Nash Equilibria in a Group Pursuit Game

Similar documents
Static Model of Decision-making over the Set of Coalitional Partitions

A Note on Open Loop Nash Equilibrium in Linear-State Differential Games

Convex Sets Strict Separation. in the Minimax Theorem

Convex Sets Strict Separation in Hilbert Spaces

Binary Relations in the Set of Feasible Alternatives

Positive Consequences of Negative Attitude: Game-Theoretic Analysis

Set-valued Solutions for Cooperative Game with Integer Side Payments

Generalization Index of the Economic Interaction. Effectiveness between the Natural Monopoly and. Regions in Case of Multiple Simultaneous Projects

Binary Relations in the Space of Binary Relations. I.

ES 111 Mathematical Methods in the Earth Sciences Lecture Outline 3 - Thurs 5th Oct 2017 Vectors and 3D geometry

Advertising and Promotion in a Marketing Channel

A Note of the Strong Convergence of the Mann Iteration for Demicontractive Mappings

H Paths in 2 Colored Tournaments

Laplace Type Problem with Non-uniform Distribution

Interval Images Recognition and Fuzzy Sets

6.891 Games, Decision, and Computation February 5, Lecture 2

Dynamic Model of Space Robot Manipulator

On a Certain Representation in the Pairs of Normed Spaces

Qualitative Theory of Differential Equations and Dynamics of Quadratic Rational Functions

Alternate Locations of Equilibrium Points and Poles in Complex Rational Differential Equations

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics

Buffon-Laplace Type Problem for an Irregular Lattice

On a Boundary-Value Problem for Third Order Operator-Differential Equations on a Finite Interval

Fixed Duration Pursuit-Evasion Differential Game with Integral Constraints

Integration over Radius-Decreasing Circles

Explicit Expressions for Free Components of. Sums of the Same Powers

Novel Approach to Calculation of Box Dimension of Fractal Functions

International Mathematical Forum, Vol. 9, 2014, no. 36, HIKARI Ltd,

Diophantine Equations. Elementary Methods

Boundary Value Problem for Second Order Ordinary Linear Differential Equations with Variable Coefficients

Many-on-One Pursuit. M. Pachter. AFIT Wright-Patterson A.F.B., OH 45433

Hyers-Ulam-Rassias Stability of a Quadratic-Additive Type Functional Equation on a Restricted Domain

An Abundancy Result for the Two Prime Power Case and Results for an Equations of Goormaghtigh

Math-Net.Ru All Russian mathematical portal

Game Theory. Professor Peter Cramton Economics 300

On Optimality Conditions for Pseudoconvex Programming in Terms of Dini Subdifferentials

THE STUDY OF THE SET OF NASH EQUILIBRIUM POINTS FOR ONE TWO-PLAYERS GAME WITH QUADRATIC PAYOFF FUNCTIONS

A Generalization of p-rings

A Generalization of Generalized Triangular Fuzzy Sets

On Acyclicity of Games with Cycles

Factorization of Directed Graph Describing Protein Network

On Positive Stable Realization for Continuous Linear Singular Systems

Solving Homogeneous Systems with Sub-matrices

The Expansion of the Confluent Hypergeometric Function on the Positive Real Axis

Some Properties of a Semi Dynamical System. Generated by von Forester-Losata Type. Partial Equations

On Equilibria of Distributed Message-Passing Games

Game theory Lecture 19. Dynamic games. Game theory

Generalization of the Banach Fixed Point Theorem for Mappings in (R, ϕ)-spaces

Second Hankel Determinant Problem for a Certain Subclass of Univalent Functions

MATH 150 Pre-Calculus

Computational Game Theory Spring Semester, 2005/6. Lecturer: Yishay Mansour Scribe: Ilan Cohen, Natan Rubin, Ophir Bleiberg*

EC319 Economic Theory and Its Applications, Part II: Lecture 2

Solving a Class of Generalized Nash Equilibrium Problems

Double Total Domination on Generalized Petersen Graphs 1

Secure Weakly Connected Domination in the Join of Graphs

A Laplace Type Problems for a Lattice with Cell Composed by Three Quadrilaterals and with Maximum Probability

