Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming

Similar documents
Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming

Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming

Approximate Dynamic Programming

Introduction to Reinforcement Learning

Approximate Dynamic Programming

MDP Preliminaries. Nan Jiang. February 10, 2019

Reinforcement Learning

Approximate Dynamic Programming

An Adaptive Clustering Method for Model-free Reinforcement Learning

Finite-Sample Analysis in Reinforcement Learning

Planning in Markov Decision Processes

Internet Monetization

Introduction to Reinforcement Learning Part 1: Markov Decision Processes

INTRODUCTION TO MARKOV DECISION PROCESSES

MS&E338 Reinforcement Learning Lecture 1 - April 2, Introduction

An Empirical Algorithm for Relative Value Iteration for Average-cost MDPs

Lecture notes for Analysis of Algorithms : Markov decision processes

Christopher Watkins and Peter Dayan. Noga Zaslavsky. The Hebrew University of Jerusalem Advanced Seminar in Deep Learning (67679) November 1, 2015

Computational complexity estimates for value and policy iteration algorithms for total-cost and average-cost Markov decision processes

Abstract Dynamic Programming

Optimal Stopping Problems

Reinforcement Learning. Introduction

Analysis of Classification-based Policy Iteration Algorithms

Markov Decision Processes Infinite Horizon Problems

Introduction to Reinforcement Learning. CMPT 882 Mar. 18

Weighted Sup-Norm Contractions in Dynamic Programming: A Review and Some New Applications

Value and Policy Iteration

Basics of reinforcement learning

Elements of Reinforcement Learning

Stochastic Shortest Path Problems

On the Convergence of Optimistic Policy Iteration

Reinforcement Learning

CS599 Lecture 1 Introduction To RL

Understanding (Exact) Dynamic Programming through Bellman Operators

Reinforcement Learning and Optimal Control. ASU, CSE 691, Winter 2019

Markov Decision Processes and Solving Finite Problems. February 8, 2017

Lecture 3: Markov Decision Processes

The Art of Sequential Optimization via Simulations

MARKOV DECISION PROCESSES (MDP) AND REINFORCEMENT LEARNING (RL) Versione originale delle slide fornita dal Prof. Francesco Lo Presti

Reinforcement Learning

Total Expected Discounted Reward MDPs: Existence of Optimal Policies

5. Solving the Bellman Equation

Reinforcement Learning and Deep Reinforcement Learning

Real Time Value Iteration and the State-Action Value Function

Markov decision processes

Reinforcement Learning

Near-Optimal Control of Queueing Systems via Approximate One-Step Policy Improvement

Artificial Intelligence & Sequential Decision Problems

Prioritized Sweeping Converges to the Optimal Value Function

Lecture 17: Reinforcement Learning, Finite Markov Decision Processes

Reinforcement learning

CS 598 Statistical Reinforcement Learning. Nan Jiang

Algorithms for MDPs and Their Convergence

Optimal Control of an Inventory System with Joint Production and Pricing Decisions

Lecture 1: March 7, 2018

Procedia Computer Science 00 (2011) 000 6

, and rewards and transition matrices as shown below:

1 Markov decision processes

Reinforcement Learning. Yishay Mansour Tel-Aviv University

Infinite-Horizon Discounted Markov Decision Processes

CMU Lecture 11: Markov Decision Processes II. Teacher: Gianni A. Di Caro

1 Stochastic Dynamic Programming

Lecture 3: Policy Evaluation Without Knowing How the World Works / Model Free Policy Evaluation

Distributed Optimization. Song Chong EE, KAIST

Decision Theory: Markov Decision Processes

Markov Decision Processes Chapter 17. Mausam

Central-limit approach to risk-aware Markov decision processes

Value Function Based Reinforcement Learning in Changing Markovian Environments

CSE250A Fall 12: Discussion Week 9

Markov Decision Processes and their Applications to Supply Chain Management

Introduction to Reinforcement Learning

Reinforcement Learning with Function Approximation. Joseph Christian G. Noel

The Multi-Arm Bandit Framework

Biasing Approximate Dynamic Programming with a Lower Discount Factor

A Gentle Introduction to Reinforcement Learning

On Finding Optimal Policies for Markovian Decision Processes Using Simulation

Course 16:198:520: Introduction To Artificial Intelligence Lecture 13. Decision Making. Abdeslam Boularias. Wednesday, December 7, 2016

COMPUTING OPTIMAL SEQUENTIAL ALLOCATION RULES IN CLINICAL TRIALS* Michael N. Katehakis. State University of New York at Stony Brook. and.

The Simplex and Policy Iteration Methods are Strongly Polynomial for the Markov Decision Problem with Fixed Discount

6.231 DYNAMIC PROGRAMMING LECTURE 17 LECTURE OUTLINE

ON THE POLICY IMPROVEMENT ALGORITHM IN CONTINUOUS TIME

Exponential Moving Average Based Multiagent Reinforcement Learning Algorithms

Efficient Approximate Planning in Continuous Space Markovian Decision Problems

Q-Learning for Markov Decision Processes*

Open Theoretical Questions in Reinforcement Learning

Probabilistic Planning. George Konidaris

DS-GA 1002 Lecture notes 0 Fall Linear Algebra. These notes provide a review of basic concepts in linear algebra.

A Review of the E 3 Algorithm: Near-Optimal Reinforcement Learning in Polynomial Time

UNCORRECTED PROOFS. P{X(t + s) = j X(t) = i, X(u) = x(u), 0 u < t} = P{X(t + s) = j X(t) = i}.

