macroeconometric models inherited from the 1960s, because the latter imposed incredible restrictions, which were largely inconsistent with the notion that economic agents take the effect of todays choices on tomorrows utility into account. VARs have been used for macroeconomic forecasting and policy analysis to investigate the sources of business-cycle fluctuations and to provide a benchmark against which modern dynamic macroeconomic theories can be evaluated.

s Let y t = (y t1,..., y tq ) contain q (macroeconomic) time series observed at time t. The (basic) VAR(p) can be written as where y t = B 1 y t 1 +... + B p y t p + u t u t i.i.d. N(0, Σ) and B 1,..., B p are (q q) autoregressive matrices Σ is an (q q) variance-covariance matrix

s Multivariate regression More compactly, y t = Bx t + u t u t N(0, Σ), where B = (B 1,..., B p ) is the (q qp) autoregressive matrix, x t = (y t 1,..., y t p) is qp-dimensional.

s Let Y = (y 1,..., y n ) is n q, X = (x 1,..., x n ) is n qp, U = (y 1,..., u n ) is n q. Matrix normal Then Y = XB + U U N(0, I n, Σ).

s Multivariate normal Let y i = (y 1i,..., y ni ) be the n-dimensional vector with the observations for time series i, for i = 1,..., q. Let y = vec(y ) = (y 1, y 2,..., y q). Similarly, β = vec(b ) and u = vec(u). Then y = (I q X )β + u u N(0, Σ I n ).

s or 0 B @ y t y t 1 y t 2. y t p+1 h-step ahead forecast 1 0 1 0 B 1 B 2 B p 1 B p I q 0 0 0 = 0 I q 0 0 C B A @......... C B.. A @ 0 0 I q 0 y t = Ay t 1 + u t. y t 1 y t 2 y t 3. y t p 1 0 + C B A @ u t u t 1 u t 2. u t p+1 1 C A Therefore, the h-step ahead forecast is Z y t(h) = F (A, yt, h)p(b, Σ data)d(b, Σ), where the forecast function F (A, y t, h) = A h y t is a highly nonlinear function of B 1,..., B p.

s A VAR(p) is covariance-stationary if all values of z satisfying lie outside the unit circle. I q B 1 z B 2 z 2 B p z p = 0 This is equivalent to all eigenvalues of A lying inside the unit circle.

s Vector MA( ) representation If all eigenvalues of A lie inside the unit circle, then with y t = Ψ i u t i, i=0 Ψ 0 = I q Ψ s = B 1 Ψ s 1 + B 2 Ψ s 2 + + B p Ψ s p for s = 1, 2,... Ψ s = 0 for s < 0

s Variance Decomposition The mean square error (MSE) of the h-step ahead forecast is Σ + Ψ 1 ΣΨ 1 + + Ψ h 1 ΣΨ h 1. The error u t N(0, Σ) can be orthogonalized by ε t = A 1 u t N(0, D) where Σ = ADA and D is diagonal (for instance, via singular value decomposition or Cholesky decomposition). The MSE of the h-step ahead forecast can be rewritten as The conbribution of the jth orthogonalized innovation to the MSE is d j (a j a j + Ψ 1 a j a jψ 1 + + Ψ h 1 a j a jψ h 1 )

s Impulse-response function The matrix Ψ s has the interpretation y t+s u s = Ψ s, that is, the (i, j) element of Ψ s identifies the consequences of a one-unit increase in the innovation of variable j at time t for the value of variable i at time t + s, holding all other innovations at all dates constant. A plot of the (i, j) element of Ψ s, y t+s,i u s,i, as a function of s is called the impulse-response function. Similar to the forecast function, the impulse-response function is also highly nonlinear on B 1,..., B q.

s Simulated example 1 Simulating 1000 observations from a trivariate VAR(2) 2 0.7 0.1 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.0 µ = 1 B 1 = 0.0 0.4 0.1 B 2 = 0.0 0.1 0.1 0 0.9 0.0 0.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 and 0.26 0.03 0.00 Σ = 0.03 0.09 0.00. 0.00 0.00 0.81 Posterior summaries based on 1000 draws. 1 Based on Lütkepohl s (2007) Problem 2.3 and using Sims code (later slides).

