Trade, Inequality and Costly Redistribution

Similar documents
Inequality, Costly Redistribution and Welfare in an Open Economy

Globalization, Inequality and Welfare

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GLOBALIZATION, INEQUALITY AND WELFARE. Pol Antràs Alonso de Gortari Oleg Itskhoki

Globalization, Inequality and Welfare

Measuring the Gains from Trade: They are Large!

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy

Optimal Income Taxation: Mirrlees Meets Ramsey

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory)

Optimal Tax Progressivity: An Analytical Framework

Optimal Tax Progressivity: An Analytical Framework

Negative Income Taxes, Inequality and Poverty

A Theory of Income Taxation under Multidimensional Skill Heterogeneity

International Trade. Course Description and Requirements

Politico Economic Consequences of Rising Wage Inequality

On the Geography of Global Value Chains

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

SELECTION EFFECTS WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS: ONLINE APPENDIX

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Trade and Inequality: From Theory to Estimation

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Should Robots Be Taxed?

Should Robots Be Taxed?

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory)

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

A Theory of Optimal Inheritance Taxation

Internationa1 l Trade

Internation1al Trade

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES NONLINEAR TAX INCIDENCE AND OPTIMAL TAXATION IN GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM. Dominik Sachs Aleh Tsyvinski Nicolas Werquin

Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms

Public Economics Ben Heijdra Chapter 9: Introduction to Normative Public Economics

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial Insurance Economy

Problem Set Suggested Answers

Wages, Unemployment and Inequality with Heterogeneous Firms and Workers

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Monopolistic Competition when Income Matters

Advanced Macroeconomics

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Addendum to: New Trade Models, Same Old Gains?

STRUCTURE Of ECONOMICS A MATHEMATICAL ANALYSIS

Motivation A Figure 1 Figure 2 Table 1 Table 2

International Prices and Exchange Rates Econ 2530b, Gita Gopinath

OPTIMAL TAXATION: LESSONS FOR TAX POLICY

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Proper Welfare Weights for Social Optimization Problems

New Trade Models, Same Old Gains?

Top 10% share Top 1% share /50 ratio

Bequest Motives, Estate Taxes, and Wealth Distributions in Becker-Tomes Models with Investment Risk

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

The Role of the Most Favored Nation Principle of the GATT/WTO in the New Trade Model

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems

Monopolistic Competition in Trade III Trade Costs and Gains from Trade

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lectures 2 and 3: Static Voting Models

Nonlinear Tax Incidence and Optimal Taxation in General Equilibrium

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

CROSS-COUNTRY DIFFERENCES IN PRODUCTIVITY: THE ROLE OF ALLOCATION AND SELECTION

Beyond CES: Three Alternative Classes of Flexible Homothetic Demand Systems

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

Global Production with Export Platforms

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade

Equality of Opportunity

Labour Supply Responses and the Extensive Margin: The US, UK and France

Granular Comparative Advantage

Trade and the political economy of redistribution

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

A Note on the Welfare Evaluation of Tax Reform with Non-Convex Preferences and Discrete Labor Supply

AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS STAFF PAPER SERIES

14.770: Introduction to Political Economy Lectures 1 and 2: Collective Choice and Voting

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

Importing Skill-Biased Technology

WELFARE: THE SOCIAL- WELFARE FUNCTION

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Lecture 1: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

Political Cycles and Stock Returns. Pietro Veronesi

Economic Policy and Equality of Opportunity

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

Trade and Domestic Policy in Models with Monopolistic Competition

Web Appendix for Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Not for Publication)

Schumpeterian Growth Models

Political Economy of Institutions and Development. Lecture 8. Institutional Change and Democratization

Technological Spillovers and Dynamics of Comparative Advantage

The Geography of Development: Evaluating Migration Restrictions and Coastal Flooding

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES NEW TRADE MODELS, SAME OLD GAINS? Costas Arkolakis Arnaud Costinot Andrés Rodríguez-Clare