Model-Based Reinforcement Learning with Continuous States and Actions

ARTIFICIAL INTELLIGENCE. Reinforcement learning

Stochastic Primal-Dual Methods for Reinforcement Learning

Some AI Planning Problems

Markov Decision Processes Chapter 17. Mausam

Motivation for introducing probabilities

Value Iteration and Action ɛ-approximation of Optimal Policies in Discounted Markov Decision Processes

Reinforcement Learning as Classification Leveraging Modern Classifiers

Basic Deterministic Dynamic Programming

Algorithms for Reinforcement Learning

Gradient Estimation for Attractor Networks

Transcription:

Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming A. LAZARIC (SequeL Team @INRIA-Lille) Ecole Centrale - Option DAD SequeL INRIA Lille EC-RL Course

In This Lecture A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 2/81

In This Lecture How do we formalize the agent-environment interaction? Markov Decision Process (MDP) A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 2/81

In This Lecture How do we formalize the agent-environment interaction? Markov Decision Process (MDP) How do we solve an MDP? Dynamic Programming A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 2/81

Mathematical Tools Outline Mathematical Tools The Markov Decision Process Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems Bellman Equations for Uniscounted Infinite Horizon Problems Dynamic Programming Conclusions A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 3/81

Mathematical Tools Probability Theory Definition (Conditional probability) Given two events A and B with P(B) > 0, the conditional probability of A given B is P(A B) = P(A B). P(B) A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 4/81

Mathematical Tools Probability Theory Definition (Conditional probability) Given two events A and B with P(B) > 0, the conditional probability of A given B is P(A B) = P(A B). P(B) Similarly, if X and Y are non-degenerate and jointly continuous random variables with density f X,Y (x, y) then if B has positive measure then the conditional probability is y B x A P(X A Y B) = f X,Y (x, y)dxdy x f X,Y (x, y)dxdy. y B A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 4/81

Mathematical Tools Probability Theory Definition (Law of total expectation) Given a function f and two random variables X, Y we have that E X,Y [ f (X, Y ) ] = EX [E Y [ f (x, Y ) X = x ] ]. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 5/81

Mathematical Tools Norms and Contractions Definition Given a vector space V R d a function f : V R + 0 an only if If f (v) = 0 for some v V, then v = 0. For any λ R, v V, f (λv) = λ f (v). is a norm if Triangle inequality: For any v, u V, f (v + u) f (v) + f (u). A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 6/81

Mathematical Tools Norms and Contractions L p -norm ( d ) 1/p v p = v i p. i=1 A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 7/81

Mathematical Tools Norms and Contractions L p -norm L -norm ( d ) 1/p v p = v i p. i=1 v = max 1 i d v i. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 7/81

Mathematical Tools Norms and Contractions L p -norm L -norm L µ,p -norm ( d ) 1/p v p = v i p. i=1 v = max 1 i d v i. ( d v µ,p = i=1 v i p ) 1/p. µ i A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 7/81

Mathematical Tools Norms and Contractions L p -norm L -norm L µ,p -norm L µ,p -norm ( d ) 1/p v p = v i p. i=1 v = max 1 i d v i. ( d v µ,p = i=1 v i p ) 1/p. µ i v i v µ, = max. 1 i d µ i A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 7/81

Mathematical Tools Norms and Contractions L p -norm L -norm ( d ) 1/p v p = v i p. i=1 v = max 1 i d v i. L µ,p -norm L µ,p -norm ( d v µ,p = i=1 v i p ) 1/p. µ i v i v µ, = max. 1 i d µ i L 2,P -matrix norm (P is a positive definite matrix) v 2 P = v Pv. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 7/81

Mathematical Tools Norms and Contractions Definition A sequence of vectors v n V (with n N) is said to converge in norm to v V if lim n v n v = 0. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 8/81

Mathematical Tools Norms and Contractions Definition A sequence of vectors v n V (with n N) is said to converge in norm to v V if lim n v n v = 0. Definition A sequence of vectors v n V (with n N) is a Cauchy sequence if lim sup m n v n v m = 0. n A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 8/81

Mathematical Tools Norms and Contractions Definition A sequence of vectors v n V (with n N) is said to converge in norm to v V if lim n v n v = 0. Definition A sequence of vectors v n V (with n N) is a Cauchy sequence if Definition lim sup m n v n v m = 0. n A vector space V equipped with a norm is complete if every Cauchy sequence in V is convergent in the norm of the space. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 8/81

Mathematical Tools Norms and Contractions Definition An operator T : V V is L-Lipschitz if for any v, u V T v T u L u v. If L 1 then T is a non-expansion, while if L < 1 then T is a L-contraction. If T is Lipschitz then it is also continuous, that is if v n v then T v n T v. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 9/81

Mathematical Tools Norms and Contractions Definition An operator T : V V is L-Lipschitz if for any v, u V T v T u L u v. If L 1 then T is a non-expansion, while if L < 1 then T is a L-contraction. If T is Lipschitz then it is also continuous, that is Definition if v n v then T v n T v. A vector v V is a fixed point of the operator T : V V if T v = v. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 9/81

Mathematical Tools Norms and Contractions Proposition (Banach Fixed Point Theorem) Let V be a complete vector space equipped with the norm and T : V V be a γ-contraction mapping. Then 1. T admits a unique fixed point v. 2. For any v 0 V, if v n+1 = T v n then v n v with a geometric convergence rate: v n v γ n v 0 v. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 10/81

Mathematical Tools Linear Algebra Given a square matrix A R N N : Eigenvalues of a matrix (1). v R N and λ R are eigenvector and eigenvalue of A if Av = λv. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 11/81

