WARDROP EQUILIBRIA IN AN INFINITE NETWORK

Similar documents
SOME MEASURABILITY AND CONTINUITY PROPERTIES OF ARBITRARY REAL FUNCTIONS

THEOREMS, ETC., FOR MATH 515

Analysis III Theorems, Propositions & Lemmas... Oh My!

Problem Set 2: Solutions Math 201A: Fall 2016

Analysis Finite and Infinite Sets The Real Numbers The Cantor Set

LECTURE 15: COMPLETENESS AND CONVEXITY

Homework 1 Solutions ECEn 670, Fall 2013

4.6 Montel's Theorem. Robert Oeckl CA NOTES 7 17/11/2009 1

Week 5 Lectures 13-15

SOLUTIONS TO ADDITIONAL EXERCISES FOR II.1 AND II.2

Iowa State University. Instructor: Alex Roitershtein Summer Homework #5. Solutions

g 2 (x) (1/3)M 1 = (1/3)(2/3)M.

Real Analysis Math 131AH Rudin, Chapter #1. Dominique Abdi

Real Analysis Notes. Thomas Goller

29 Linear Programming

Midterm 1. Every element of the set of functions is continuous

Recall that if X is a compact metric space, C(X), the space of continuous (real-valued) functions on X, is a Banach space with the norm

The Great Wall of David Shin

A necessary and sufficient condition for the existence of a spanning tree with specified vertices having large degrees

Spring 2014 Advanced Probability Overview. Lecture Notes Set 1: Course Overview, σ-fields, and Measures

On Kusuoka Representation of Law Invariant Risk Measures

MAT 570 REAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES. Contents. 1. Sets Functions Countability Axiom of choice Equivalence relations 9

D-bounded Distance-Regular Graphs

Linear Algebra (part 1) : Vector Spaces (by Evan Dummit, 2017, v. 1.07) 1.1 The Formal Denition of a Vector Space

("-1/' .. f/ L) I LOCAL BOUNDEDNESS OF NONLINEAR, MONOTONE OPERA TORS. R. T. Rockafellar. MICHIGAN MATHEMATICAL vol. 16 (1969) pp.

Erdös-Ko-Rado theorems for chordal and bipartite graphs

Czechoslovak Mathematical Journal

The small ball property in Banach spaces (quantitative results)


CHAPTER 8: EXPLORING R

Course 212: Academic Year Section 1: Metric Spaces

GRAND SOBOLEV SPACES AND THEIR APPLICATIONS TO VARIATIONAL PROBLEMS

Summary of Real Analysis by Royden

STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS WITH EXTRA PROPERTIES H. JEROME KEISLER. Department of Mathematics. University of Wisconsin.

NOTES ON VECTOR-VALUED INTEGRATION MATH 581, SPRING 2017

A Representation of Excessive Functions as Expected Suprema

Ramsey Theory. May 24, 2015

Contents: 1. Minimization. 2. The theorem of Lions-Stampacchia for variational inequalities. 3. Γ -Convergence. 4. Duality mapping.

Introduction to Real Analysis

2.31 Definition By an open cover of a set E in a metric space X we mean a collection {G α } of open subsets of X such that E α G α.

Real Analysis Chapter 4 Solutions Jonathan Conder

Part III. 10 Topological Space Basics. Topological Spaces

Appendix B Convex analysis

THE CANTOR GAME: WINNING STRATEGIES AND DETERMINACY. by arxiv: v1 [math.ca] 29 Jan 2017 MAGNUS D. LADUE

Math 421, Homework #6 Solutions. (1) Let E R n Show that = (E c ) o, i.e. the complement of the closure is the interior of the complement.

B. Appendix B. Topological vector spaces

Topology, Math 581, Fall 2017 last updated: November 24, Topology 1, Math 581, Fall 2017: Notes and homework Krzysztof Chris Ciesielski

Partially Optimal Routing

Homework 11. Solutions

{ move v ars to left, consts to right { replace = by t wo and constraints Ax b often nicer for theory Ax = b good for implementations. { A invertible

Geometry and topology of continuous best and near best approximations

Constrained Leja points and the numerical solution of the constrained energy problem

CHAPTER 2: CONVEX SETS AND CONCAVE FUNCTIONS. W. Erwin Diewert January 31, 2008.