Locating Chromatic Number of Banana Tree

Dynamic Pricing in the Presence of Competition with Reference Price Effect

Finite Codimensional Invariant Subspace and Uniform Algebra

A Direct Proof of Caristi s Fixed Point Theorem

A Study on Linear and Nonlinear Stiff Problems. Using Single-Term Haar Wavelet Series Technique

Algorithmic Game Theory and Applications. Lecture 4: 2-player zero-sum games, and the Minimax Theorem

Strong Convergence of the Mann Iteration for Demicontractive Mappings

Some Reviews on Ranks of Upper Triangular Block Matrices over a Skew Field

An Approximate Solution for Volterra Integral Equations of the Second Kind in Space with Weight Function

A Present Position-Dependent Conditional Fourier-Feynman Transform and Convolution Product over Continuous Paths

Mixed 0-1 Linear Programming for an Absolute. Value Linear Fractional Programming with Interval. Coefficients in the Objective Function

Near-Potential Games: Geometry and Dynamics

Stationary Flows in Acyclic Queuing Networks

On the Deformed Theory of Special Relativity

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 30 Apr 2015

A Fixed Point Approach to the Stability of a Quadratic-Additive Type Functional Equation in Non-Archimedean Normed Spaces

KKM-Type Theorems for Best Proximal Points in Normed Linear Space

On Uniform Limit Theorem and Completion of Probabilistic Metric Space

Linearization of Two Dimensional Complex-Linearizable Systems of Second Order Ordinary Differential Equations

Game Theory DR. ÖZGÜR GÜRERK UNIVERSITY OF ERFURT WINTER TERM 2012/13. Strict and nonstrict equilibria

The Automorphisms of a Lie algebra

Convergence of Fractional Brownian Motion with Reflections to Uniform Distribution

On a 3-Uniform Path-Hypergraph on 5 Vertices

A Buffon - Laplace Type Problems for an Irregular Lattice and with Maximum Probability

Second Proof: Every Positive Integer is a Frobenius Number of Three Generators

Z. Omar. Department of Mathematics School of Quantitative Sciences College of Art and Sciences Univeristi Utara Malaysia, Malaysia. Ra ft.

Morera s Theorem for Functions of a Hyperbolic Variable

Algebrability of Certain Subsets of C 0 (R + )

On Multivalent Functions Associated with Fixed Second Coefficient and the Principle of Subordination

Double Contraction in S-Metric Spaces

Geometric Construction of an Ellipse from Its Moments

How to Make a Proof of Halting Problem More Convincing: A Pedagogical Remark

Caristi-type Fixed Point Theorem of Set-Valued Maps in Metric Spaces

Regular Generalized Star b-continuous Functions in a Bigeneralized Topological Space

A Generic Bound on Cycles in Two-Player Games

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206)

The Linear Chain as an Extremal Value of VDB Topological Indices of Polyomino Chains

Conjectural Variations in Aggregative Games: An Evolutionary Perspective

Direction and Stability of Hopf Bifurcation in a Delayed Model with Heterogeneous Fundamentalists

Basic Game Theory. Kate Larson. January 7, University of Waterloo. Kate Larson. What is Game Theory? Normal Form Games. Computing Equilibria

Recurrence Relations between Symmetric Polynomials of n-th Order

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Supermodular Games

Restrained Weakly Connected Independent Domination in the Corona and Composition of Graphs

Equiblocking Sets in K 2,2 -Designs and in K 3,3 -Designs

Transcription:

Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 10, 2016, no. 17, 809-821 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/10.12988/ams.2016.614 Nash Equilibria in a Group Pursuit Game Yaroslavna Pankratova St. Petersburg State University 7/9 Universitetskaya nab., St. Petersburg 199034 Russia Svetlana Tarashnina St. Petersburg State University 7/9 Universitetskaya nab., St. Petersburg 199034 Russia Denis Kuzyutin St. Petersburg State University 7/9 Universitetskaya nab., St. Petersburg 199034 Russia & National Research University Higher School of Economics Copyright c 2016 Yaroslavna Pankratova, Svetlana Tarashnina and Denis Kuzyutin. This article is distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. Abstract We study a group pursuit game with players moving on the plane with bounded velocities. The game is a nonzero-sum pursuit game between an evader and m pursuers acting independently of each other. The case of perfect information is considered. We find analytical formulas for calculating coordinates of the intersection points of the Apollonius circles. We construct a Nash equilibrium in this game. Existence of the Nash equilibrium is proved. Finally, we give several examples that illustrate the obtained results. Mathematics Subject Classification: 49N75

