NETS 412: Algorithmic Game Theory March 28 and 30, Lecture Approximation in Mechanism Design. X(v) = arg max v i (a)

Similar documents
Knapsack Auctions. Sept. 18, 2018

Solution: Since the prices are decreasing, we consider all the nested options {1,..., i}. Given such a set, the expected revenue is.

Vickrey Auction VCG Characterization. Mechanism Design. Algorithmic Game Theory. Alexander Skopalik Algorithmic Game Theory 2013 Mechanism Design

Lecture 6: Communication Complexity of Auctions

2 Making the Exponential Mechanism Exactly Truthful Without

CS599: Algorithm Design in Strategic Settings Fall 2012 Lecture 7: Prior-Free Multi-Parameter Mechanism Design. Instructor: Shaddin Dughmi

Game Theory: Spring 2017

On the Impossibility of Black-Box Truthfulness Without Priors

CS 598RM: Algorithmic Game Theory, Spring Practice Exam Solutions

EECS 495: Combinatorial Optimization Lecture Manolis, Nima Mechanism Design with Rounding

1 Submodular functions

Welfare Maximization in Combinatorial Auctions

Vickrey Auction. Mechanism Design. Algorithmic Game Theory. Alexander Skopalik Algorithmic Game Theory 2013 Mechanism Design

Lecture 4. 1 Examples of Mechanism Design Problems

Lecture 10: Mechanism Design

a 1 a 2 a 3 a 4 v i c i c(a 1, a 3 ) = 3

CS599: Algorithm Design in Strategic Settings Fall 2012 Lecture 12: Approximate Mechanism Design in Multi-Parameter Bayesian Settings

1 The Knapsack Problem

CS364B: Frontiers in Mechanism Design Lecture #2: Unit-Demand Bidders and Walrasian Equilibria

Query and Computational Complexity of Combinatorial Auctions

Mechanism Design: Basic Concepts

Optimal Auctions with Correlated Bidders are Easy

Combinatorial Auction-Based Allocation of Virtual Machine Instances in Clouds

Lecture 10: Mechanisms, Complexity, and Approximation

Mechanism Design with Approximate Valuations. Alessandro Chiesa Silvio Micali Zeyuan Allen Zhu

Computationally Feasible VCG Mechanisms

CS599: Algorithm Design in Strategic Settings Fall 2012 Lecture 1: Introduction and Class Overview. Instructor: Shaddin Dughmi

Mechanism Design and Truthful Algorithms

Algorithmic Game Theory and Economics: A very short introduction. Mysore Park Workshop August, 2012

Module 18: VCG Mechanism

On the Complexity of Computing an Equilibrium in Combinatorial Auctions

CIS 700 Differential Privacy in Game Theory and Mechanism Design January 17, Lecture 1

Frugality and Truthfulness in Approximate Mechanism Design

CS 573: Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture date: April 11, 2008

Outline / Reading. Greedy Method as a fundamental algorithm design technique

Algorithmic Game Theory and Applications

Core-selecting package auctions. Han Dong, Hajir Roozbehani

Knapsack. Bag/knapsack of integer capacity B n items item i has size s i and profit/weight w i

CS 6901 (Applied Algorithms) Lecture 3

Lecture 11 October 7, 2013

This means that we can assume each list ) is

Mechanisms for Multi-Unit Auctions

CS599: Algorithm Design in Strategic Settings Fall 2012 Lecture 11: Ironing and Approximate Mechanism Design in Single-Parameter Bayesian Settings

Sequential Bidding in the Bailey-Cavallo Mechanism

theory of mechanism design has been applied in computational settings such as distributed resource and task allocation [16, 27, 26], communication net

CS364B: Frontiers in Mechanism Design Lecture #3: The Crawford-Knoer Auction

Truthful and Near-Optimal Mechanism Design via Linear Programming Λ

Mechanism Design. Terence Johnson. December 7, University of Notre Dame. Terence Johnson (ND) Mechanism Design December 7, / 44

Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanisms

Lecture Slides - Part 4

Motivation. Game Theory 24. Mechanism Design. Setting. Preference relations contain no information about by how much one candidate is preferred.