p(µ data) VAR s 0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 mu(1) 0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 mu(2) 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 mu(3) 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 1.0 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0

p(b i data) VAR s 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 B1(1,1) 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 0 2 4 6 8 B1(1,2) 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 0 5 10 15 20 B1(1,3) 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 0 2 4 6 8 10 B2(1,1) 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 0 2 4 6 8 B2(1,2) 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 0 5 10 15 20 B2(1,3) 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 0 5 10 15 B1(2,1) 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 B1(2,2) 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 B1(2,3) 0 5 10 15 B2(2,1) 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 B2(2,2) 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 B2(2,3) 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 B1(3,1) B1(3,2) B1(3,3) B2(3,1) B2(3,2) B2(3,3) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 0 1 2 3 4 5 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 0 1 2 3 4 5 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0

p(σ data) VAR s 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 Sigma(1,1) 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0 5 10 15 20 Sigma(1,2) 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0 5 10 15 20 Sigma(1,3) 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Sigma(2,1) Sigma(2,2) Sigma(2,3) 0 5 10 15 20 0 10 20 30 40 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Sigma(3,1) Sigma(3,2) Sigma(3,3) 0 5 10 15 20 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 0 5 10 15 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0

s Response of Y1 Response of Y1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.10 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.0 0.1 0.5 Shock on Y1 0 10 20 30 40 50 Steps Shock on Y2 Response of Y2 Response of Y2 0.05 0.10 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.00 0.15 Shock on Y1 0 10 20 30 40 50 Steps Shock on Y2 Impulse response Response of Y3 Response of Y3 0.10 0.05 0.05 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.15 0.00 0.05 Shock on Y1 0 10 20 30 40 50 Steps Shock on Y2 0 10 20 30 40 50 Steps 0 10 20 30 40 50 Steps 0 10 20 30 40 50 Steps Shock on Y3 Shock on Y3 Shock on Y3 Response of Y1 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 Response of Y2 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.1 Response of Y3 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 0 10 20 30 40 50 Steps 0 10 20 30 40 50 Steps 0 10 20 30 40 50 Steps

s Real data example 2 Monthly real stock returns, real interest rates, real industrial production growth and the inflation rate (1947.1 1987.12) 2 Section 11.5 of Zivot and Wang (2003).

s Posterior means E(µ data) = ( 0.0074 0.0002 0.0010 0.0019 ) E(B 1 data) = 0.24 0.81 1.50 0.00 0.00 0.88 0.71 0.00 0.01 0.06 0.46 0.01 0.03 0.38 0.07 0.35 E(B 2 data) = 0.05 0.35 0.06 0.19 0.00 0.04 0.01 0.00 0.01 0.59 0.25 0.02 0.04 0.33 0.04 0.09

s Impulse-response functions

s Variance decomposition

s Recall that β = vec(b ). Prior shrinkage Let β i be column i of B : B = (β 1,..., β q ). Therefore, β = (β 1,..., β q) with β i a vector of dimension qp corresponding to all autoregressive coefficients from equation i. : q = 3, p = 2 b 1,11 b 1,12 b 1,13 b 2,11 b 2,12 b 2,13 B = b 1,21 b 1,22 b 1,23 b 2,21 b 2,22 b 2,23 = b 1,31 b 1,32 b 1,33 b 2,31 b 2,32 b 2,33 β 1 β 2 β 3

s Litterman s (1980,1986) advocates that β i N(β i0, V i0 ) with V i0 chosen to center the individual equations around the random walk with drift: y ti = µ i + y t 1,i + u ti. This amounts to: Shrinking the diagonal elements of B 1 toward one, Shrinking the remaining coefficients of B 1,..., B p toward zero, In addition: Shrinking the number of lags p towards one, Own lags should explain more of the variation than the lags of other variables in the equation.

s V i0 is diagonal with elements θ 2 λ 2 k 2 σ2 i σ 2 j for coefficients on lags of variable j i, and for coefficients on own lags. λ 2 k 2 Specifying V i0 The error matrix Σ is assumed to be diagonal, fixed and known Σ = diag(σ 2 1,..., σ 2 q).

s on (β, Σ) Kadiyala and Karlsson (1993,1997) extend the : Normal-Wishart prior N(β 0, Σ Ω)IW (Σ 0, α) Jeffreys prior p(β, Σ) Σ (q+1)/2 Normal-Diffuse prior β N(β 0, V 0 ) p(σ) Σ (q+1)/2 Extended Natural Conjugate (ENC) prior Kadiyala and Karlsson (1993) use MC integration. Kadiyala and Karlsson (1997) use Gibbs sampler.

s

s Kadiyala and Karlsson (1997) revisited Litterman (1986): Annual growth rates of real GNP (RGNPG), Annual inflation rates (INFLA), Unemployment rate (UNEMP) Logarithm of nominal money supply (M1) Logarithm of gross private domestic investment (INVEST), Interest rate on four- to six-month commercial paper (CPRATE) Change in business inventories (CBI). Quarterly data from 1948:1 to 1981:1 (133 observations). Out-of-sample forecast: 1980:2 to 1986:4 q = 7, p = 6 7 + 6(7 2 ) = 301 parameters.