Reminder Notes for the Course on Measures on Topological Spaces

Introduction and Preliminaries

Topological properties

REAL AND COMPLEX ANALYSIS

3 (Due ). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure?

MTH 404: Measure and Integration

FUNCTIONAL ANALYSIS LECTURE NOTES: COMPACT SETS AND FINITE-DIMENSIONAL SPACES. 1. Compact Sets

1 Lecture 4: Set topology on metric spaces, 8/17/2012

AN EXPLORATION OF THE METRIZABILITY OF TOPOLOGICAL SPACES

SOLUTION TO RUBEL S QUESTION ABOUT DIFFERENTIALLY ALGEBRAIC DEPENDENCE ON INITIAL VALUES GUY KATRIEL PREPRINT NO /4

TOPOLOGICAL ASPECTS OF YAO S ROUGH SET

Large topological cliques in graphs without a 4-cycle

van Rooij, Schikhof: A Second Course on Real Functions

A theorem on summable families in normed groups. Dedicated to the professors of mathematics. L. Berg, W. Engel, G. Pazderski, and H.- W. Stolle.

290 J.M. Carnicer, J.M. Pe~na basis (u 1 ; : : : ; u n ) consisting of minimally supported elements, yet also has a basis (v 1 ; : : : ; v n ) which f

Rearrangements and polar factorisation of countably degenerate functions G.R. Burton, School of Mathematical Sciences, University of Bath, Claverton D

MATHS 730 FC Lecture Notes March 5, Introduction

Notes for Functional Analysis

1/12/05: sec 3.1 and my article: How good is the Lebesgue measure?, Math. Intelligencer 11(2) (1989),

Real Analysis Problems

5 Banach Algebras. 5.1 Invertibility and the Spectrum. Robert Oeckl FA NOTES 5 19/05/2010 1

On metric characterizations of some classes of Banach spaces

Def. A topological space X is disconnected if it admits a non-trivial splitting: (We ll abbreviate disjoint union of two subsets A and B meaning A B =

Ordinary differential equations. Recall that we can solve a first-order linear inhomogeneous ordinary differential equation (ODE) dy dt

Rose-Hulman Undergraduate Mathematics Journal

Introduction to Real Analysis Alternative Chapter 1

(1) Consider the space S consisting of all continuous real-valued functions on the closed interval [0, 1]. For f, g S, define

Chapter 3: Baire category and open mapping theorems

Maths 212: Homework Solutions

Uniqueness of Generalized Equilibrium for Box Constrained Problems and Applications

MARKOV CHAINS: STATIONARY DISTRIBUTIONS AND FUNCTIONS ON STATE SPACES. Contents

The Geometry of Hyperbolic Manifolds via the Curve Complex

Indeed, if we want m to be compatible with taking limits, it should be countably additive, meaning that ( )

Notes on Iterated Expectations Stephen Morris February 2002

REVIEW OF ESSENTIAL MATH 346 TOPICS

Appendix PRELIMINARIES 1. THEOREMS OF ALTERNATIVES FOR SYSTEMS OF LINEAR CONSTRAINTS

1 Introduction This work follows a paper by P. Shields [1] concerned with a problem of a relation between the entropy rate of a nite-valued stationary

Introduction to Functional Analysis

II - REAL ANALYSIS. This property gives us a way to extend the notion of content to finite unions of rectangles: we define

An Algebraic View of the Relation between Largest Common Subtrees and Smallest Common Supertrees

Markov processes Course note 2. Martingale problems, recurrence properties of discrete time chains.

MONOTONE MULTITERMINAL RESISTORS AND LARGE NETWORKS

Continuous Functions on Metric Spaces

Connectedness. Proposition 2.2. The following are equivalent for a topological space (X, T ).

THEOREMS, ETC., FOR MATH 516

MORE EXERCISES FOR SECTIONS II.1 AND II.2. There are drawings on the next two pages to accompany the starred ( ) exercises.