Constrained Efficiency in a Risky Human Capital Model

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Estimating the effect of exchange rate changes on total exports

Optimal income taxation with composition effects

Transcription:

Trade, Inequality and Costly Redistribution Pol Antràs Alonso de Gortari Oleg Itskhoki Harvard Harvard Princeton ILO Symposium September 2015 1 / 30

Introduction International trade raises real income but also increases inequality and makes some worse off Standard approach to demonstrating and quantifying the gains from trade largely ignore trade-induced inequality Kaldor-Hicks compensation principle Two issues with this approach: 1 How much compensation/redistribution actually takes place? 2 Is this redistribution costless, as the Kaldor-Hicks approach assumes? These issue are relevant not just for trade, but also for technology adoption etc. 2 / 30

This Paper We study quantitatively welfare implications of trade in a model where: 1 trade leads to an increase in inequality 2 redistribution requires distortionary taxation (e.g., due to informational constraints, as in Mirrlees) 3 despite progressive tax system, trade still increases inequality in after-tax incomes 3 / 30

This Paper We study quantitatively welfare implications of trade in a model where: 1 trade leads to an increase in inequality 2 redistribution requires distortionary taxation (e.g., due to informational constraints, as in Mirrlees) 3 despite progressive tax system, trade still increases inequality in after-tax incomes We propose two types of adjustment to standard welfare measures: 1 Welfarist correction: taking into account inequality-aversion of society (or risk-adjustment under the veil of ignorance) 2 Costly-redistribution correction: capturing behavioral responses to trade-induced shifts across marginal tax rates 3 / 30

Motivating Figure 1.7 1.6 Mean Income Median Income Real Income in the United States (1979-2007) 1.5 1.4 1.3 1.2 1.1 1 0.9 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 1.74% versus 0.47% annualized annual growth 4 / 30

Motivating Figure 14% Openness and Inequality in the United States (1979 2007) 0.60 13% 0.58 12% 0.56 11% 0.54 10% 0.52 9% 0.50 8% 0.48 7% 0.46 1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 Trade Share Gini of Market Income 4 / 30

Building Blocks and Related Literature Trade models with heterogeneous workers Itskhoki (2008) matching/sorting models (see Grossman, and Costinot and Vogel for surveys) models with imperfect labor markets (Helpman, Itskhoki, Redding, and others) Gains from trade and costly redistribution: Dixit and Norman (1986), Rodrik (1992), Spector (2001), Naito (2006) Welfarist approach: Bergson (1938), Samuelson (1947), Diamond & Mirlees (1971), Saez more recently Costly-redistribution: Kaplow (2008), Hendren (2014) Nonlinear tax system as in Heathcote, Storesletten and Violante (2014) Model calibrated to fit 2007 U.S. data on income distribution from IRS public records 5 / 30

Road Map 1 A Motivating Example 2 Open Economy Model 3 Calibration 4 Counterfactuals: Inequality and the Gains from Trade 6 / 30

MOTIVATING EXAMPLE 7 / 30

The Kaldor-Hicks Principle Consider an economy with a unit measure of individuals with ability ϕ H ϕ earning market income r ϕ F r We want to evaluate a shift of income distribution F r F r 7 / 30

The Kaldor-Hicks Principle Consider an economy with a unit measure of individuals with ability ϕ H ϕ earning market income r ϕ F r We want to evaluate a shift of income distribution F r F r The compensating variation v ϕ for each individual: u(r ϕ ) = u(r ϕ + v ϕ ) v ϕ = r ϕ r ϕ 7 / 30

The Kaldor-Hicks Principle Consider an economy with a unit measure of individuals with ability ϕ H ϕ earning market income r ϕ F r We want to evaluate a shift of income distribution F r F r The compensating variation v ϕ for each individual: Hence: u(r ϕ ) = u(r ϕ + v ϕ ) v ϕ = r ϕ r ϕ v ϕ dh ϕ = = r ϕdh ϕ r ϕ dh ϕ rdf r rdf r = R R Kaldor-Hicks Gains = Aggregate Real Income Growth G KH = R R R µ 7 / 30