s Time series

s Root mean square error

s They argue that and... our preferred choice is the Normal-Wishart when the prior beliefs are of the Litterman type. For more general prior beliefs... the Normal-Diffuse and EN priors are strong alternatives to the Normal-Wishart.

s Rubio-Ramírez, Waggoner and Zha (2010) say that Since the seminal work by Sims (1980), identification of structural vector autoregressions (SVARs) has been an unresolved theoretical issue. Filling this theoretical gap is of vital importance because impulse responses based on SVARs have been widely used for policy analysis and to provide stylized facts for dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models.

s Let P c,t is the price index of commodities. Y t is output. R t is the nominal short-term interest rate. Trivariate SVAR(1) representation: a 11 log P c,t + 0.0 log Y t + a 31 R t = c 1 + b 11 log P c,t 1 + b 21 log Y t 1 + b 31 R t 1 + ε 1,t a 12 log P c,t + a 22 log Y t + 0.0R t = c 2 + b 12 log P c,t 1 + b 22 log Y t 1 + b 32 R t 1 + ε 2,t a 13 log P c,t + a 23 log Y t + a 33 R t = c 3 + b 13 log P c,t 1 + b 23 log Y t 1 + b 33 R t 1 + ε 3,t 1st eq. monetary policy equation. 2nd eq. characterizes behaviour of finished-goods producers. 3rd eq. commodity prices are set in active competitive markets.

s The (basic) SVAR(p) can be written as A 0 y t = A 1 y t 1 +... + A p y t p + u t u t i.i.d. N(0, I q ), where A = (A 1,..., A p ) B i = A 1 0 A i i = 1,..., p B = A 1 0 A Σ = (A 0 A 0 ) 1 Much of the SVAR literature involves exactly identified models.

s Exact identification Define g such that g(a 0, A) = (A 1 0 A, (A 0A 0 ) 1 ). Consider an SVAR with restrictions represented by R. Definition: The SVAR is exactly identified if and only if, for almost any reduced-form parameter point (B, Σ), there exists a unique structural parameter point (A 0, A) R such that g(a 0, A) = (B, Σ). Waggoner and Zha (2003) developed an efficient MCMC algorithm to generate draws from a restricted A 0 matrix.

s 0 A 0 = B @ Illustration 1 PS PS MP MD Inf log Y a 11 a 12 0 a 14 a 15 log P 0 a 22 0 a 14 a 25 R 0 0 a 33 a 34 a 35 log M 0 0 a 43 a 44 a 45 log P c 0 0 0 0 a 15 where log Y : log gross domestic product (GDP) log P: log GDP deflator R: nominal short-term interest rate log M: log M3 log P c: log commodity prices and MP: monetary policy (central bank s contemporaneous behavior) Inf: commodity (information) market MD: money demand equation PS: production sector 1 C A

s 0 A 0 = B @ Illustration 2 PCOM M2 R Y CPI U Inform X X X X X X MP 0 X X 0 0 0 MD 0 X X X X 0 Prod 0 0 0 X 0 0 Prod 0 0 0 X X 0 Prod 0 0 0 X X X where PCOM: Price index for industrial commodities M2: Real money R: Federal funds rate (R) Y: real GDP interpolated to monthly frequency CPI: Consumer price index (CPI) U: Unemployment rate (U) Inform: Information market MP: Monetary policy rule MD: Money demand Prod: Production sector of the economy 1 C A

s Monetary Policy Shock

s Pelloni and Polasek (2003) introduce the VAR model with GARCH errors as where and vech(σ t ) = α 0 + y t = p B i y t i + u t i=1 u t N(0, Σ t ) r A i vech(σ t i ) + i=1 s Θ i vech(u t i u t i) i=1

s German, U.S., and U.K. quarterly data sets over the period 1968-1998. Variables are logs of aggregate employment and of the employment shares of the manufacturing, finance, trade, and construction sectors for U.S. and U.K.

s Uhlig (1997) introduced stochastic volatility (SV) for the error term in BVARs: p y t = B i y t i + u t, where and dynamics i=1 u t N(0, Σ t ) and Σ 1 t = L t L t, Σ 1 t+1 = L tθ t L t λ ( ν + pq Θ t B q, 1 2 2 ).

s Primiceri (2005) discusses VARs with time varying coefficients and stochastic volatility with y t = p B it y t i + u t u t N(0, Σ t ) i=1 Σ t = (A t ) 1 D t (A t) 1, and 1 0 0 σ 2 1,t 0 0 α 21,t 1 0 A t =........ D 0 σ2,t 2 0 t =......... α q1,t α q,q 1,t 1 0 0 σq,t 2

s Dynamics VAR coefficients: B t = B t 1 + ν t ν t N(0, Q) Cholesky coefficients: α t = α t 1 + ξ t ξ t N(0, S) Stochastic volatility: log σ t = log σ t 1 + η t η t N(0, W )

s

s See Nakajima, Kasuya and Watanabe (2011) for an application to the Japanese economy.