M17 MAT25-21 HOMEWORK 6

Transcription:

LE MATEMATICHE Vol. LV (2000) Fasc. I, pp. 1728 WARDROP EQUILIBRIA IN AN INFINITE NETWORK BRUCE CALVERT In a nite network, there is a classical theory of trafc ow, which gives existence of a Wardrop equilibrium for given OD demands and afne route costs. In this note, the existence theory is extended to innite networks. 1. Introduction. We dene a classical model of Wardrop equilibrium for trafc ow [2]. Let (N, B) be a nite directed graph, with node set N and branch or link set B. A path in which all links are similarly directed is called a route, with the initial and nal nodes forming an origin/destination or O/D pair. Consider a nonempty set W of O/D pairs, and for each w W, suppose a ow demand d w > 0 to be given. Let R w be the set of routes joining w. For each w W, consider F r 0 for each r R w, such that F r = d w, giving a route ow r R w vector F = (F r ) r Rw,w W. This route ow induces a link ow f = ( f b ) b B, by f b = F r for each b, where we identify a route with the set of its links. For rb each link a, suppose a link cost c a = b B g ab f b + h a, where g ab and h a are given. For r R w, w W, dene a route cost by C r = c a. a r A route ow H is a Wardrop equilibrium if it satises the condition that for all r, s R w, w W, if C r < C s then H s = 0. In other words there is, for Entrato in Redazione il 26 maggio 2000. AMS 2000 Subject Classications: 90B10, 47H05.

18 BRUCE CALVERT each w, a common route cost γ w for all routes r R w with nonzero H r. There exists a Wardrop equilibrium [4]. In this paper we shall let (N, B) be an innite directed graph. Our mission is to extend our concepts in a natural way, so that we nd that Wardrop equilibria exist. In Section 2 we take the most naive extensions, and give counterexamples to show the need for innte routes. In Section 3 we show that allowing innite routes is still not enough, and end with the promise to give Wardrop ows as measures. Some background on innite routes is given in Section 4. Section 5 addresses a well known variational inequality in the setting of the pairing between Borel measures and continuous functions on the closure of the routes. In Section 6 we dene a Wardrop equilibrium, and show that it exists, by taking the completion of the measure given by the variational inequality, and restricting this to the routes. 2. The need for a 1-network. Recall an innite graph is locally nite if each node has only nitely many links incident to it. We shall consider an innite directed graph, allowing only nite routes, but a possibly innite set of O/D pairs W. Of course, even with a single O/D pair, o, d, it may be that there are innitely many routes from o to d. Assumption 1. Let G = (N, B) be an innite, locally nite, and connected directed graph. Assumption 2. d l 1 (W ), i.e w W d w <. Remark 1. Let R = R w. Under Assumption 2, dene K = {F : R w W [0, ) : for each w, F r = d w }. Later we shall replace this denition. If r R w F K then link ows are nite, since for b B, f b = rb F r r R F r = w W d w. We keep the same denition of link costs, but it involves an innite sum. Temporary Assumption 3. Assume for each link b, g b,a <. a B