Mathematical Tools Linear Algebra Given a square matrix A R N N : Eigenvalues of a matrix (1). v R N and λ R are eigenvector and eigenvalue of A if Av = λv. Eigenvalues of a matrix (2). If A has eigenvalues {λ i } N i=1, then B = (I αa) has eigenvalues {µ i } µ i = 1 αλ i. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 11/81

Mathematical Tools Linear Algebra Given a square matrix A R N N : Eigenvalues of a matrix (1). v R N and λ R are eigenvector and eigenvalue of A if Av = λv. Eigenvalues of a matrix (2). If A has eigenvalues {λ i } N i=1, then B = (I αa) has eigenvalues {µ i } µ i = 1 αλ i. Matrix inversion. A can be inverted if and only if i, λ i 0. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 11/81

Mathematical Tools Linear Algebra Stochastic matrix. A square matrix P R N N is a stochastic matrix if 1. all non-zero entries, i, j, [P] i,j 0 2. all the rows sum to one, i, N j=1 [P] i,j = 1. All the eigenvalues of a stochastic matrix are bounded by 1, i.e., i, λ i 1. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 12/81

The Markov Decision Process Outline Mathematical Tools The Markov Decision Process Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems Bellman Equations for Uniscounted Infinite Horizon Problems Dynamic Programming Conclusions A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 13/81

The Markov Decision Process The Reinforcement Learning Model Environment Critic action / actuation reward state / perception Learning Agent A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 14/81

The Markov Decision Process Markov Chains Definition (Markov chain) Let the state space X be a bounded compact subset of the Euclidean space, the discrete-time dynamic system (x t ) t N X is a Markov chain if it satisfies the Markov property P(x t+1 = x x t, x t 1,..., x 0 ) = P(x t+1 = x x t ), Given an initial state x 0 X, a Markov chain is defined by the transition probability p p(y x) = P(x t+1 = y x t = x). A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 15/81

The Markov Decision Process Example: Weather prediction Informal definition: we want to describe how the weather evolves over time. Board! A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 16/81

The Markov Decision Process Markov Decision Process Definition (Markov decision process [1, 4, 3, 5, 2]) A Markov decision process is defined as a tuple M = (X, A, p, r) where A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 17/81

The Markov Decision Process Markov Decision Process Definition (Markov decision process [1, 4, 3, 5, 2]) A Markov decision process is defined as a tuple M = (X, A, p, r) where t is the time clock, A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 17/81

The Markov Decision Process Markov Decision Process Definition (Markov decision process [1, 4, 3, 5, 2]) A Markov decision process is defined as a tuple M = (X, A, p, r) where t is the time clock, X is the state space, A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 17/81

The Markov Decision Process Markov Decision Process Definition (Markov decision process [1, 4, 3, 5, 2]) A Markov decision process is defined as a tuple M = (X, A, p, r) where t is the time clock, X is the state space, A is the action space, A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 17/81

The Markov Decision Process Markov Decision Process Definition (Markov decision process [1, 4, 3, 5, 2]) A Markov decision process is defined as a tuple M = (X, A, p, r) where t is the time clock, X is the state space, A is the action space, p(y x, a) is the transition probability with p(y x, a) = P(x t+1 = y x t = x, a t = a), A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 17/81

The Markov Decision Process Markov Decision Process Definition (Markov decision process [1, 4, 3, 5, 2]) A Markov decision process is defined as a tuple M = (X, A, p, r) where t is the time clock, X is the state space, A is the action space, p(y x, a) is the transition probability with p(y x, a) = P(x t+1 = y x t = x, a t = a), r(x, a, y) is the reward of transition (x, a, y). A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 17/81

The Markov Decision Process Examples Park a car Find the shortest path from home to school Schedule a fleet of truck A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 18/81

The Markov Decision Process Policy Definition (Policy) A decision rule π t can be Deterministic: π t : X A, Stochastic: π t : X (A), A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 19/81

The Markov Decision Process Policy Definition (Policy) A decision rule π t can be Deterministic: π t : X A, Stochastic: π t : X (A), A policy (strategy, plan) can be Non-stationary: π = (π 0, π 1, π 2,... ), Stationary (Markovian): π = (π, π, π,... ). A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 19/81

The Markov Decision Process Policy Definition (Policy) A decision rule π t can be Deterministic: π t : X A, Stochastic: π t : X (A), A policy (strategy, plan) can be Non-stationary: π = (π 0, π 1, π 2,... ), Stationary (Markovian): π = (π, π, π,... ). Remark: MDP M + stationary policy π Markov chain of state X and transition probability p(y x) = p(y x, π(x)). A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 19/81

The Markov Decision Process Question Is the MDP formalism powerful enough? Let s try! A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 20/81

The Markov Decision Process Example: the Retail Store Management Problem Description. At each month t, a store contains x t items of a specific goods and the demand for that goods is D t. At the end of each month the manager of the store can order a t more items from his supplier. Furthermore we know that The cost of maintaining an inventory of x is h(x). The cost to order a items is C(a). The income for selling q items is f (q). If the demand D is bigger than the available inventory x, customers that cannot be served leave. The value of the remaining inventory at the end of the year is g(x). Constraint: the store has a maximum capacity M. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 21/81

The Markov Decision Process Example: the Retail Store Management Problem State space: x X = {0, 1,..., M}. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 22/81

The Markov Decision Process Example: the Retail Store Management Problem State space: x X = {0, 1,..., M}. Action space: it is not possible to order more items that the capacity of the store, then the action space should depend on the current state. Formally, at statex, a A(x) = {0, 1,..., M x}. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 22/81