The Kaldor-Hicks Principle Pros and Cons Principle does not rely on interpersonal comparisons of utility: indirect utility can be heterogeneous across agents result relies on ordinal rather than cardinal preferences notion of efficiency argued to be free of value judgements What if redistribution does not take place? under the veil of ignorance, agents see a probability distribution over potential outcomes (need cardinal preferences) risk aversion inequality aversion Even if some redistribution takes place, whenever it is costly, shouldn t W /W reflect those costs? Dixit and Norman (1986) showed that W /W > 0 using a course set of taxes, but by how much is W /W diminished? 8 / 30

A Constant-Elasticity Model Closed Economy A unit measure of individuals with CRRA-GHH utility: U(c, l) = 1 (c 1 1 + ρ γ lγ) Each individual produces a task according to y = ϕl, ϕ H ϕ This translates into market income r = Q 1 β y β, Q = r ϕ dh ϕ Consumption equals after-tax income: show data c = r T (r) = kr 1 φ Government runs balanced budget g = G r 1 φ Q = 1 k ϕ dh ϕ rϕ dh ϕ 9 / 30

A Constant-Elasticity Model Closed Economy A unit measure of individuals with CRRA-GHH utility: U(c, l) = 1 (c 1 1 + ρ γ lγ) Each individual produces a task according to y = ϕl, ϕ H ϕ This translates into market income r = Q 1 β y β, Q = r ϕ dh ϕ Consumption equals after-tax income: show data c = r T (r) = kr 1 φ Government runs balanced budget g = G r 1 φ Q = 1 k ϕ dh ϕ rϕ dh ϕ In constant-elasticity model, r ϕ ϕ β(1+ε) 1+εφ, where ε β γ β 9 / 30

Welfare: W 0 = 1 1 + ε (1 g) Q, Welfare Corrections W ρ = 1 + εφ 1 + ε (1 g)q = W 0 Θ, 10 / 30

Welfare: W 0 = 1 1 + ε (1 g) Q, Welfare Corrections W ρ = 1 + εφ 1 + ε (1 g)q = W 0 Θ, Welfarist Correction (Atkison, 1970): ( ) 1 (1 φ)(1 ρ) 1 ρ r ϕ dh ϕ r 1 φ ϕ dh ϕ 10 / 30

Welfare: W 0 = 1 1 + ε (1 g) Q, Welfare Corrections W ρ = 1 + εφ 1 + ε (1 g)q = W 0 Θ, Welfarist Correction (Atkison, 1970): ( ) 1 (1 φ)(1 ρ) 1 ρ r ϕ dh ϕ r 1 φ ϕ dh ϕ Costly Redistribution Correction: [ ( ) 1+ε rϕ dh ϕ Θ (1+εφ) Q Q = (1 + εφ)(1 φ) }{{} Θ κε ( r 1 φ ) ε ϕ dh ϕ r 1+εφ ϕ dh ϕ }{{} Θ ] κ 10 / 30

Properties of the Correction Terms General properties: 1, Θ [0, 1] and independent of µ. 2 = 1 if either ρ = 0 or F r is degenerate. < 1 otherwise, and monotonically decreasing in ρ 3 Θ = 1 iff φ = 0. If F r is degenerate, Θ = 1 and Θ = Θ 1. Θ is monotonically decreasing in φ and ε. 11 / 30

Properties of the Correction Terms General properties: 1, Θ [0, 1] and independent of µ. 2 = 1 if either ρ = 0 or F r is degenerate. < 1 otherwise, and monotonically decreasing in ρ 3 Θ = 1 iff φ = 0. If F r is degenerate, Θ = 1 and Θ = Θ 1. Θ is monotonically decreasing in φ and ε. Special-case: log-normal ability distribution { } = exp ρ(1 φ) 2 σ2 r, 2 { Θ = exp κε(1 + ε)φ 2 σ2 r 2 }. both and Θ decrease in dispersion of income (σ r, Gini, etc.) yet, increases and Θ decreases in φ policy tradeoff 11 / 30