810 Yaroslavna Pankratova et al. Keywords: group pursuit game, Nash equilibrium, differential games 1 Introduction The process of pursuit represents a typical conflict situation. When only two players are involved in pursuit we deal with a classical zero-sum differential pursuit game. These games grew out of military problems and were developed in [1], [2], [3], [9], [10] and other works. When more than two players participate in a game and players objectives are not strictly opposite it is rather reasonable to consider this game as a nonzero-sum one. In terms, in such a case players are not aimed to destruct each other. In this paper we study a group pursuit game with one evader and m pursuers acting independently of each other. The game is supposed to be a nonzero-sum pursuit game with perfect information. This game was formalized and investigated in [8] and further developed in [6], [12]. As a solution of the constructed game we find a Nash equilibrium [5]. For this purpose for arbitrary initial positions of the players we construct the corresponding Apollonius circles and derive analytical formulas for calculating coordinates of all intersection points of the circles. Finally, we give several examples that illustrate the result. 2 Nonzero-sum group pursuit game We consider a group pursuit game with pursuers P 1, P 2,..., P m and evader E. The players move on a plane with bounded velocities. Denote by α 1, α 2,..., α m and β the maximal velocities of P 1, P 2,..., P m and E, respectively. Moreover, we suppose that β < min{α 1, α 2,..., α m }, where α 1, α 2,..., α m, β are constant. The players start their motion at the moment t = 0 at the initial positions P 0 1 = z 0 1, P 0 2 = z 0 2,..., P 0 m = z 0 m, E 0 = z 0 and have the possibility of making decisions continuously in time. At each instant t they may choose directions of their motion and velocities within prescribed limits. The sets of control variables U P, U Ei have the following forms U Pj = { u Pj = (u 1 P j, u 2 P j ) : (u 1 P j ) 2 + (u 2 P j ) 2 α 2 j}, j = 1, m, U E = { u E = (u 1 E, u 2 E) : (u 1 E) 2 + (u 2 E) 2 β 2 }. This means that the players move on a plane with bounded velocities and control the direction of their motion choosing parameters u Pj = (u 1 P j, u 2 P j ) and

Nash equilibria in a group pursuit game 811 u E = (u 1 E, u 2 E) at each time instant. The motion of the players is described by the following system of differential equations with initial conditions ż j = u Pj, u Pj U Pj, j = 1, m, ż = u E, u E U E (1) z 1 (0) = z 0 1,..., z m (0) = z 0 m, z(0) = z 0. (2) Let us denote by P1 t = z1,. t.., Pm t = zm, t E t = z t the current positions of the players at the time instant t. We consider the case of perfect information. This means that every player at each time instant t 0 knows the moment t and his own and all other player s positions. Additionally, we assume that the pursuers use strategies with discrimination against the evader. In other words, at each moment t pursuers P 1,..., P m know the vector-velocities u t E chosen by the evader at that time moment. Now we need to explain how the players choose their control variables throughout the game according to incoming information. We define a strategy of the evader as a function of time and the current positions of the players. A strategy of player E is a function u E (t, z1, t..., zm, t z t ) with values in U E. So, the evader uses piecewise open-loop strategies. Denote by U E the set of admissible strategies of player E. A strategy of player P j, j = 1, m, is a function of time, players positions and vector-velocities of the evader, i.e. u Pj (t, z1, t..., zm, t z t, u t E). In words, the class of admissible strategies of a pursuer consists of strategies with discrimination (counterstrategies). Denote by U Pj the set of admissible strategies of player P j, j = 1, m. Evader E is considered caught if the positions of P j and E coincide at some time moment. So, t Pj ( ) is the meeting time of pursuer P j and evader E which is defined as follows t Pj (z 0 1,..., z 0 m, z 0, u P1 ( ),..., u Pm ( ), u E ( )) = min{t : z t j = z t }, j = 1, m. If there is no such t, then t Pj = +. We say that the game is over if any of the pursuers captures the evader. Let t E (z 0 1,..., z 0 m, z 0, u P1 ( ),..., u Pm ( ), u E ( )) = min{t P1,..., t Pm }. Here t E is the first time moment for evader E when he meets any of the pursuers. Let K E be the payoff function of the evader. It is equal to its