The Markov Decision Process Example: the Retail Store Management Problem State space: x X = {0, 1,..., M}. Action space: it is not possible to order more items that the capacity of the store, then the action space should depend on the current state. Formally, at statex, a A(x) = {0, 1,..., M x}. Dynamics: x t+1 = [x t + a t D t ] +. Problem: the dynamics should be Markov and stationary! A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 22/81

The Markov Decision Process Example: the Retail Store Management Problem State space: x X = {0, 1,..., M}. Action space: it is not possible to order more items that the capacity of the store, then the action space should depend on the current state. Formally, at statex, a A(x) = {0, 1,..., M x}. Dynamics: x t+1 = [x t + a t D t ] +. Problem: the dynamics should be Markov and stationary! The demand D t is stochastic and time-independent. Formally, i.i.d. D t D. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 22/81

The Markov Decision Process Example: the Retail Store Management Problem State space: x X = {0, 1,..., M}. Action space: it is not possible to order more items that the capacity of the store, then the action space should depend on the current state. Formally, at statex, a A(x) = {0, 1,..., M x}. Dynamics: x t+1 = [x t + a t D t ] +. Problem: the dynamics should be Markov and stationary! The demand D t is stochastic and time-independent. Formally, i.i.d. D t D. Reward: r t = C(a t ) h(x t + a t ) + f ([x t + a t x t+1 ] + ). A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 22/81

The Markov Decision Process Exercise: the Parking Problem A driver wants to park his car as close as possible to the restaurant. 1 2 Reward t T p(t) Restaurant Reward 0 A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 23/81

The Markov Decision Process Exercise: the Parking Problem A driver wants to park his car as close as possible to the restaurant. 1 2 Reward t T p(t) Restaurant Reward 0 The driver cannot see whether a place is available unless he is in front of it. There are P places. At each place i the driver can either move to the next place or park (if the place is available). The closer to the restaurant the parking, the higher the satisfaction. If the driver doesn t park anywhere, then he/she leaves the restaurant and has to find another one. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 23/81

The Markov Decision Process Question How do we evaluate a policy and compare two policies? Value function! A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 24/81

The Markov Decision Process Optimization over Time Horizon Finite time horizon T : deadline at time T, the agent focuses on the sum of the rewards up to T. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 25/81

The Markov Decision Process Optimization over Time Horizon Finite time horizon T : deadline at time T, the agent focuses on the sum of the rewards up to T. Infinite time horizon with discount: the problem never terminates but rewards which are closer in time receive a higher importance. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 25/81

The Markov Decision Process Optimization over Time Horizon Finite time horizon T : deadline at time T, the agent focuses on the sum of the rewards up to T. Infinite time horizon with discount: the problem never terminates but rewards which are closer in time receive a higher importance. Infinite time horizon with terminal state: the problem never terminates but the agent will eventually reach a termination state. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 25/81

The Markov Decision Process Optimization over Time Horizon Finite time horizon T : deadline at time T, the agent focuses on the sum of the rewards up to T. Infinite time horizon with discount: the problem never terminates but rewards which are closer in time receive a higher importance. Infinite time horizon with terminal state: the problem never terminates but the agent will eventually reach a termination state. Infinite time horizon with average reward: the problem never terminates but the agent only focuses on the (expected) average of the rewards. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 25/81

The Markov Decision Process State Value Function Finite time horizon T : deadline at time T, the agent focuses on the sum of the rewards up to T. [ T 1 ] V π (t, x) = E r(x s, π s (x s )) + R(x T ) x t = x; π, s=t where R is a value function for the final state. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 26/81

The Markov Decision Process State Value Function Infinite time horizon with discount: the problem never terminates but rewards which are closer in time receive a higher importance. [ ] V π (x) = E γ t r(x t, π(x t )) x 0 = x; π, t=0 with discount factor 0 γ < 1: small = short-term rewards, big = long-term rewards for any γ [0, 1) the series always converge (for bounded rewards) A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 27/81

The Markov Decision Process State Value Function Infinite time horizon with terminal state: the problem never terminates but the agent will eventually reach a termination state. [ T ] V π (x) = E r(x t, π(x t )) x 0 = x; π, t=0 where T is the first (random) time when the termination state is achieved. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 28/81

The Markov Decision Process State Value Function Infinite time horizon with average reward: the problem never terminates but the agent only focuses on the (expected) average of the rewards. [ 1 V π (x) = lim E T T T 1 t=0 ] r(x t, π(x t )) x 0 = x; π. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 29/81

The Markov Decision Process State Value Function Technical note: the expectations refer to all possible stochastic trajectories. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 30/81

The Markov Decision Process State Value Function Technical note: the expectations refer to all possible stochastic trajectories. A non-stationary policy π applied from state x 0 returns (x 0, r 0, x 1, r 1, x 2, r 2,...) with r t = r(x t, π t (x t )) and x t p( x t 1, a t = π(x t )) are random realizations. The value function (discounted infinite horizon) is V π (x) = E (x1,x 2,...) [ t=0 ] γ t r(x t, π(x t )) x 0 = x; π, A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 30/81

The Markov Decision Process Optimal Value Function Definition (Optimal policy and optimal value function) The solution to an MDP is an optimal policy π satisfying π arg max π Π V π in all the states x X, where Π is some policy set of interest. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 31/81

The Markov Decision Process Optimal Value Function Definition (Optimal policy and optimal value function) The solution to an MDP is an optimal policy π satisfying π arg max π Π V π in all the states x X, where Π is some policy set of interest. The corresponding value function is the optimal value function V = V π. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 31/81

The Markov Decision Process Optimal Value Function Definition (Optimal policy and optimal value function) The solution to an MDP is an optimal policy π satisfying π arg max π Π V π in all the states x X, where Π is some policy set of interest. The corresponding value function is the optimal value function V = V π. Remark: π arg max( ) and not π = arg max( ) because an MDP may admit more than one optimal policy. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 31/81