WARDROP EQUILIBRIA IN AN INFINITE NETWORK 19 Suppose F K. Then, for each link b, c b = e b + a B g b,a f F a is nite, by Remark 1. Given F, we may write f F, c F, and C F to remind us that they are induced by F. For each route r, the route cost Cr F = c b is nite, since r is nite. b r Hence the denition of Wardrop equilibrium needs no change, under the above assumptions. The rst question is whether there exists a Wardrop equilibrium, considering only nite routes. Counterexample 1. Consider the innite ladder with nodes at points on the plane (n, 0) and (n, 1) for n 0. The nth top link from (n 1, 1) to (n, 1) is denoted nt, the nth bottom one nb, and the nth vertical one from (n 1, 1) to (n 1, 0), (n 1)v. Let the top links point right, the vertical ones down, and the bottom ones left. Let the link cost be given in terms of link ow f by c = a n + b n f on each of nt, nb and nv, where a n and b n are assumed non-negative. Suppose we have one OD pair, from (0, 1) to (0, 0), with demand d = 1. Suppose that for all n, 3(a n+1 + b n+1 ) < a n. Then there is no Wardrop equilibrium. Let the routes be indexed by the vertical links nv. Suppose F is a Wardrop equilibrium, given by F n on each nv. For any n 0, let the route cost on route nv be C n. Let the link cost on any link a be c a. Then C n+1 = C n c nv + c (n+1)t + c (n+1)b + c (n+1)v C n + 3(a n+1 + b n+1 ) a n < C n. Since F is a Wardrop equilibrium, F n = 0. But then summing the F n gives zero instead of d, a contradiction. What we shall do is dene a generalized Wardrop equilibrium, in this case being a ow of 1 out along the top innite route and back along the bottom route. To formalize this we may use a little of the concept of 1-networks from [1]. In this case, we merely add on an ideal node n 1, (the end) and regard the top innite route as being from (0, 1) to n 1, and the bottom from n 1 back to (0, 0). That is, we have allowed innite routes.

20 BRUCE CALVERT 3. The need for route ows as measures. Even this construction of 1-networks is not enough in general, and the next example and counterexample provoke a concept of ow which will give existence. We have just shown that it is possible that merely allowing innite routes can give a Wardrop equilibrium. We now look at two almost identical situations: Example 1 for which it is enough to allow innite routes and give a route ow as a summable function on these, and Counterexample 2 for which it is not enough. Example 1. Consider the graph formed from the innite ladder above by identifying nodes (n, 0) and (n, 1) for all n, and eliminating nv, and re-orienting links nb to point right. That is, we have two links, nt and nb in parallel from (n 1, 0) to (n, 0), for each n 1. As above we have n 1, and we suppose we have one OD pair, from (0, 0) to n 1, with demand d = 1, joined by innite routes. Let the link cost be given in terms of link ow f by c = e b + g b f on each link b, where e b and g b are nonnegative. Suppose e and g are summable, so that route costs, obtained by summing their link costs, are nite. There does exist a Wardrop equilibrium. Let us dene δ a,r for any link a and route r to be 1 if a r and 0 otherwise. First, for for each n, there is a Wardrop equilibrium on the subnetwork with links nt and nb, giving two link ows f nt and f nb, summing to 1. Take route r1 such that for each n, nt is in it iff f nt 1/2, and take route ow F r1 = 1/2. Then take route r2 such that for each n, nt is in it iff f nt δ nt,r1 F r1 1/4, and take route ow F r2 = 1/4. Continuing, we have a route ow vector F = {F rn : n = 1,...}. These give the link ow vector { f b : b B}, and therefore route costs are all equal on the routes rn, and F is a Wardrop equilibrium. This looks encouraging, and we are led to look for a ow F as a summable function on R, that is, as an element of K from Remark 1. Using this concept, we obtain a counterexample to a claim of existence of a Wardrop equilibrium. Counterexample 2. Consider a directed graph as in the last example, but with n links in parallel from (n 1, 0) to (n, 0), for each n. As above we have n 1, and we suppose we have one OD pair, from (0, 0) to n 1, with demand d = 1. Let the link cost be given in terms of link ow f by c = e b + g b f