812 Yaroslavna Pankratova et al. meeting time multiplied by some number γ > 0. Here γ is a price of a time unit. Thus, K E (z 0 1,..., z 0 m, z 0, u P1 ( ),..., u Pm ( ), u E ( )) = = γ t E (z 0 1,..., z 0 m, z 0, u P1 ( ),..., u Pm ( ), u E ( )). The payoff function of player P j (j = 1, m) is given as follows (3) K Pj (z 0 1,..., z 0 m, z 0, u P1 ( ),..., u Pm ( ), u E ( )) = = γ t Pj (z 0 1,..., z 0 m, z 0, u P1 ( ),..., u Pm ( ), u E ( )). (4) The objective of each player in the game is to maximize his own payoff function, i.e. each pursuer has a reason to meet the evader before the other players do and the evader wants to be caught as late as possible. So, we define this nonzero-sum pursuit game in a normal form Γ(z 0 1,..., z 0 m, z 0 ) = N, {U i } i N, {K i } i N, (5) where N = {P 1,..., P m, E} is the set of players, U i is the set of admissible strategies of player i, and K i is a payoff function of player i defined by (3) and (4), i N. The constructed game depends on initial positions of the players. Let us fix players initial positions and consider the game Γ(z 0 1,..., z 0 m, z 0 ). 3 The Apollonius circle In this game we suppose that the pursuers use the parallel pursuit strategy (Π-strategy) [8] which is defined below. Definition 3.1 The parallel pursuit strategy (Π-strategy) is a behavior of a pursuer which provides a segment P t E t connecting current players positions P t and E t at each time moment t > 0 to be parallel to the initial segment P 0 E 0 and its length strictly decreases. It is known that if pursuer P j uses the parallel pursuit strategy and evader E uses all possible strategies from U E, then all possible meeting points of evader E and pursuer P j cover the Apollonius disk. If the evader moves along a straight line with the maximal velocity, then the meeting point of E and P j lies on the Apollonius circle. Let us remind the following definition given in [8]. Definition 3.2 The Apollonius circle A(zj 0, z 0 ) for initial positions Pj 0 = zj 0 and E 0 = z 0 of pursuer P j and evader E, respectively, is the set of points M such that where α j > β > 0. E 0 M β = P 0 j M α j,

Nash equilibria in a group pursuit game 813 Denote by A j the Apollonius disk corresponding to the Apollonius circle A(z 0 j, z 0 ). The set of all intersection points of the Apollonius circles is denoted by A. First let us consider a three person game: with pursuers P 1, P 2 and one evader E. We have two intersection points of the Apollonius circles, so, A = {ẑ 12, z 12 }, where ẑ 12 is the farthest from E 0 intersection point and z 12 is the closest to E 0 intersection point of the Apollonius circles (Figure 1). A(z, z ) 0 0 1 ^ z 12 0 A(z, z 0 ) 2 O 0 1 E 0 O 0 2 P 0 2 ~ z 12 Figure 1 The Apollonius circles for the game Γ(z 0 1, z0 2, z0 ) For the Apollonius circle A(z 0 j, z 0 ) = S(O 0 j, R 0 j) of radius R 0 j with center at O 0 j we have the following formulas E 0 Oj 0 = β 2 P 0 1 z 0 j z 0 α 2 j β 2, R0 j = α j β z 0 j z 0, j = 1, 2, αj 2 β2 where is a distance in Euclidean space. Now let us consider the game Γ(z 0 1,..., z 0 m, z 0 ). For this game A = {(ẑ ij, z ij ) : i, j = 1, m, i < j}. Figure 2 The Apollonius circles for the game with an evader and m pursuers