The Markov Decision Process Example: the EC student dilemma 1 p=0.5 Rest 0.5 2 r=1 Rest 0.4 r= 10 r=0 Work Work 0.3 0.4 0.6 5 0.5 0.5 0.7 Rest 0.6 r=100 r= 1 3 0.5 Work 0.5 r= 10 0.9 Rest 0.1 1 Work 4 6 7 r= 1000 A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 32/81

The Markov Decision Process Example: the EC student dilemma Model: all the transitions are Markov, states x 5, x 6, x 7 are terminal. Setting: infinite horizon with terminal states. Objective: find the policy that maximizes the expected sum of rewards before achieving a terminal state. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 33/81

The Markov Decision Process Example: the EC student dilemma V = 88.3 1 r=0 0.5 Rest Work r= 1 V = 86.9 3 p=0.5 0.5 Work 0.5 r=1 0.5 0.3 0.4 0.7 Rest 0.6 Work 0.5 r= 10 V = 88.9 4 V = 88.3 2 Rest 0.6 0.9 Rest Work 0.4 0.1 1 r=100 r= 10 V = 10 5 V = 100 6 r= 1000 V = 1000 7 A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 34/81

The Markov Decision Process Example: the EC student dilemma V 7 = 1000 V 6 = 100 V 5 = 10 V 4 = 10 + 0.9V 6 + 0.1V 4 88.9 V 3 = 1 + 0.5V 4 + 0.5V 3 86.9 V 2 = 1 + 0.7V 3 + 0.3V 1 V 1 = max{0.5v 2 + 0.5V 1, 0.5V 3 + 0.5V 1 } V 1 = V 2 = 88.3 A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 35/81

The Markov Decision Process State-Action Value Function Definition In discounted infinite horizon problems, for any policy π, the state-action value function (or Q-function) Q π : X A R is [ ] Q π (x, a) = E γ t r(x t, a t ) x 0 = x, a 0 = a, a t = π(x t ), t 1, t 0 and the corresponding optimal Q-function is Q (x, a) = max π Qπ (x, a). A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 36/81

The Markov Decision Process State-Action Value Function The relationships between the V-function and the Q-function are: Q π (x, a) = r(x, a) + γ p(y x, a)v π (y) y X V π (x) = Q π (x, π(x)) Q (x, a) = r(x, a) + γ p(y x, a)v (y) y X V (x) = Q (x, π (x)) = max a A Q (x, a). A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 37/81

Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems Outline Mathematical Tools The Markov Decision Process Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems Bellman Equations for Uniscounted Infinite Horizon Problems Dynamic Programming Conclusions A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 38/81

Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems Question Is there any more compact way to describe a value function? Bellman equations! A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 39/81

Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems The Bellman Equation Proposition For any stationary policy π = (π, π,... ), the state value function at a state x X satisfies the Bellman equation: V π (x) = r(x, π(x)) + γ y p(y x, π(x))v π (y). A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 40/81

Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems The Bellman Equation Proof. For any policy π, V π (x) = E [ γ t r(x t, π(x t )) x 0 = x; π ] t 0 = r(x, π(x)) + E [ γ t r(x t, π(x t )) x 0 = x; π ] = r(x, π(x)) + γ y = r(x, π(x)) + γ y t 1 P(x 1 = y x 0 = x; π(x 0 ))E [ γ t 1 r(x t, π(x t )) x 1 = y; π ] p(y x, π(x))v π (y). t 1 A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 41/81

Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems The Optimal Bellman Equation Bellman s Principle of Optimality [1]: An optimal policy has the property that, whatever the initial state and the initial decision are, the remaining decisions must constitute an optimal policy with regard to the state resulting from the first decision. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 42/81

Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems The Optimal Bellman Equation Proposition The optimal value function V (i.e., V = max π V π ) is the solution to the optimal Bellman equation: V [ (x) = max a A r(x, a) + γ p(y x, a)v (y) ]. and the optimal policy is π (x) = arg max a A y [ r(x, a) + γ p(y x, a)v (y) ]. y A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 43/81

Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems The Optimal Bellman Equation Proof. For any policy π = (a, π ) (possibly non-stationary), V (x) (a) = max π E[ γ t r(x t, π(x t )) x 0 = x; π ] t 0 [ (b) = max r(x, a) + γ (a,π ) y (c) = max a (d) = max a [ r(x, a) + γ y [ r(x, a) + γ y ] p(y x, a)v π (y) ] p(y x, a) max V π (y) π ] p(y x, a)v (y). A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 44/81

Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems The Bellman Operators Notation. w.l.o.g. a discrete state space X = N and V π R N. Definition For any W R N, the Bellman operator T π : R N R N is T π W (x) = r(x, π(x)) + γ y p(y x, π(x))w (y), and the optimal Bellman operator (or dynamic programming operator) is [ T W (x) = max a A r(x, a) + γ p(y x, a)w (y) ]. y A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 45/81

Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems The Bellman Operators Proposition Properties of the Bellman operators 1. Monotonicity: for any W 1, W 2 R N, if W 1 W 2 component-wise, then T π W 1 T π W 2, T W 1 T W 2. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 46/81

Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems The Bellman Operators Proposition Properties of the Bellman operators 1. Monotonicity: for any W 1, W 2 R N, if W 1 W 2 component-wise, then 2. Offset: for any scalar c R, T π W 1 T π W 2, T W 1 T W 2. T π (W + ci N ) = T π W + γci N, T (W + ci N ) = T W + γci N, A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 46/81

Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems The Bellman Operators Proposition 3. Contraction in L -norm: for any W 1, W 2 R N T π W 1 T π W 2 γ W 1 W 2, T W 1 T W 2 γ W 1 W 2. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 47/81

Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems The Bellman Operators Proposition 3. Contraction in L -norm: for any W 1, W 2 R N T π W 1 T π W 2 γ W 1 W 2, T W 1 T W 2 γ W 1 W 2. 4. Fixed point: For any policy π V π is the unique fixed point of T π, V is the unique fixed point of T. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 47/81

Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems The Bellman Operators Proposition 3. Contraction in L -norm: for any W 1, W 2 R N T π W 1 T π W 2 γ W 1 W 2, 4. Fixed point: For any policy π T W 1 T W 2 γ W 1 W 2. V π is the unique fixed point of T π, V is the unique fixed point of T. Furthermore for any W R N and any stationary policy π lim (T π ) k W = V π, k lim (T k )k W = V. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 47/81

Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems The Bellman Equation Proof. The contraction property (3) holds since for any x X we have T W 1(x) T W 2(x) [ = max r(x, a) + γ p(y x, a)w ] [ a 1(y) max r(x, a ) + γ a y y (a) max a = γ max a [ r(x, a) + γ p(y x, a)w ] 1(y) [ r(x, a) + γ y y p(y x, a) W 1(y) W 2(y) y γ W 1 W 2 max a p(y x, a) = γ W 1 W 2, y p(y x, a )W 2(y) ] p(y x, a)w 2(y) ] where in (a) we used max a f (a) max a g(a ) max a(f (a) g(a)). A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 48/81

Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems Exercise: Fixed Point Revise the Banach fixed point theorem and prove the fixed point property of the Bellman operator. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 49/81

Bellman Equations for Uniscounted Infinite Horizon Problems Outline Mathematical Tools The Markov Decision Process Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems Bellman Equations for Uniscounted Infinite Horizon Problems Dynamic Programming Conclusions A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 50/81

Bellman Equations for Uniscounted Infinite Horizon Problems Question Is there any more compact way to describe a value function when we consider an infinite horizon with no discount? Proper policies and Bellman equations! A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 51/81

Bellman Equations for Uniscounted Infinite Horizon Problems The Undiscounted Infinite Horizon Setting The value function is [ T ] V π (x) = E r(x t, π(x t )) x 0 = x; π, t=0 where T is the first random time when the agent achieves a terminal state. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 52/81

Bellman Equations for Uniscounted Infinite Horizon Problems Proper Policies Definition A stationary policy π is proper if n N such that x X the probability of achieving the terminal state x after n steps is strictly positive. That is ρ π = max x P(x n x x 0 = x, π) < 1. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 53/81

Bellman Equations for Uniscounted Infinite Horizon Problems Bounded Value Function Proposition For any proper policy π with parameter ρ π after n steps, the value function is bounded as V π r max ρ t/n π. t 0 A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 54/81

Bellman Equations for Uniscounted Infinite Horizon Problems The Undiscounted Infinite Horizon Setting Proof. By definition of proper policy P(x 2n x x 0 = x, π) = P(x 2n x x n x, π) P(x n x x 0 = x, π) ρ 2 π. Then for any t N P(x t x x 0 = x, π) ρ t/n π, which implies that eventually the terminal state x is achieved with probability 1. Then V π = max E[ r(x t, π(x t )) x 0 = x; π ] x X t=0 r max P(x t x x 0 = x, π) t>0 nr max + r max t n ρ t/n π. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 55/81

Bellman Equations for Uniscounted Infinite Horizon Problems Bellman Operator Assumption. There exists at least one proper policy and for any non-proper policy π there exists at least one state x where V π (x) = (cycles with only negative rewards). Proposition ([2]) Under the previous assumption, the optimal value function is bounded, i.e., V < and it is the unique fixed point of the optimal Bellman operator T such that for any vector W R n T W (x) = max a A [ r(x, a) + p(y x, a)w (y)]. y Furthermore V = lim k (T ) k W. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 56/81

Bellman Equations for Uniscounted Infinite Horizon Problems Bellman Operator Proposition Let all the policies π be proper, then there exist µ R N with µ > 0 and a scalar β < 1 such that, x, y X, a A, p(y x, a)µ(y) βµ(x). y Thus both operators T and T π are contraction in the weighted norm L,µ, that is T W 1 T W 2,µ β W 1 W 2,µ. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 57/81

Bellman Equations for Uniscounted Infinite Horizon Problems Bellman Operator Proof. Let µ be the maximum (over policies) of the average time to the termination state. This can be easily casted to a MDP where for any action and any state the rewards are 1 (i.e., for any x X and a A, r(x, a) = 1). Under the assumption that all the policies are proper, then µ is finite and it is the solution to the dynamic programming equation µ(x) = 1 + max p(y x, a)µ(y). a Then µ(x) 1 and for any a A, µ(x) 1 + y p(y x, a)µ(y). Furthermore, p(y x, a)µ(y) µ(x) 1 βµ(x), for y β = max x y µ(x) 1 µ(x) < 1. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 58/81

Bellman Equations for Uniscounted Infinite Horizon Problems Bellman Operator Proof (cont d). From this definition of µ and β we obtain the contraction property of T (similar for T π ) in norm L,µ : T W 1 T W 2,µ = max x max x,a max x,a T W 1 (x) T W 2 (x) µ(x) y p(y x, a) W 1 (y) W 2 (y) µ(x) y p(y x, a)µ(y) W 1 W 2 µ µ(x) β W 1 W 2 µ A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 59/81