WARDROP EQUILIBRIA IN AN INFINITE NETWORK 21 on each link b, where e b and g b are positive, with both e b all equal and g b all equal if b is from (n 1, 0) to (n, 0). Suppose e and g are summable, so that route costs are nite. There does not exist a Wardrop equilibrium. Any Wardrop equilibrium F gives an equilibrium on the links from (n 1, 0) to (n, 0). These give link ows which must be equal on the links from (n 1, 0) to (n, 0), and thus take the value 1/n. For any route r, F r 1/n for all n. Therefore F r = 0, contradicting F r = d. What we shall do is dene a Wardrop equilibrium as a measure on a sigma eld of subsets of R, to give existence. First we develop some theory. 4. Notation and denitions. We take s : B (0, ) a summable function, after noting that B is countable by Assumption 1.. Dene the metric d 0 on N by d 0 (x, x) = 0 and d 0 (x, y) = inf s b : P a path connecting x and y. b B Write ( N, d 0 ) for the completion, and call any limit point or cluster point (i.e., any element of N ) an end of (N, B). We now allow innite routes, which may be between a node x N and an end e N, or even between two ends, with the initial and nal nodes or ends forming an O/D pair. We say that an innite route is between two ends e 1 and e 2 if its nodes n k converge to these in ( N, d 0 ) as k goes to plus or minus innity. Likewise for an innite route between a node x and an end e. We shall identify a route with its branch set. We also allow 1- routes, made by concatenating a nite number of innite routes, the destination of one innite route being the origin of the next, each node and each end only visited once on a 1-route. Counterexample 1 gives a typical 1-route, the top innite route followed by the bottom innite route. Let R stand for the union of all the routes, both nite and innite, including the 1-routes. Let S be the metric space of subsets of B with metric d(u, V ) = {s b : b (U \ V ) (V \ U)}

22 BRUCE CALVERT 5. Solution of a variational inequality. Proposition 1. S is compact. Proof. S is a complete metric space [5], chapter II,2, Proposition. We need only show S is totally bounded. Let > 0 be given. Take H so that {sb b / H } <. For P S, the distance d(p, P H ) <. Note {P H P R} is nite, and we have a nite -net. We recall that the dual of the Banach space of continuous real valued functions on a compact metric space is the space of signed Borel measures [5]. Now we update our denition of K. Noting R S, let cl(r) denote the closure in S of R. Denition. Let K = {µ C(cl(R); R) : µ 0, µ(cl(r w ) = d w for all w W }. The next proposition extends a result of [4]. Proposition 2. Let H K, w W, and C C(cl(R); R). The following are equivalent. (1) H {r cl(r w ) : C(r) > in f {C(x) : x cl(r w )}} = 0. (2) C(r) d(f H )(r) 0 for all F K. cl(r w ) Proof. (1) (2) Let γ w = inf{c(x) : x cl(r w )}. Let F K be given. We want to show C(r) d F(r) C(r) d H (r), or equivalently cl(r w ) cl(r w ) (C(r) γ w ) d f (r) cl(r w ) cl(r w ) But RH S = 0 by (1), and L H S 0 since F 0. (C(r) γ w ) d H (r). (2) (1) Suppose (1) does not hold. Let T = {r cl(r w ) : C(r) > γ w }. Then take b cl(r w ) with C(b ) = γ w. Dene F by Note F 0, and F = H cl(r)\t + 0.5H T + 0.5H (T )δ b. F(cl(R w )) = H (cl(r w ) \ T ) + 0.5H (T ) + 0.5H (T )

WARDROP EQUILIBRIA IN AN INFINITE NETWORK 23 = H (cl(r w )). Note that for v W \ {w}, since R v and R w are a positive distance apart, and hence F K. Then cl(r w ) F(cl(R v )) = H (cl(r v )), C(r) d(f H )(r) = 0.5 C(r) d(h )(r) T + 0.5H (T )C(b ) = 0.5 (C(r) γ w ) d(h )(r) T < 0 since H (T ) > 0, and C(r) γ w > 0 on T, and (2) does not hold. Note that for b B, {r cl(r) : r b} is open in cl(r), in particular a Borel set, allowing the next denition. Denition. For F K, let us dene f b = fb F for b B by f b = F{r cl(r) : r b}, then c b = cb F by c b = e b + g b,a f a, and then for r S, C(r) = C F (r) a B is dened as C(r) = c b, giving C F : S R. b r Note that the link ows are bounded, for f b = w W F{r cl(r w ) : r b} w W d w. The link costs are nite by Temporary Assumption 3. The route costs are now innite sums, but are nite by the following Assumption 3, a stronger assumption than the temporary one. Assumption 3. Both e and g are summable, g is nonnegative and all e b > 0, and g b,a f a f b 0 for a bounded real valued function f on B. a,b B Proposition 3. Let H K. C H is continuous on S.

