The Lucas Imperfect Information Model

Similar documents
Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

Demand Shocks with Dispersed Information

Demand Shocks, Monetary Policy, and the Optimal Use of Dispersed Information

Aggregate Supply. Econ 208. April 3, Lecture 16. Econ 208 (Lecture 16) Aggregate Supply April 3, / 12

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Source: US. Bureau of Economic Analysis Shaded areas indicate US recessions research.stlouisfed.org

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

Monetary Economics. Lecture 15: unemployment in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy

A Summary of Economic Methodology

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Macroeconomics Field Exam. August 2007

Empirical Industrial Organization (ECO 310) University of Toronto. Department of Economics Fall Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria

V. The Speed of adjustment of Endogenous Variables and Overshooting

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Chapter 11 The Stochastic Growth Model and Aggregate Fluctuations

Simple Consumption / Savings Problems (based on Ljungqvist & Sargent, Ch 16, 17) Jonathan Heathcote. updated, March The household s problem X

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Lecture 3: A dynamic IS-LM model

1 The Basic RBC Model

Endogenous Information Choice

Learning, Expectations, and Endogenous Business Cycles

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

The Real Business Cycle Model

Mankiw Chapter 11. Aggregate Demand I. Building the IS-LM Model

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

004: Macroeconomic Theory

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Lecture 9: The monetary theory of the exchange rate

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 W2005

Monetary Policy, Price Dynamics, and Welfare

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

The Hansen Singleton analysis

WORKING PAPER NO INTEREST RATE VERSUS MONEY SUPPLY INSTRUMENTS: ON THE IMPLEMENTATION OF MARKOV-PERFECT OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Precautionary Demand for Money in a Monetary Business Cycle Model

Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model.

Problem set 2 solutions Prof. Justin Marion Econ 100M Winter 2012

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 2

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them.

Online Appendix for Slow Information Diffusion and the Inertial Behavior of Durable Consumption

The Keynesian Model of Income Determination (revised)

1. Using the model and notations covered in class, the expected returns are:

A Dynamic Model of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Monetary Policy in a Macro Model

Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics ARE 251/Econ 270A, Fall Household Models

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

Two Models of Macroeconomic Equilibrium

Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory Notes. David L. Kelly. Department of Economics University of Miami Box Coral Gables, FL

Learning to Optimize: Theory and Applications

Closed economy macro dynamics: AD-AS model and RBC model.

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

Macroeconomics Theory II

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics

Expectations, Learning and Macroeconomic Policy

Money and the Sidrauski Model

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

ECON4515 Finance theory 1 Diderik Lund, 5 May Perold: The CAPM

Economics 232c Spring 2003 International Macroeconomics. Problem Set 3. May 15, 2003

h Edition Money in Search Equilibrium

Theoretical premises of the Keynesian approach

Microeconomic theory focuses on a small number of concepts. The most fundamental concept is the notion of opportunity cost.

Macroeconomics Theory II

Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Econ 5110 Solutions to the Practice Questions for the Midterm Exam

Phillips curve and the Tinbergen and Theil approach to economic policy

Endogenous information acquisition

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Quantifying the Welfare Gains from History Dependent Income Taxation

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

APPENDIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital?

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Problem set Solutions

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

Motivation Non-linear Rational Expectations The Permanent Income Hypothesis The Log of Gravity Non-linear IV Estimation Summary.

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Inflation traps, and rules vs. discretion

Transcription:

The Lucas Imperfect Information Model Based on the work of Lucas (972) and Phelps (970), the imperfect information model represents an important milestone in modern economics. The essential idea of the model is that producers inability to distinguish between price movements due to relative price changes (to which they should respond) and aggregate price level changes (e.g., general inflation, to which they should not respond) generates an upwardsloping aggregate supply curve. Producers attribute some proportion of any observed aggregate price level change to a relative price change, and thus change the quantity of goods that they produce. First, we will solve the model assuming perfect information about price changes, and then solve it assuming imperfect information about price changes. The Lucas Island Model under Perfect Information Islands consume a market basket of produced goods (denoted C), which has unit price P (this will be a price index of all produced goods). Production cannot be saved, but must be consumed instantaneously. Production is denoted Y. Individuals on islands work to receive income to purchase the market basket, with island labor input denoted L. Production rises one-for-one with the amount of labor input. Let z index islands. Let the island representative agent utility maximization problem be: max C(z),L(z) U (z) C (z) γ L (z)γ s.t. C (z) P (z) Y (z) P Y (z) L (z) and γ >. The marginal utility of consumption is constant. Combined with the budget constraint, this implies that islands want to maximize their income to maximize their consumption. However, they experience an increasing marginal disutility of work. They thus must balance their marginal utility of consumption with their marginal disutility of work. The individual optimization problem then gives us: U (z) P (z) L (z) P γ L (z)γ U (z) L (z) P (z) P L (z)γ 0 ( ) P (z) γ Y (z) L (z) P y (z) (p (z) p). γ Lowercase letters denote the logarithmic values of the corresponding uppercase letter variables. Because goods are not storable, solution of the instantaneous problem gives us the solution for production at any point in time. Let γ > 0. Then, the island supply function at time t is given by: y t (z) p t (z) p t. Suppose that the island has a demand function for its production at time t given by: y d t (z) m t (z) p t (z). Here, we can think of m as denoting the log money supply for island z. It is actually just a shorthand for

modeling the demand side. If we apply a market clearing condition, then we have: y t (z) y d t (z) p t (z) p t m t (z) p t (z) p t (z) m t (z) + p t. Suppose that there are total islands. Aggregation across islands requires that m t p t, where p t p t (z) and m t m t (z). Why? If we aggregate across all the individual island market clearing conditions we can see that: p t (z) p t p t p t m t (z) m t p t p t p t m t p t 0 m t p t m t p t. p t (z) ow, we will make some assumptions about the evolution of m t (z). Suppose that the log money supply for an island is given by m t (z) m t + η t (z), where η t (z) is an idiosyncratic, mean zero shock. Further, suppose that the aggregate money supply evolves according to m t m t + µ + ξ t, where µ denotes a common constant money growth rate and ξ t denotes a random, mean zero, aggregate money supply shock. With the above assumptions, we can close the model, and solve for individual and aggregate prices and quantities as functions of the exogenous parameters. ote that the individual island price path becomes: p t (z) m t (z) + p t m t + η t (z) + m t m t + µ + ξ t + η t (z) + (m t + µ + ξ t ) m t + µ + ξ t + η t (z) m t + η t (z). This in turn implies that individual island production in equilibrium will be: y t (z) p t (z) p t m t + η t (z) m t η t (z). From the aggregate market clearing condition, we know that y t m t p t 0. see that: y t y t (z) η t (z) η t (z) η t (z). 2 Or more precisely, we can