814 Yaroslavna Pankratova et al. In order to find a Nash equilibrium in the game Γ(z 0 1,..., z 0 m, z 0 ) we need to know coordinates of the intersection points of the corresponding Apollonius circles. Further we define the farthest from the initial position E 0 intersection point ẑ that belongs to the set A 1... A m A (shaded area in Figure 2). As Apollonius circles are crossed in pairs, we consider two arbitrary pursuers P i, P j and evader E and determine two points ẑ ij and z ij from A. Given i, j = 1, n, i < j, we get the whole set A. For this purpose let us fix initial positions of the players: E : z 0 = (x 0 E, y 0 E), P i : z 0 i = (x 0 P i, y 0 P i ), P j : z 0 j = (x 0 P j, y 0 P j ). We construct the curvilinear coordinate system z 0 X Y with the beginning at z 0 that is the initial position of evader E. The axises z 0 X and z 0 Y go through the initial positions of pursuers P i and P j, respectively. Additionally, we consider Cartesian coordinate system z 0 XY with the same beginning at the point z 0. Denote by ϕ an angel between axises z 0 X and z 0 X and by ψ an angel between z 0 Y and z 0 Y. Here ϕ and ψ are defined by the formulas cos ϕ = x0 E x 0 P i z 0 z 0 i, cos ψ = x0 E x 0 P j z 0 zj 0, sin ϕ = y0 E y 0 P i z 0 z 0 i, Using the formulas for coordinate s transformation we obtain { x = x cos ϕ + y cos ψ, y = x sin ϕ + y sin ψ, sin ψ = y0 E yp 0 j z 0 zj 0. Oi 0 = (a i cos ϕ ; a i sin ϕ), a i = E 0 Oi 0, Oj 0 = (a j cos ψ; a j sin ψ), a j = E 0 Oj 0. The intersection points ẑ ij = (ˆx ij, ŷ ij ) and z ij = ( x ij, ỹ ij ) can be found from the following system of equations { (x ai cos ϕ) 2 + (y a i sin ϕ) 2 = R 2 i, (x a j cos ψ) 2 + (y a j sin ψ) 2 = R 2 j. (6) Subtracting the second equation from the first one we have the following equality 2x(a j cos ψ a i cos ϕ) + 2y(a j sin ψ a i sin ϕ) + a 2 i a 2 j = R 2 i R 2 j. (7) Now we need to consider several cases and subcases:

Nash equilibria in a group pursuit game 815 1. Let a j cos ψ a i cos ϕ = 0, then we have two subcases: (a) a j sin ψ a i sin ϕ = 0. It means that both circles have the same center. If their radiuses are equal (R i = R j ), then these circles coincide. In other case, the circle of a smaller radius lies inside the circle of a lager radius. So, such circles are not crossed and we should not take into account the pursuer whose Apollonius circle has a lager radius (in fact, this pursuer can never capture the evader earlier than the other one). (b) a j sin ψ a i sin ϕ 0. In this subcase the ordinates of the intersection points are equal and defined by the formula ŷ ij = ỹ ij = R2 i R 2 j a 2 i + a 2 j 2(a j sin ψ a i sin ϕ). (8) Substituting formula (8) to equation (7), we find x 1,2 ij = a i cos ϕ ± Ri 2 (y a i sin ϕ) 2. (9) It is easy to check that the inequality y a i sin ϕ R i is satisfies for the Apollonius circles corresponding to one evader and two pursuers. 2. If a j cos ψ a i cos ϕ 0, then x = Using the following notations c = R2 i Rj 2 + a 2 j a 2 i 2(a j cos ψ a i cos ϕ) y a j sin ψ a i sin ϕ a j cos ψ a i cos ϕ. (10) R2 i Rj 2 + a 2 j a 2 i 2(a j cos ψ a i cos ϕ), b = a j sin ψ a i sin ϕ a j cos ψ a i cos ϕ and substituting formulas (9) to (7), we get the following equation y 2 (b 2 + 1) 2y(a i sin ϕ b a i cos ϕ +c b)+c 2 2c a i cos ϕ +a 2 i R 2 i = 0. This quadratic equation has two real roots y 1,2 ij = a i sin ϕ b a i cos ϕ + cb ± Ri 2(b2 + 1) (c a i cos ϕ b a i sin ϕ) 2 b 2. + 1 (11) The inequality R 2 i (b 2 + 1) (c a i cos ϕ b a i sin ϕ) 2 is holds for all initial positions of the players and x 1 ij, x 2 ij can be found from (10).