24 BRUCE CALVERT Proof. Let > 0 be given. Using Assumption 3, we take a nite B f B, such that e b < 1, and g b,a < 1, where 1 is to be chosen. Take b B f a B,b B f δ to be min{s b : b B f }. Let r and r be in S with d(r, r ) < δ. Then r B f = r B f. Therefore C H (r) C H (r ) = c b c b, b r\b f b r \B f and as noted after the previous denition, for any b, f H b w W d w, giving C H (r) C H (r ) b B f [e b + a B g b,a f H b ] < 1 + ( w W 1 + ( w W =, d w ) d w ) 1 b B f,a B choosing 1 so that the last equality holds. Thus C H is uniformly continuous on S. Let us denote the restriction of C H to cl(r) by C H. Proposition 4. The map C : K monotone. g b,a C(cl(R); R), mapping H to C H, is Proof. Let F and H be in K. For a B, let S(a) = {r cl(r) : r a}. Then (C F C H, F H ) = (C F (r) C H (r)) d(f H )(r) = ( a,b B = ( a,b B g a,b g a,b χ r (a)((f H )S(b))) d(f H )(r) χ r (a)((f H )S(b)) d(f H )(r)

WARDROP EQUILIBRIA IN AN INFINITE NETWORK 25 by Fubini = a,b B = 0. a,b B g a,b r S(a) (F H )S(b) d(f H )(r) g a,b [(F H )(S(a))][(F H )(S(b))] Proposition 5. For F, H K, the map Z (C Z, F H ) is continuous on the line segment [F, H ]. Proof. We put, for t [0, 1], Z = (1 t)f + t H, and consider t C Z (r) d(h F)(r) = d(h F)(r) = = a r χ r (a)(e a + a B b B = t + (1 t) This is continuous. ca Z a r (e a + g a,b Z (S(b)) d(h F)(r) b B g a,b [t H (S(b)) + (1 t)f(s(b)]) d(h F)(r) χ r (a)(e a + a B b a B χ r (a)(e a + b g a,b H (S(b)) d(h F)(r) g a,b F(S(b)) d(h F)(r). We recall the following corollary of the Debrunner-Flor Lemma [3]. Proposition 6. Let E be a real locally convex topological vector space and let K be a nonempty compact convex subset of E. Suppose C : K E is monotone and for x, y K, the map z (C(z), y x) is continuous on the line segment [x, y]. Then there exists x K such that for all y K, (C(x), y x) 0. Proposition 7. Suppose Assumptions 1,2, and 3 hold. There exists H K such that H and C H : cl(r) R satisfy (1) and (2) of Proposition 2.

26 BRUCE CALVERT Proof. Use the Debrunner-Flor result with E the space of signed Borel measures on cl(r), with the weak topology on E = C(cl(R); R), and K = {µ C(cl(R); R) : µ 0, µ(cl(r w ) = d w for all w W }. For H K, the map F (C H, F) is a weak continuous linear functional, and we have shown the required monotonicity and continuity. 6. Wardrop equilibria and their existence. We now look at the relationship between R o,d and its closure, for o, d an O/D pair. This allows us to consider the completion H 0 of H on R. Notation. Let (N, B) be a connected locally nite directed graph, with nitely many ends. For F a nite subset of B, and e an end, we write e(f) for the innite component of (N, B \ F) with e as limit point. If G is a subgraph of (N, B), we write E(G) for its link set and V (G) for its node set. A 1-walk will be like a 1-route, a concatenation of innite routes, except we may visit ends more than once. Theorem 8. Let (N, B) be a connected locally nite directed graph, with nitely many ends. Let o and d(d = o) be in N. For r cl(r o,d ), there exists s R o,d with s r. Proof. Suppose for now that o and d are ends, to x ideas. Take a nite F B, such that e 1 (F) / e 2 (F) if e 1 and e 2 are distinct ends. Take a sequence r k r, with r k R o,d, and take k 0 such that for all k k 0, r k F = r F. This intersection is a nite union of nite routes p i. We enlarge F to F by including all nite routes q contained in r with q F =, and origin and destination in F. By taking k 0 larger if necessary, assume r k F = r F for all k k 0. There are now no nite routes q contained in r with q F = and having origin and destination in F. Let F r k, for k k 0, be the nite union of nite routes p i, from o i to d i (all distinct), i = 1,..., L. By taking a subsequence, we assume that all r k traverse the routes p i in the same order, say p 1 to p L, and k 0 = 1. We claim there is a 1-route in r from d i 1 to o i for each i from 2 to L, and innite routes from o to o 1 and from d L to d. For all k, the links of r k from d i 1 to o i form a nite route or 1-route, denoted r i k. Since r k traverses the p j in order 1 to L, the links of r i k are all in E(e(F )) for some end e. Now suppose thare is a nite H B, with F H, such that for all k, r i k stays in E(e(F )) H. Then there exists a nite route contained in r E(e(F )), with origin and destination in F, which is impossible. Hence for each such H, r i k has some links (r i k ) b in E(e(H )). This gives the existence of a route q i contained in r from d i 1 to e,