On Random Sampling Auctions for Digital Goods

CO759: Algorithmic Game Theory Spring 2015

Payment Rules for Combinatorial Auctions via Structural Support Vector Machines

A Theory of Robust Hardness for Truthful Mechanism Design

CPS 173 Mechanism design. Vincent Conitzer

Network Design and Game Theory Spring 2008 Lecture 2

Limits on Computationally Efficient VCG-Based Mechanisms for Combinatorial Auctions and Public Projects

CS 6783 (Applied Algorithms) Lecture 3

Algorithmic Game Theory Introduction to Mechanism Design

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012

A Review of Auction Theory: Sequential Auctions and Vickrey Auctions

NTU IO (I) : Auction Theory and Mechanism Design II Groves Mechanism and AGV Mechansim. u i (x, t i, θ i ) = V i (x, θ i ) + t i,

arxiv: v1 [cs.gt] 9 Sep 2011

Mechanism Design: Bayesian Incentive Compatibility

Redistribution Mechanisms for Assignment of Heterogeneous Objects

APPLIED MECHANISM DESIGN FOR SOCIAL GOOD

Welfare Maximization with Friends-of-Friends Network Externalities

Economics and Computation

1 Primals and Duals: Zero Sum Games

4 Lecture Applications

Worst-Case Optimal Redistribution of VCG Payments in Multi-Unit Auctions

Multi-object auctions (and matching with money)

Vasilis Syrgkanis Microsoft Research NYC

CSC2420 Spring 2017: Algorithm Design, Analysis and Theory Lecture 12

CS 781 Lecture 9 March 10, 2011 Topics: Local Search and Optimization Metropolis Algorithm Greedy Optimization Hopfield Networks Max Cut Problem Nash

The Computational Complexity of Truthfulness in Combinatorial Auctions

Two-Sided Matching. Terence Johnson. December 1, University of Notre Dame. Terence Johnson (ND) Two-Sided Matching December 1, / 47

Efficient Money Burning in General Domains

Exact and Approximate Equilibria for Optimal Group Network Formation

RADIO spectrum is a critical but scarce resource for. Approximately Truthful Mechanisms for Radio Spectrum Allocation

The Sample Complexity of Revenue Maximization in the Hierarchy of Deterministic Combinatorial Auctions

On Revenue Maximization with Sharp Multi-Unit Demands

9. Submodular function optimization

Algorithmic Mechanism Design

We set up the basic model of two-sided, one-to-one matching

On Greedy Algorithms and Approximate Matroids

Lecture 13 March 7, 2017

Optimization of Submodular Functions Tutorial - lecture I

Matching. Terence Johnson. April 17, University of Notre Dame. Terence Johnson (ND) Matching April 17, / 41

CORE AND NO-TREAT EQUILIBRIUM IN TOURNAMENT GAMES WITH EXTERNALITIES

What do you do when you can t use money to solve your problems?

Mechanism Design Tutorial David C. Parkes, Harvard University Indo-US Lectures Week in Machine Learning, Game Theory and Optimization

Submodular Secretary Problem and Extensions

Essential facts about NP-completeness:

On Characterizations of Truthful Mechanisms for Combinatorial Auctions and Scheduling

The Greedy Method. Design and analysis of algorithms Cs The Greedy Method

Lectures One Way Permutations, Goldreich Levin Theorem, Commitments

Virtual Robust Implementation and Strategic Revealed Preference

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann

Transcription:

NETS 412: Algorithmic Game Theory March 28 and 30, 2017 Lecture 16+17 Lecturer: Aaron Roth Scribe: Aaron Roth Approximation in Mechanism Design In the last lecture, we asked how far we can go beyond the VCG mechanism when we want to optimize an objective other than social welfare. In this lecture, we will explore a different reason we might need to go beyond the VCG mechanism, even when we want to optimize social welfare: computational complexity. Recall, that in mechanism design problem, the VCG mechanism has to implement the following social-welfare maximizing allocation rule: X(v) = arg max (a) a A What do we do when this problem is hard to solve for example, when it is NP-complete? For many NP-complete problems we have good approximation algorithms, but this is not enough. Recall that for many of the properties of the VCG mechanism (including crucially truthfulness and individual rationality), we depended on the choice rule computing the exactly welfare maximizing outcome. If we only have the ability to find an alternative that achieves 99% of the optimal social welfare, we might lose all of the incentive properties of the VCG mechanism. As a case study, we will consider the Knapsack auction setting. Definition 1 In a knapsack auction: Each bidder i {1,..., n} has a publicly known size R 0. The mechanism has a publicly known budget B R 0. The feasible alternatives are all subsets of bidders of total size B: A = {S {1,..., n} : B} i For each a A we write a i = 1 if i a. These are single parameter domains. Each bidder i has a real value R 0, and their value for alternative a is a i This is called a knapsack auction because finding the optimal social welfare alternative, i.e. arg max S A is NP-hard, which means we do not believe that there is any polynomial time algorithm for this task. But note that this is a very natural problem that we would like to be able to solve it models, for example, the problem of auctioning off seats on an airplane to people who have different sized parties, and many other discrete allocation problems in which there is some finite resource constraint. If we need to have an auction that runs in a reasonable amount of time, what can we do? We could attempt to use a choice rule which approximates the social welfare objective, and to find a pricing rule (necessarily different from the VCG pricing rule) which makes this choice rule dominant strategy truthful. We know from last lecture that if this is going to succeed, we have to not only come up with an approximation algorithm for the Knapsack problem, we need to come up with one that is a monotone non-decreasing choice rule. If we can do this, we are done we simply use the pricing rule from the last lecture to make it truthful. If we can t, we are out of luck. First, we define what it means to approximate the optimal social welfare: 16+17-1

Definition 2 For a set of values and weights v, w R n 0, let: OPT(v, w) = max S [n]: wi B denote the optimal solution to the knapsack instance defined by v and w. We say that an algorithm A is an α-approximation algorithm for the Knapsack problem if for every v, w R n 0, A(v, w) = S such that: 1. S is a feasible solution: B 2. S approximates OPT to within a factor of α: OPT(v,w) α Recall what it means in this setting for A to be a monotone non-decreasing allocation rule: for every v, w R n 0, and for every i and v i >, if S = A(v, w) and S = A((v i, v i), w), then: i S i S. Our goal is to come up with a monotone algorithm A that is also an α-approximation algorithm for the Knapsack problem, for a reasonable value of α. Lets think about how we might do that. The first observation we make is that we can write the knapsack problem in the following integer linear optimization form. We want to solve: maximize x i such that: x i B x i {0, 1} i where here the x i variables indicate whether agent i has been selected or not. This captures the problem we want to solve exactly; however, because solving this problem is NP-hard, it means we won t be able to reason very fruitfully about any structure that optimal solutions might have. Consider instead the following relaxed version of the problem, in which we let the x i variables be fractional: maximize x i such that: x i B x i [0, 1] i Write OPT F (v, w) to denote the optimal value of this fractional version of the problem. This is simply a linear programming problem which can be solved efficiently for our purposes, however, the benefit of this formulation is that we have some hope of understanding the structure of the solutions! We start with a simple observation: Claim 3 For all v, w R n 0 : OPT F (v, w) OPT(v, w) 16+17-2

Proof This holds simply because the fractional version of the problem is simply less constrained: any optimal solution to the integer version of the problem is a feasible solution to the fractional version, so OPT F (v, w) must always be at least as large as OPT(v, w) (since we can use the same optimal solution), but might be larger. What this means is if we can come up with an algorithm that obtains an α-approximation to OPT F (v, w) then we also obtain (at least!) an α-approximation to OPT(v, w), which is what we really want. It also leaves us free to consider the easier-to-understand solutions of the fractional relaxation. This relaxation has some simple structure: Lemma 4 Let x be a fractional solution obtaining value OPT F (v, w) in the fractional knapsack problem. Let i, j [n] be any pair of agents such that: Then x j > 0 x i = 1 > v j. Proof Suppose otherwise, and that for such an i, j pair, x j > 0 but x i < 1. Define δ > 0 by δ = min((1 x i ) wi, x j ). We now define a new solution x and argue that it is feasible, and has higher objective value, which will contradict the optimality of x. Let x l = x l for all l {i, j}, and let and x j = x j δ x i = x i + δ. Note that x continues to satisfy the knapsack constraint: the change in size of the bundle was: (δ ) δ = δ δ = 0 Moreover, by definition of δ, we know x j x j x j = 0 and x i x i + ((1 x i ) wi ) wj (because x was feasible) x is feasible. The change in value of the bundle is: = 1. Hence (δ ) δ v j > 0 This follows because by assumption: > v j ( ) > v j (by multiplying through by ). But then x has higher objective value than x while maintaining feasibility, which contradicts the optimality of x. Ok! Once we understand this structure, we can give a simple combinatorial algorithm for solving the fractional version of the knapsack problem, which will help us understand its behavior (recall we need to show that our algorithm in the end is monotone). Given our lemma, we know the algorithm given here (FractionalKnapsack) must be optimal. Now how can we use this algorithm to get a solution to the integer knapsack problem? (We know it optimally solves the fractional version). Note that until the last step, the algorithm is constructing an integer solution. So suppose we just leave out the last step, which fills the remaining space in the knapsack with the last element fractionally? We get an integer solution how well does it do? Terribly! Consider the following example. 16+17-3