GDP growth rates: Welfarist correction: Corrections for Welfare Gains µ = Q Q Q, µ = Q Q Q = G G W W ρ W ρ = (1 + µ) 1 Costly redistribution correction: µ = (1 + µ) Θ Θ 1 12 / 30

Look at the data Growth corrections for US, 1979 2007 Welfare correction: G W /µ / ρ = 0.5 1 2 Non-parametric 0.89 0.80 0.08 Log-normal 0.90 0.80 0.60 CR correction: µ/ µ Θ /Θ ε = 0.5 1 2 Non-parametric 1.04 1.14 1.98 Log-normal 1.06 1.27 ( µ < 0) Recall that annualized µ = 1.74% over 1979 2007, inequality increased but progressively (φ) decreased 13 / 30

3 Contribution (Taxation) 3 Contribution (Taxation) Policy Tradeoff for US, 1979 2007 θ δ {}}{{}}{ In logs: log W ρ = log W 0 + log Θ + log 0.12 (/,3) Phase Diagram, rho=0.5, eps=0.5 0.11 0.1 0.09 0.08 0.07 0.06 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 0.55 0.6 / Contribution (Inequality) 0.12 (/,3) Phase Diagram, rho=0.7, eps=0.5 0.11 0.1 0.09 0.08 0.07 0.06 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 0.55 0.6 / Contribution (Inequality) 14 / 30

Trade and Welfarist Correction A Preliminary Quantitative Assessment How large is the negative correction to social welfare associated with trade-induced inequality? Consider U.S. during the period 1979 2007: Two crucial questions: 1979 2007 Trade Share 0.092 0.140 Gini Coefficient 0.367 0.489 1 How much did the rise in the trade share increase aggregate disposable income? 2 Which share s of the 0.122 increase in the Gini is caused by that trade opening? Trade model will answer these questions, but suppose µ = 3% and s = 5%, 10%, and 20% 15 / 30

Welfarist Correction A Preliminary Quantitative Assessment It does not take an awful lot of inequality aversion to generate significant downward corrections to gains from trade Table 1. Social Welfarist Inequality Correction to Welfare Effects of Trade Integration Pareto Correction Lognormal Correction Contribution of Trade to Inequality Contribution of Trade to Inequality s = 5% s = 10% s = 20% s = 5% s = 10% s = 20% Inequality Aversion (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) ρ = 0 3.00% 3.00% 3.00% 3.00% 3.00% 3.00% ρ = 0.1 2.85% 2.69% 2.36% 2.91% 2.83% 2.65% ρ = 0.25 2.67% 2.33% 1.64% 2.79% 2.57% 2.12% ρ = 0.5 2.46% 1.92% 0.80% 2.57% 2.14% 1.25% ρ = 0.75 2.32% 1.63% 0.23% 2.36% 1.72% 0.39% ρ = 1 2.22% 1.43% -0.18% 2.15% 1.29% -0.46% ρ = 2 1.98% 0.96% -1.08% 1.31% -0.39% -3.81% 16 / 30

ECONOMIC MODEL 17 / 30

Open Economy Environment Consider a world economy with N + 1 symmetric regions Households can market their output locally or in any of the other N regions Trade/Offshoring involves two types of additional costs 1 Variable iceberg trade cost τ 2 Fixed cost of market access f (n) increasing in the number n of foreign markets served. We adopt f (n) = fn α Household income r ϕ = Υ 1 β n ϕ Q 1 β y β ϕ, where Υ nϕ = 1 + n ϕ τ β 1 β Taxation: the government does not observe export decisions and f (n) is not tax deductible: c ϕ = krϕ 1 φ fnϕ α 17 / 30