Dynamic Programming Outline Mathematical Tools The Markov Decision Process Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems Bellman Equations for Uniscounted Infinite Horizon Problems Dynamic Programming Conclusions A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 60/81

Dynamic Programming Question How do we compute the value functions / solve an MDP? Value/Policy Iteration algorithms! A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 61/81

Dynamic Programming System of Equations The Bellman equation V π (x) = r(x, π(x)) + γ y p(y x, π(x))v π (y). is a linear system of equations with N unknowns and N linear constraints. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 62/81

Dynamic Programming System of Equations The Bellman equation V π (x) = r(x, π(x)) + γ y p(y x, π(x))v π (y). is a linear system of equations with N unknowns and N linear constraints. The optimal Bellman equation V [ (x) = max a A r(x, a) + γ p(y x, a)v (y) ]. is a (highly) non-linear system of equations with N unknowns and N non-linear constraints (i.e., the max operator). y A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 62/81

Dynamic Programming Value Iteration: the Idea 1. Let V 0 be any vector in R N A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 63/81

Dynamic Programming Value Iteration: the Idea 1. Let V 0 be any vector in R N 2. At each iteration k = 1, 2,..., K A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 63/81

Dynamic Programming Value Iteration: the Idea 1. Let V 0 be any vector in R N 2. At each iteration k = 1, 2,..., K Compute V k+1 = T V k A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 63/81

Dynamic Programming Value Iteration: the Idea 1. Let V 0 be any vector in R N 2. At each iteration k = 1, 2,..., K Compute V k+1 = T V k 3. Return the greedy policy π K (x) arg max a A [ r(x, a) + γ y ] p(y x, a)v K (y). A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 63/81

Dynamic Programming Value Iteration: the Guarantees From the fixed point property of T : lim V k = V k A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 64/81

Dynamic Programming Value Iteration: the Guarantees From the fixed point property of T : lim V k = V k From the contraction property of T V k+1 V = T V k T V γ V k V γ k+1 V 0 V 0 A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 64/81

Dynamic Programming Value Iteration: the Guarantees From the fixed point property of T : lim V k = V k From the contraction property of T V k+1 V = T V k T V γ V k V γ k+1 V 0 V 0 Convergence rate. Let ɛ > 0 and r r max, then after at most iterations V K V ɛ. K = log(r max/ɛ) log(1/γ) A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 64/81

Dynamic Programming Value Iteration: the Complexity One application of the optimal Bellman operator takes O(N 2 A ) operations. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 65/81

Dynamic Programming Value Iteration: Extensions and Implementations Q-iteration. 1. Let Q 0 be any Q-function 2. At each iteration k = 1, 2,..., K Compute Q k+1 = T Q k 3. Return the greedy policy π K (x) arg max a A Q(x,a) A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 66/81

Dynamic Programming Value Iteration: Extensions and Implementations Q-iteration. 1. Let Q 0 be any Q-function 2. At each iteration k = 1, 2,..., K Compute Q k+1 = T Q k 3. Return the greedy policy Asynchronous VI. 1. Let V 0 be any vector in R N π K (x) arg max a A Q(x,a) 2. At each iteration k = 1, 2,..., K Choose a state x k Compute V k+1 (x k ) = T V k (x k ) 3. Return the greedy policy π K (x) arg max a A [ r(x, a) + γ p(y x, a)v K (y) ]. y A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 66/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Idea 1. Let π 0 be any stationary policy A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 67/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Idea 1. Let π 0 be any stationary policy 2. At each iteration k = 1, 2,..., K A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 67/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Idea 1. Let π 0 be any stationary policy 2. At each iteration k = 1, 2,..., K Policy evaluation given πk, compute V π k. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 67/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Idea 1. Let π 0 be any stationary policy 2. At each iteration k = 1, 2,..., K Policy evaluation given πk, compute V π k. Policy improvement: compute the greedy policy [ π k+1 (x) arg max a A r(x, a) + γ p(y x, a)v π k (y) ]. y A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 67/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Idea 1. Let π 0 be any stationary policy 2. At each iteration k = 1, 2,..., K Policy evaluation given πk, compute V π k. Policy improvement: compute the greedy policy [ π k+1 (x) arg max a A r(x, a) + γ p(y x, a)v π k (y) ]. 3. Return the last policy π K y A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 67/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Idea 1. Let π 0 be any stationary policy 2. At each iteration k = 1, 2,..., K Policy evaluation given πk, compute V π k. Policy improvement: compute the greedy policy [ π k+1 (x) arg max a A r(x, a) + γ p(y x, a)v π k (y) ]. 3. Return the last policy π K y Remark: usually K is the smallest k such that V π k = V π k+1. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 67/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Guarantees Proposition The policy iteration algorithm generates a sequences of policies with non-decreasing performance V π k+1 V π k, and it converges to π in a finite number of iterations. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 68/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Guarantees Proof. From the definition of the Bellman operators and the greedy policy π k+1 V π k = T π k V π k T V π k = T π k+1 V π k, (1) A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 69/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Guarantees Proof. From the definition of the Bellman operators and the greedy policy π k+1 V π k = T π k V π k T V π k = T π k+1 V π k, (1) and from the monotonicity property of T π k+1, it follows that V π k T π k+1 V π k, T π k+1 V π k (T π k+1 ) 2 V π k,... (T π k+1 ) n 1 V π k (T π k+1 ) n V π k,... A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 69/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Guarantees Proof. From the definition of the Bellman operators and the greedy policy π k+1 V π k = T π k V π k T V π k = T π k+1 V π k, (1) and from the monotonicity property of T π k+1, it follows that V π k T π k+1 V π k, T π k+1 V π k (T π k+1 ) 2 V π k,... (T π k+1 ) n 1 V π k (T π k+1 ) n V π k,... Joining all the inequalities in the chain we obtain V π k lim n (T π k+1 ) n V π k = V π k+1. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 69/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Guarantees Proof. From the definition of the Bellman operators and the greedy policy π k+1 V π k = T π k V π k T V π k = T π k+1 V π k, (1) and from the monotonicity property of T π k+1, it follows that V π k T π k+1 V π k, T π k+1 V π k (T π k+1 ) 2 V π k,... (T π k+1 ) n 1 V π k (T π k+1 ) n V π k,... Joining all the inequalities in the chain we obtain V π k lim n (T π k+1 ) n V π k = V π k+1. Then (V π k ) k is a non-decreasing sequence. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 69/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Guarantees Proof (cont d). Since a finite MDP admits a finite number of policies, then the termination condition is eventually met for a specific k. Thus eq. 1 holds with an equality and we obtain V π k = T V π k and V π k = V which implies that π k is an optimal policy. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 70/81