816 Yaroslavna Pankratova et al. Thus, using formulas (8) and (9) or (10) and (11), we can calculate the coordinates of all intersection points of the Apollonius circles at the initial time moment. 4 Nash equilibrium in the game Γ(z 0 1,..., z 0 m, z 0 ) In nonzero-sum games there is a number of solution concepts that are based on some additional assumptions for players behaviour and structure of a game. One of them is Nash equilibrium [5]. Let us construct a Nash equlibrium in this game and formulate the main result of the paper. Theorem 4.1 In the game Γ(z 0 1,..., z 0 m, z 0 ) there exists a Nash equilibrium. It is constructed as follows: evader E moves along a straight line with the maximal velocity to the point ẑ, where ẑ = arg max z 0 z ij, i j, i, j = 1, m, z ij A 1... A m z ij are the intersection points of the Apollonius circles which belong to the intersection of all Apollonius disks; players P 1,..., P m use the parallel pursuit strategy (Π-strategy). The optimality of Π-strategy for a pursuit game with life-line was proved in [7]. Further we give some examples that illustrate Theorem 4.1 and the results of the previous section. Example 4.2 1 Let us consider a 4-person pursuit game Γ(z 0 1, z 0 2, z 0 3, z 0 ). The players initial positions are the following: z 0 1 = (5; 7), z 0 2 = (10; 6), z 0 3 = (13; 12), z 0 = (8; 8). The players move on a plane with the maximal velocities α 1 = α 2 = α 3 = 3, β = 2. In Figure 3 there are three Apollonius circles constructed at the initial time moment. So, in this game we have six intersection points of the Apollonius circles that make up the set A and are listed in Table 1. 1 All calculations are performed from formulas (8) (11) by means of a created computer program.

Nash equilibria in a group pursuit game 817 Figure 3 The Apollonius circles for the game with an evader and three pursuers The set A 1... A m is presented in Figure 3 by the shaded area. The intersection points that belong to this area are listed in the second column of Table 1. According to Theorem 4.1, evader E is captured at the point z 13 = (7,2; 10,85) by pursuers P 1 and P 3. A A 1... A m A ẑ ẑ 12 = (8,63; 12,16) z 12 = (7,48; 6,38) z 12 = (7,48; 6,38) ẑ 13 = (10,27; 5,01) z 13 = (7,2; 10,85) z 13 = (7,2; 10,85) z 13 = (7,2; 10,85) ẑ 23 = (3,01; 9,35) z 23 = (9,77; 9,2) z 23 = (9,77; 9,2) Table 1 In this game there exists a unique Nash equilibrium in which the players get the following payoffs K P1 = K P3 = 1, 48, K P2 =, K E = 1, 48. The total pursuit time is equal to 1, 48.

818 Yaroslavna Pankratova et al. Example 4.3 Let us consider a 5-person pursuit game Γ(z 0 1, z 0 2, z 0 3, z 0 4, z 0 ). The players initial positions are the following: z 0 1 = (5; 8), z 0 2 = (8; 5), z 0 3 = (11; 8), z 0 4 = (8; 11), z 0 = (8; 8). The players move on a plane with the maximal velocities α 1 = α 2 = α 3 = α 4 = 3, β = 2. In Figure 4 there are four Apollonius circles constructed at the initial time moment. So, in this game we have twelve intersection points of the Apollonius circles that make up the set A and are listed in Table 2. Figure 4 The Apollonius circles for the game with an evader and four pursuers The set A 1... A m is presented in Figure 4 by the shaded area. The intersection points that belong to this area are listed in the second column of Table 2.