Relative Revenues, r/r Trade and Inequality Trade increases relative revenues of high-ability households (due to market access), but reduces that of low-ability households (due to foreign competition) 6 5 Autarky Open Economy 4 3 2 1 0 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800 900 1000 Productivity 18 / 30

Trade and Inequality 1.035 Gini Ratio, N=1 1.07 Variance(R/mean(R)) Ratio, N=1 1.03 1.025 1.02 1.015 1.01 Pre-Tax Post-Tax 1.06 1.05 1.04 1.03 1.005 1.02 1 1 1.5 2 2.5 Variable Trade Cost = 1.01 1 1.5 2 2.5 Variable Trade Cost = 1.12 1.1 1.08 1.06 1.04 1.02 Gini Ratio, N=10 Variance(R/mean(R)) Ratio, N=10 1.9 1.8 1.7 1.6 1.5 1.4 1.3 1 1 1.5 2 2.5 Variable Trade Cost = 1.2 1 1.5 2 2.5 Variable Trade Cost = 19 / 30

CALIBRATION AND COUNTERFACTUALS 20 / 30

Calibration and Counterfactuals Road Map We first calibrate the model to 2007 U.S. data (trade share, income distribution, tax progressivity) We then explore the implication of a move to autarky on 1 Aggregate Income 2 Income Inequality We use the model to gauge the quantitative importance of the two corrections developed above 1 How large are the gains from trade for different degrees of inequality aversion? 2 How large would the gains from trade be in the absence of costly redistribution (i.e., φ = 0)? 20 / 30

Hold the following parameters fixed Calibration 1 Elasticity of substitution = 4 (β = 3/4) BEJK (2003), Broda and Weinstein (2006), Antràs, Fort and Tintelnot (2014) 2 Iceberg trade costs (τ = 1.83) Anderson and Van Wincoop (2004), Melitz and Redding (2014) 3 Number of countries (N = 10) U.S. roughly 10-15% of world manufacturing; results not too sensitive to N above 5 Set baseline fixed cost f to match a U.S. trade share of 0.14 Set convexity of fixed costs to either α = 1 or α = 3 (consistent with preliminary estimates using U.S. exports) Labor supply elasticity: experiment with various values for γ between γ = 10000 (or ε 0) and γ = 5/3 (or ε = 1.5) 21 / 30

Calibration: Progressivity We set φ = 0.147, consistent with 2007 income data: 14.5 Log Income After Taxes and Transfers, 2007 13.5 12.5 11.5 10.5 y = 0.853x + 1.661 R² = 0.995 9.5 9.5 10.5 11.5 12.5 13.5 14.5 Log Market Income, 2007 22 / 30

Calibration: Distribution of Ability Use 2007 U.S. Individual Income Tax Public Use Sample approximately 2.5 million anonymized tax returns use NBER weights to ensure this is a representative sample we map market income to adjusted gross income in line 37 of IRS Form 1040 We follow two types of approaches: 1 Nonparametric approach: given other parameter values, one can recover the ϕ s from the observed distribution of adjusted gross income 2 Parametric approach: assume that ϕ LogNormal(µ, σ) and calibrate µ and σ to match the mean and the Gini coefficient of adjusted gross income 23 / 30

Parametric vs. Non-Parametric Approach Lognormal provides a reasonably good approximation, but it does a poor fit for the right-tail of the distribution, which looks Pareto 1 Income Distribution 2.6 Empirical Pareto Coefficient 0.9 0.8 0.7 Nonparametric Lognormal Data 2.4 2.2 0.6 2 0.5 1.8 0.4 1.6 0.3 0.2 1.4 0.1 1.2 0 6 8 10 12 log(r) 1 0 2 4 6 8 10 R #10 5 24 / 30