Dynamic Programming Exercise: Convergence Rate Read the more refined convergence rates in: Improved and Generalized Upper Bounds on the Complexity of Policy Iteration by B. Scherrer. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 71/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration Notation. For any policy π the reward vector is r π (x) = r(x, π(x)) and the transition matrix is [P π ] x,y = p(y x, π(x)) A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 72/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Policy Evaluation Step Direct computation. For any policy π compute V π = (I γp π ) 1 r π. Complexity: O(N 3 ) (improvable to O(N 2.807 )). A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 73/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Policy Evaluation Step Direct computation. For any policy π compute V π = (I γp π ) 1 r π. Complexity: O(N 3 ) (improvable to O(N 2.807 )). Exercise: prove the previous equality. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 73/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Policy Evaluation Step Direct computation. For any policy π compute V π = (I γp π ) 1 r π. Complexity: O(N 3 ) (improvable to O(N 2.807 )). Exercise: prove the previous equality. Iterative policy evaluation. For any policy π lim T π V 0 = V π. n Complexity: An ɛ-approximation of V π requires O(N 2 log 1/ɛ log 1/γ ) steps. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 73/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Policy Evaluation Step Direct computation. For any policy π compute V π = (I γp π ) 1 r π. Complexity: O(N 3 ) (improvable to O(N 2.807 )). Exercise: prove the previous equality. Iterative policy evaluation. For any policy π lim T π V 0 = V π. n Complexity: An ɛ-approximation of V π requires O(N 2 log 1/ɛ log 1/γ ) steps. Monte-Carlo simulation. In each state x, simulate n trajectories ((x i t ) t 0, ) 1 i n following policy π and compute ˆV π (x) 1 n n γ t r(xt i, π(xt i )). i=1 t 0 Complexity: In each state, the approximation error is O(1/ n). A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 73/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Policy Improvement Step If the policy is evaluated with V, then the policy improvement has complexity O(N A ) (computation of an expectation). A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 74/81

Dynamic Programming Policy Iteration: the Policy Improvement Step If the policy is evaluated with V, then the policy improvement has complexity O(N A ) (computation of an expectation). If the policy is evaluated with Q, then the policy improvement has complexity O( A ) corresponding to π k+1 (x) arg max Q(x, a), a A A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 74/81

Dynamic Programming Comparison between Value and Policy Iteration Value Iteration Pros: each iteration is very computationally efficient. Cons: convergence is only asymptotic. Policy Iteration Pros: converge in a finite number of iterations (often small in practice). Cons: each iteration requires a full policy evaluation and it might be expensive. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 75/81

Dynamic Programming Exercise: Review Extensions to Standard DP Algorithms Modified Policy Iteration λ-policy Iteration A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 76/81

Dynamic Programming Exercise: Review Linear Programming Linear Programming: a one-shot approach to computing V A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 77/81

Conclusions Outline Mathematical Tools The Markov Decision Process Bellman Equations for Discounted Infinite Horizon Problems Bellman Equations for Uniscounted Infinite Horizon Problems Dynamic Programming Conclusions A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 78/81

Conclusions Things to Remember The Markov Decision Process framework A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 79/81

Conclusions Things to Remember The Markov Decision Process framework The discounted infinite horizon setting A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 79/81

Conclusions Things to Remember The Markov Decision Process framework The discounted infinite horizon setting State and state-action value function A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 79/81

Conclusions Things to Remember The Markov Decision Process framework The discounted infinite horizon setting State and state-action value function Bellman equations and Bellman operators A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 79/81

Conclusions Things to Remember The Markov Decision Process framework The discounted infinite horizon setting State and state-action value function Bellman equations and Bellman operators The value and policy iteration algorithms A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 79/81

Conclusions Bibliography I R. E. Bellman. Dynamic Programming. Princeton University Press, Princeton, N.J., 1957. D.P. Bertsekas and J. Tsitsiklis. Neuro-Dynamic Programming. Athena Scientific, Belmont, MA, 1996. W. Fleming and R. Rishel. Deterministic and stochastic optimal control. Applications of Mathematics, 1, Springer-Verlag, Berlin New York, 1975. R. A. Howard. Dynamic Programming and Markov Processes. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 1960. M.L. Puterman. Markov Decision Processes: Discrete Stochastic Dynamic Programming. John Wiley & Sons, Inc., New York, Etats-Unis, 1994. A. LAZARIC Markov Decision Processes and Dynamic Programming 80/81

Conclusions Reinforcement Learning Alessandro Lazaric alessandro.lazaric@inria.fr sequel.lille.inria.fr