Nash equilibria in a group pursuit game 819 A A 1... A m A ẑ ẑ 12 = (11,44; 11,44) z 12 = (6,96; 6,96) z 12 = (6,96; 6,96) z 12 = (6,96; 6,96) ẑ 13 = (8; 5,32) z 13 = (8; 10,7) ẑ 14 = (11,44; 4,56) z 14 = (6,96; 9,04) z 14 = (6,96; 9,04) z 14 = (6,96; 9,04) ẑ 23 = (4,56; 11,44) z 23 = (9,04; 6,96) z 23 = (9,04; 6,96) z 23 = (9,04; 6,96) ẑ 24 = (5,32; 8) z 24 = (10,7; 8) ẑ 34 = (4,56; 4,56) z 34 = (9,04; 9,04) z 34 = (9,04; 9,04) z 34 = (9,04; 9,04) Table 2 According to Theorem 4.1, evader E can be captured at several points, and namely, at z 12 = (6,96; 6,96) by pursuers P 1 and P 2 ; at z 14 = (6,96; 9,04) by pursuers P 1 and P 4 ; at z 23 = (9,04; 6,96) by pursuers P 2 and P 3 ; at z 34 = (9,04; 9,04) by pursuers P 3 and P 4. Here there exist several symmetrical Nash equilibria. The total pursuit time is equal to 0, 73. Taking into account the fact that the evader can be captured only by one or two pursuers we have a situation when the evader has an opportunity to choose one or another Nash equilibrium according to its preferences with respect to one or another pursuer. For example, if the evader prefers pursuers P 1 and P 2, then the players get the following payoffs K P1 = K P2 = 0, 73, K P3 = K P4 =, K E = 0, 73. And if the evader prefers pursuers P 3 and P 4, the situation for the players changes complectly and their payoffs are K P3 = K P4 = 0, 73, K P1 = K P2 =, K E = 0, 73. 5 Conclusion In the considered game there may be several Nash equilibria depending on initial positions of the players. For example, in a symmetric case the evader obtains the same payoff in all Nash equilibria. Thus, the evader has an opportunity to choose one or another Nash equilibrium according to its preferences with respect to one or another pursuer. However, this equilibria are

820 Yaroslavna Pankratova et al. distinguishable for pursuers. As a result, we have a competition between the pursuers in the game. To resolve this situation one can use a framework of multicriteria games [4] or apply a cooperative approach to this group pursuit game [6], [12]. Acknowledgements. The research of D. Kuzyutin has been partially supported by the grant 15-33-11190 of the Russian Foundation for Humanities. References [1] R. Isaaks, Differential Games: a Mathematical Theory with Applications to Warfare and Pursuit, Control and Optimization, New York, Wiley, 1965. [2] L. D. Bercovitz, W. H Fleming, On differential games with integral payoff, Contributions to the Theory of Games. Ann. of Math. Studies, 3 (1957), 413-435. [3] A. F. Kleimenov, Non Zero-sum Differential Games, Ekaterinburg, Nauka, 1993. [4] D. Kuzyutin, M. Nikitina, L. Razgulyaeva, On the A-equilibria properties in multicriteria extensive games, Applied Mathematical Sciences, 9 (2015), no. 92, 4565-4573. http://dx.doi.org/10.12988/ams.2015.55374 [5] J. F. Nash, Equilibrium points in n-person games, Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci. USA, 36 (1950), 48-49. http://dx.doi.org/10.1073/pnas.36.1.48 [6] Ya. B. Pankratova, Solution of a cooperative differential group pursuit game, Diskretnyi Analiz i Issledovanie Operatsii, 17 (2010), no. 2, 57-78, (in Russian). [7] L. A. Petrosjan, Life-line pursuit games with several players, Izv. Akad. Nauk Arm. SSR Ser. Mat., 1 (1966), no. 5, 331-340. [8] L. Petrosjan and G. Tomskii, Geometry of Simple Pursuit, Nauka, Novosibirsk, 1983, (in Russian). [9] B. N. Pshenichnyi, Simple pursuit by several objects, Cybernetics, 3 (1976), 145-146 (in Russian). [10] L. S. Pontryagin, On some differential games, Report of the USSR Academy of Sciences, 156 (1964), no. 4, (in Russian).

Nash equilibria in a group pursuit game 821 [11] S. Tarashnina, Nash equilibria in a differential pursuit game with one pursuer and m evaders, Game Theory and Applications, 3 (1998), 115-123. [12] S. Tarashnina, Time-consistent solution of a cooperative group pursuit game, International Game Theory Review, 4 (2002), 301-317. http://dx.doi.org/10.1142/s0219198902000719 Received: January 19, 2016; Published: March 11, 2016