s VAR(1) case 3 Small: q = 3 15 parameters Medium: q = 20 610 parameters Large: q = 131 25,807 parameters Curse of dimensionality 3 Small, Medium and Large are based on the VAR specifications of Bańura, Giannone and Reichlin (2010).

s References Ahmadi and Uhlig (2009) Measuring the Dynamic Effects of Monetary Policy Shocks: A Bayesian FAVAR Approach with Sign Restriction. Technical Report. Bańbura, Giannone and Reichlin (2010) Large Bayesian vector auto regressions. JAE, 25, 71-92. Brandt and Freeman (2006) Advances in Bayesian Time Series Modeling and the Study of Politics: Theory Testing,, and Policy Analysis. Political Analysis, 14, 1-36. Carriero, Kapetanios, Marcellino (2009) exchange rates with a large Bayesian VAR. International Journal of, 25, 400-417. Del Negro and Schorfheide (2011) Bayesian Macroeconometrics. In Handbook of Bayesian Econometrics, Chapter 7, 293-387. Oxford University Press. Doan, Litterman and Sims (1984) and conditional projection using realistic prior distributions (with discussion). Econometric Reviews, 3, 1-144. Garratt, Koop, Mise and Vahey (2009) Real-Time Prediction With U.K. Monetary Aggregates in the Presence of Model Uncertainty. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 27, 480-491. Jochmann, Koop, Leon-Gonzalez and Strachan (2011) Stochastic search variable selection in vector error correction models with application to a model of the UK macroeconomy. JAE. Jochmann, Koop and Strachan (2010) Bayesian forecasting using stochastic search variable selection in a VAR subject to breaks. International Journal of, 26, 326-347. Kadiyala and Karlsson (1993) with generalized Bayesian vector autoregressions. Journal of, 12, 365-78. Kadiyala and Karlsson (1997). Numerical methods for estimation and inference in Bayesian VAR-models. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 12, 99-132.

s Refences (cont.) Koop and Korobilis (2009). Bayesian multivariate time series methods for empirical macroeconomics. Foundations and Trends in Econometrics, 3, 267-358. Koop and Korobilis (2012) Large Time-Varying Parameter VARs. Technical Report. Korobilis (2008) in vector autoregressions with many predictors. Technical Report, University of Strathclyde. Korobilis (2012) VAR forecasting using Bayesian variable selection. Journal of Applied Econometrics, forthcoming. Litterman (1980) A Bayesian procedure for forecasting with vector autoregressions. Technical Report, MIT. Litterman (1986) with Bayesian vector autoregressions five years of experience. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 4, 25-38. Lütkepohl (2007) New Introduction to Multiple Time Series Analysis. Springer. Nakajima, Kasuya and Watanabe (2011) Bayesian analysis of time-varying parameter vector autoregressive model for the Japanese economy and monetary policy. Journal of The Japanese and International Economies, 25, 225-245. Pelloni and Polasek (2003) Macroeconomic Effects of Sectoral Shocks in Germany, the U.K. and, the U.S.: A -M Approach. Computational Economics, 21, 65-85. Pfaff (2008) VAR, SVAR and SVEC Models: Implementation within R Package vars. Journal of Statistical Software, 27, 1-32. Primiceri (2005). Time Varying Structural Vector Autoregressions and Monetary Policy, Review of Economic Studies, 72, 821-852.

s Refences (cont.) Rubio-Ramírez, Waggoner and Zha (2010) Structural Vector Autoregressions: Theory of Identification and Algorithms for Inference. Review of Economic Studies, 77, 665-696. Sims (1980) Macroeconomics and Reality. Econometrica, 48, 1-48. Sims (2007) Bayesian Methods in Applied Econometrics, or, Why Econometrics Should Always and Everywhere Be Bayesian. Technical Report, Princeton University. Sims and Zha (1998). Bayesian Methods for Dynamic Multivariate Models. International Economic Review, 39, 949-968. Stock and Watson (2005) Implications of dynamic factor models for VAR analysis. Technical Report. Uhlig (1997) Bayesian Vector Autoregressions with Stochastic Volatility. Econometrica, 65, 59-73. Villani (2009) Steady-state priors for vector autoregressions. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 24, 630-650. Waggoner and Zha (2003) A Gibbs Sampler for s. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 28, 349-366. Zha (1999) Block recursion and structural vector autoregressions. Journal of Econometrics, 90, 291-316. Zivot and Wang (2003) Modeling Financial Time Series with S-plus. Springer.