Assuming that all islands are atomistic (so small that they do not move the aggregate market individually), we effectively have. By a law of large numbers, we know that: η t (z) E (η t (z)) 0, as. Recall that we assumed that η t (z) was mean zero. Hence, we can see that y t 0. Under perfect information, there is no distortion to the individual island s production decision. Islands respond only to those changes in price which are due to a true change in relative prices, denoted by the individual island shock term η t (z). 2 The Lucas Island Model under Imperfect Information Suppose that the log price of an individual island s good is given by p t (z) p t + λ t (z), where λ t (z) is an idiosyncratic, mean zero island good relative price shock. To understand this interpretation, note that: p t (z) p t + (p t (z) p t ) p t + λ t (z). Hence, the island s good price differs from the aggregate price only by an idiosyncratic relative price shock term (assuming independence of p t and λ t (z)). Further, suppose that an individual island s production decision depends not on the actual aggregate price level, but rather on their expectation of the aggregate price level (they do not observe the actual aggregate price level exactly). Individual islands behave in a certainty-equivalent manner. Let their expectation of the aggregate price level given individual island information set I t (z) be denoted E (p t I t (z)) p t. Let the actual aggregate price level differ from this expectation by some independent, mean zero shock term, u t. Essentially, expectations are rational. We have that p t E (p t I t (z)) + u t p t + u t. Then, the island supply function is: y t (z) p t (z) p t p t + λ t (z) p t p t + u t + λ t (z) p t u t + λ t (z). All that individual islands observe at a point in time is u t + λ t (z); they are unable to differentiate between the aggregate level price shock term and the idiosyncratic relative price shock. Their optimal production choice should only respond to the relative price change, λ t (z). The problem individual islands face is trying to distinguish between the idiosyncratic shock λ t (z) and the aggregate shock u t. Assume that individual islands have historical data relating the realizations of λ t (z) and u t + λ t (z) (retrospective data on λ t (z) exists). Then, assume that they can calculate a linear predictor of λ t (z) by regressing λ t (z) on u t + λ t (z). Hence, we have that ˆλ t (z) ˆθ (z) u t + λ t (z), where ˆθ (z) Cov(λt(z),ut+λt(z)) V ar(λ V ar(u t +λ t (z)) t(z)) V ar(u t )+V ar(λ t (z)) (0, ). With this estimator of E (λ t (z) I t (z), p t (z))in hand, we can see that: E p t (z) p t I t (z), p t (z) E (λ t (z) I t (z), p t (z)) p t (z) E p t I t (z), p t (z) ˆθ (z) u t + λ t (z) E p t I t (z), p t (z) p t (z) ˆθ (z) u t + λ t (z) E p t I t (z), p t (z) p t (z) ˆθ (z) p t (z) p t ( E p t I t (z), p t (z) ˆθ ) (z) p t (z) + ˆθ (z) p t In fact, if we assume that the monetary shock u t and the idiosyncratic relative price shock λ t (z) are normally distributed, then their sum u t + λ t (z) is also normally distributed. Given that λ t (z) and u t + λ t (z) are jointly normally distributed, the expectation of one is a linear function of the other. Hence, our use of a linear predictor for λ t (z) is justified. 3

This equation tells us how information on p t (z) updates our expectation of p t. Essentially, we have added movements in p t (z) to our conditioning information set in forming our expectation of p t. Recall that p t E (p t I t (z)); it is the island s expectation of p t in the absence of information on p t (z). We can employ this formula to update the individual island supply function, so that islands are taking full account of all available information. We now have: y t (z) p t (z) E p t I t (z), p t (z) ( p t (z) ˆθ ) (z) p t (z) ˆθ (z) p t ˆθ (z) pt (z) ˆθ (z) p t ˆθ (z) p t (z) p t. otice how this island supply function differs slightly from the original formulation, through the inclusion of ˆθ (z). This is the Lucas supply function. To complete the model, we must invoke the demand side. Assume that the demand side is identical to the perfect information case: y d t (z) m t (z) p t (z) m t (z) m t + η t (z) m t m t + µ + ξ t, where the variables are defined as in the perfect information case. Market equilibrium requires that: y t (z) y d t (z) ˆθ (z) p t (z) p t m t (z) p t (z) ˆθ (z) p t (z) p t m t + µ + ξ t + η t (z) p t (z). Aggregating this up to the economy-level, we have that: ˆθ (z) p t p t m t + µ + ξ t p t p t m t + µ + ξ t + ˆθ (z) p t E (p t I t (z)) E (m t I t (z)) + E (µ I t (z)) + E (ξ t I t (z)) + ˆθ (z) E ( p t I t (z)) p t m t + µ + ˆθ (z) p t p t m t + µ. We can then take this result and apply it to the individual island production decision, since islands have identical information. We then have that: ˆθ (z) p t (z) m t + µ m t + µ + ξ t + η t (z) p t (z) p t (z) m t + µ + ξ t + η t (z) p t (z) m t + µ + ξ t + η t (z). Aggregating this up to the economy level again, we have that: p t m t + µ + ξ t, since η t 0. E (p t I t (z)) m t + µ p t, as above. 4

These expectations are model-consistent. Hence, the individual island production function in terms of the exogenous variables is: y t (z) ˆθ m t + µ + ξ t + η t (z) m t µ ( ) ˆθ (ξ t + η t (z)) y t and aggregate output is given by ( ) ˆθ ξ t. Under imperfect information, we can see that shocks to the aggregate money supply (ξ t ) generate inefficiencies (island production responds to aggregate price changes and not just to relative price changes) and an upward-sloping aggregate supply curve (y t and p t are positively related through the money shocks). 5