FractionalKnapsack(v, w): Sort bidders in decreasing order by vi and set size 0 and i 1. while size+ B do Set x i 1, size size +, i i + 1. end while Set x i B size and Set x j = 0 for all j > i. Return x. Example 1 We have two agents with w 1 = v 1 = 10 and w 2 = 1 and v 2 = 1.1. Our knapsack has size B = 10. Note that OPT(v, w) = 10 the optimal solution picks agent 1. However, v 2 /w 2 > v 1 /w 1, so the algorithm first picks agent 2, and then has no remaining space for agent 1 so the algorithm picks a solution with value only 1.1 about 10 times worse. We could extend this example to make the algorithm s solution arbitrarily worse! Ok, we ve identified a problem the fractional algorithm may be optimal, but leaving off the fractional portion of the solution may leave almost the entire knapsack empty, wasting tons of value! Lets see if we can correct that with a second attempt (Greedy2). Note that without loss of generality, we can assume that for all agents i, B. This is because we can discard any agent with > B without harming OPT, because such an agent cannot have appeared in the optimal solution. Greedy2(v, w): Sort bidders in decreasing order by vi and set size 0 and i 1. Set S. while size+ B do Set S S {i}, size size +, i i + 1. end while if j S v j v j+1 then Output S. else Output {i } where i = arg max i. end if We argue that Greedy2 is a 2-approximation to the Knapsack problem: Theorem 5 Greedy2 achieves a 2-approximation algorithm for the Knapsack problem. Proof We derived Greedy2 from the optimal algorithm for the fractional knapsack problem in such a way that for every agent j: j S {i + 1} x j = 0 where x is the optimal fractional solution to the corresponding fractional knapsack instance (v, w). Hence we can conclude: + +1 OPT F (v, w) OPT(v, w). Therefore, we know that: max(, +1 ) OP T (v, w) 2 and because +1 by definition, the solution our algorithm outputs is: max(, ) OP T (v, w) 2 16+17-4

It remains to show that Greedy2 is monotone if we can do this, then we know that we can efficiently find a 2-approximation to the social welfare objective in the Knapsack problem while guaranteeing dominant strategy truthfulness. Theorem 6 Greedy2 is monotone non-decreasing for every agent i. Proof Fix any w, v R n 0, any agent i, and let v i >. Write v = (v i, v i). Let T = Greedy2(v, w) and T = Greedy2(v, w). We need to show that i T i T. Write S. = S(v, w) and S. = S(v, w) to denote the intermediate sets S generated by Greedy2 on each instance. First we argue: Claim 7 i S i S Proof Note that S and S represent the prefix of the bidders of total size B when sorted in decreasing order of vj. When agent i increases his value from to he can only move himself earlier in this sorted ordering, and so if he was in the prefix represented by S he is still in the prefix represented by S. Hence we know that if T = S and T = S, then on this instance, the algorithm is monotone. Note also that if i S, then j S v j j S v j. (If i S, as we argued, i S and so the two sets have identical membership. S has higher value because v i is increased and all other v j remain the same). Hence, if i S, then if T = S, T = S and the algorithm is monotone in this instance. The only remaining case with i T is if i = i and > j S v j. But note that in this case, we must also have i T. i remains the highest value bidder, and so is either output as T = {i } in the last step of the algorithm, or is output as T = S with i S (since in order to change the value of S, i must have raised his bid high enough to be included in it). Together, we have shown that there exists a polynomial time 2-approximation for the Knapsack problem that makes truthful bidding a dominant strategy for all players (despite the fact that we cannot use the VCG mechanism to give a polynomial time solution) 16+17-5