WARDROP EQUILIBRIA IN AN INFINITE NETWORK 27 because given any nite subset H of B containing F, H rk i is constant for large k, and we take q H to be the component of H rk i with origin d i 1, and let q i be the union of the q H. Similarly, there exists a route contained in r from e to o i. Together, these two innite routes give a 1-route in r from d i 1 to o i. Similarly there are innite routes in r from o to o 1 and from d L to d. Note that an end e may be approximated more than once by nodes of the r k. It follows that there exists a 1-walk w in r from o to d, noting all nodes are only visited once, since each link of w is in r k for k large. Hence there exists a 1-route s in r from o to d. The cases where one or both of o and d are nodes can be dealt with by adjusting the preceding argument. Proposition 9. Suppose Assumptions 1,2, and 3 hold. Let H and C H : cl(r) R satisfy (1) and (2) of Proposition 2, and let w W be given. Then R w is measurable with respect to the completion (cl(r), B 0, H 0 ) of the measure space (cl(r), B, H ), where B denotes the Borel sets, and H 0 (R w ) = d w. Proof. We claim cl(r w ) \ R w is contained in a Borel set of H measure zero. It sufces to show that if r cl(r w ) \ R w, then C H (r) > C H (s) for some s cl(r w ). Now for r cl(r w ) \ R w, r contains a 1-route s = r, by Theorem 7. Then C(r) = C(s) + a r\s C(s) + > C(s). a r\s Denition. Suppose Assumptions 1,2 and 3 hold. Suppose there is a measure space (R, B 1, H 1 ) where B 1 contains the Borel σ - eld of R, such that H 1 (R w ) = d w and H 1 {r R w : C H 1 (r) > in f {C H 1 (x) : x R w }} = 0, for all w W, where C H 1 : R R is given by: for all b B, f b = H 1 {r R : r b}, c b = e b + g b,a f a, and for r R, C H 1 (r) = c b. Then we say H 1 is a B b r a Wardrop equilibrium. Theorem 10. Suppose Assumptions 1,2 and 3 hold. There exists a Wardrop equilibrium, H 1. c a e a

28 BRUCE CALVERT Proof. By Proposition 9, taking (B 1, H 1 ) to be the restriction to R of (cl(r), B 0, H 0 ). Question. Is there a version of this with the map from link ows to link costs being non afne? Acknowledgements. I thank A. Maugeri and J. Gwinner for their encouragement. REFERENCES [1] B.D. Calvert - A.H. Zemanian, Operating points in innite nonlinear networks approximated by nite networks, Trans A. M. S., 352 (2000), pp. 753780. [2] S. Dafermos - A. Nagurney, On some trafc theory equilibrium paradoxes, Transportation Res. B, 18 (1984), pp. 101110. [3] H. Debrunner - P. Flor, Ein Erweiterungsatz fur monotone Mengen, Archiv Math., 15 (1964), pp. 445-447. [4] M.J. Smith, The existence, uniqueness, and stability of trafc equilibria, Transportation Res. B, 13 (1979), pp. 295304. [5] K. Yosida, Functional Analysis, Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 1965. University of Auckland, Auckland, (NEW ZEALAND), e-mail: calvert@math.auckland.ac.nz