Myopic and perfect foresight in the OLG model

Similar documents
1 Introduction The eect of government debt on growth and welfare is an old debate. According to the view of Ricardo (1817), it is not by the payment o

2008/73. On the Golden Rule of Capital Accumulation Under Endogenous Longevity. David DE LA CROIX Grégory PONTHIERE

PUBLIC FINANCE RESEARCH PAPERS

Existence, uniqueness and stability of equilibria in an OLG model with persistent inherited habits

The Dynamics of Utility in the Neoclassical OLG Model

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Overlapping Generations Model with Endogenous. Labor Supply: General Formulation 1,2

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Competitive Equilibrium in an Overlapping Generations Model with Production Loans

ECON 581: Growth with Overlapping Generations. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Econ 7110 slides Growth models: Solow, Diamond, Malthus. January 8, 2017

Altruism and self-refrain David de la Croix y Philippe Michel z First draft: September 1997 This version: April 1998 Abstract We address the issue of

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

On the Dynamic Implications of the Cobb- Douglas Production Function

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

Overlapping Generation Models

Intergenerational Altruism and the Transfer Paradox in an Overlapping Generations Model

TOBB-ETU - Econ 532 Practice Problems II (Solutions)

Problem Set #2: Overlapping Generations Models Suggested Solutions - Q2 revised

Macro I - Practice Problems - Growth Models

From Difference to Differential Equations I

Multiple Interior Steady States in the Ramsey Model with Elastic Labor Supply

News Driven Business Cycles in Heterogenous Agents Economies

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

XLVIII Reunión Anual. Noviembre de 2013

Endogenous Growth Theory

EC9A2 Advanced Macro Analysis - Class #1

HOMEWORK #1 This homework assignment is due at 5PM on Friday, November 3 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.

The Pasinetti-Solow Growth Model With Optimal Saving Behaviour: A Local Bifurcation Analysis

Economic Growth

Characterization of Equilibrium Paths in a Two-Sector Economy with CES Production Functions and Sector-Specific Externality

EC744 Lecture Notes: Economic Dynamics. Prof. Jianjun Miao

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Third Edition

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

Lecture 4A: The Discrete-Time Overlapping-Generations Model: Basic Theory & Applications

Lecture 4: Dynamic Programming

Dynamic Optimization Using Lagrange Multipliers

Volume 29, Issue 4. Stability under learning: the neo-classical growth problem

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

14.05: Section Handout #1 Solow Model

A Policy Lesson from an Overlapping Generations Model of Habit Persistence

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

Lecture 1: Dynamic Programming

WORKING PAPER SERIES INTERGENERATIONAL ALTRUISM AND NEOCLASSICAL GROWTH MODELS NO. 386 / AUGUST 2004

ECON 582: Dynamic Programming (Chapter 6, Acemoglu) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Multiple Interior Steady States in the Ramsey Model with Elastic Labor Supply

Introduction to Recursive Methods

Overlapping Generations Model

ECON 582: The Neoclassical Growth Model (Chapter 8, Acemoglu)

A Note on the Ramsey Growth Model with the von Bertalanffy Population Law

Non-convex Aggregate Technology and Optimal Economic Growth

ADVANCED MACRO TECHNIQUES Midterm Solutions

Economics 202A Lecture Outline #3 (version 1.0)

Housing with overlapping generations

Neoclassical Growth Model: I

4.4 The functional distribution of income

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I

Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities

Suggested Solutions to Homework #3 Econ 511b (Part I), Spring 2004

Overlapping generations economy, environmental externalities, and taxation

Dynamic Optimization Problem. April 2, Graduate School of Economics, University of Tokyo. Math Camp Day 4. Daiki Kishishita.