Gains from Trade and Inequality Calibrated welfare gains from trade are higher, the higher is the labor supply elasticity ε But relative to autarky trade induces more inequality when ε is high Gains from Trade Increase in Gini Coefficient Labor supply elasticity α = 1 α = 3 α = 1 α = 3 ε = 0 4.86% 4.02% 2.31% 1.70% ε = 0.1 5.52% 4.54% 2.44% 1.81% ε = 0.25 6.54% 5.36% 2.64% 1.95% ε = 0.5 8.31% 6.77% 2.92% 2.17% ε = 0.75 10.40% 8.32% 3.16% 2.35% ε = 1 12.41% 9.89% 3.36% 2.51% ε = 1.5 16.72% 13.21% 3.72% 2.78% 25 / 30

Welfarist Correction Welfarist correction is higher, the higher is risk/inequality aversion ρ and the lower is the labor supply elasticity ε With log utility (ρ = 1) and a labor supply elasticity of ε = 0.5, welfare gains are 20 25% lower 1.00 Welfarist Correction ( ) 1.00 Welfarist Correction ( ) 0.95 0.95 0.90 0.90 0.85 0.85 0.80 0.80 0.75 0.75 0.70 0.70 0.65 0.65 0.60 0 0.1 0.25 0.5 0.75 1 2 Degree of Risk/Inequality Aversion ( ) 0.60 0 0.1 0.25 0.5 0.75 1 2 Degree of Risk/Inequality Aversion ( ) 26 / 30

Costly Redistribution Correction Costly redistribution correction is higher, the higher is the labor supply elasticity ε When ε = 0.5, welfare gains are 15 20% lower 1.00 Costly Redistribution Correction ( =0) 0.95 0.90 0.85 0.80 0.75 0.70 0.65 0.60 Elasticity of Labor Supply 27 / 30

Welfare gains from trade 1.25 1.2 Undistorted Mean Income growth 1.15 1.1 Mean Welfare Median 1.05 1 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 Export share of revenues 28 / 30

OPTIMAL PROGRESSIVITY 29 / 30

Progressivity and Inequality Aversion Optimal progressively is lower in open economy greater inequality increase if φ is adjusted 1.25 1.2 Trade Equilibrium Social welfare, W 1.15 1.1 1.05 Autarky φ T φ A 1 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 Progressivity of taxation, φ 29 / 30

Progressivity and Inequality Aversion Observed progressivity φ 0.15 in 2007 is optimal if ρ 0.7 0.25 0.2 Progressivity of taxation, φ 0.15 0.1 0.05 Autarky Trade Equilibrium 0 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 Inequality aversion, ρ 29 / 30

Progressivity and Inequality Aversion Optimal progressively is lower in open economy greater inequality increase if φ is adjusted 0.66 1.2 0.64 1.1 0.62 1 Gini of revenues 0.6 0.58 Trade Equilibrium Mean revenues 0.9 0.8 Trade Equilibrium 0.56 0.7 0.54 Autarky 0.6 Autarky φ T φ A 0.52 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 Progressivity of taxation, φ φ 0.5 T φ A 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 Progressivity of taxation, φ 29 / 30

Conclusions Trade-induced inequality is partly mitigated via a progressive income tax system Still, compensation is not full so trade induces an increase in the inequality of disposable income should we measure gains using average income or adjust for inequality? Income taxation induces behavioral responses that affect the aggregate income response to trade integration should we adjust for this leaky bucket effect? We developed welfarist and costly redistribution corrections to standard measures of the gains from trade Under plausible parameter values, these corrections are nonneglible and eliminate about one-fifth of the gains 30 / 30

APPENDIX 31 / 30

On the Shape of the Tax Schedule The tax schedule might seem ad hoc, but it fits U.S. data remarkably well: log r d ϕ = log k + (1 φ) log r ϕ 14 Log Income After Taxes and Transfers 13 12 11 10 y = 0.818x + 2.002 R² = 0.988 9 9 10 11 12 13 14 Log Market Income CBO data, percentiles of income distribution 1979 2010 (similar fit with PSID) back to slides 32 / 30

On the Shape of the Tax Schedule Over Time Degree of Progressivity φ φ 0.1.2.3.4.5 1980 1990 2000 2010 Year back to slides 33 / 30