SGZ Macro Week 3, Lecture 2: Suboptimal Equilibria. SGZ 2008 Macro Week 3, Day 1 Lecture 2

Graduate Macroeconomics - Econ 551

Advanced Macroeconomics

The Ramsey/Cass-Koopmans (RCK) Model

Growth Theory: Review

Lecture 1: The Classical Optimal Growth Model

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

1 THE GAME. Two players, i=1, 2 U i : concave, strictly increasing f: concave, continuous, f(0) 0 β (0, 1): discount factor, common

Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization

2007/8. The Problem of Non-Renewable Energy Pesources in the Production of Physical Capital. Agustin PEREZ-BARAHONA

Economic Growth (Continued) The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model. 1 Literature. Ramsey (1928) Cass (1965) and Koopmans (1965) 2 Households (Preferences)

Consumption-Savings Decisions with Quasi-Geometric Discounting: The Case with a Discrete Domain

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

The basic OLG model: Diamond

1. Money in the utility function (start)

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Consumption-Savings Decisions with Quasi-Geometric Discounting. Per Krusell and Anthony A. Smith, Jr. 1

Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM

Equilibrium in a Model with Overlapping Generations

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

On the dynamics of basic growth models: Ratio stability versus convergence and divergence in state space

Overlapping Generations Models An Introductory Course

A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Sequential Economies

Factor Substitution, Income Distribution, and Growth in a Generalized Neoclassical Model

The spatial Solow model. Abstract

The Real Business Cycle Model

Master 2 Macro I. Lecture 2 : Balance Growth Paths

SIMON FRASER UNIVERSITY. Economics 483 Advanced Topics in Macroeconomics Spring 2014 Assignment 3 with answers

A robust Hansen Sargent prediction formula

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Lecture 5: The neoclassical growth model

Macroeconomics II Dynamic macroeconomics Class 1: Introduction and rst models

HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 17 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.

Christiano 416, Fall 2014 Homework 1, due Wednesday, October Consider an economy in which household preferences have the following form:

1 Jan 28: Overview and Review of Equilibrium

Transcription:

Economics Letters 67 (2000) 53 60 www.elsevier.com/ locate/ econbase a Myopic and perfect foresight in the OLG model a b, * Philippe Michel, David de la Croix IUF, Universite de la Mediterranee and GREQAM, Centre de la Vieille Charite, rue de la Charite 2, F-3002 Marseille, France National Fund for Scientific Research and IRES, Universite catholique de Louvain, Place Montesquieu 3, B-348 Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium b Received 25 May 999; accepted 5 September 999 Abstract We compare the dynamics under myopic foresight and under perfect foresight in an overlapping generations model with capital accumulation and two-period lived individuals. When the rational dynamics are defined and the myopic dynamics are monotonic, the study of myopic foresight allows to characterize the dynamics under perfect foresight. The study of myopic dynamics also allows to obtain a condition of uniqueness of the steady state that bears only on the second order derivatives of the utility and production functions. 2000 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved. Keywords: Perfect foresight; Myopic foresight; Stability JEL classification: E32; O4. Introduction In a standard overlapping generations model with capital accumulation (Diamond, 965) there is in general a multiplicity of stationary equilibria (Galor and Ryder, 989). In the simple case of a logarithmic utility function, the capital stock of the next period is proportional to the wage of young agents. As the wage function is not necessarily a concave function of existing capital (for instance with a CES production function with low substitution possibilities) multiple stationary states can arise. With a logarithmic utility function the dynamics are the same for any type of expectation formation. With a more general utility function however, the savings function is defined over wages and the expected interest rate. The positive stationary states are the same for both perfect and myopic foresight but the dynamics are different. In this paper we address the issue of the relationship between *Corresponding author. Tel.: 32-0-473-453; fax: 32-0-473-945. E-mail address: delacroix@ires.ucl.ac.be (D. de la Croix) 065-765/ 00/ $ see front matter 2000 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved. PII: S065-765(99)00246-3

54 P. Michel, D. de la Croix / Economics Letters 67 (2000) 53 60 the dynamics under myopic foresight and those under perfect foresight. We show that this comparison is interesting as knowledge of the dynamics under myopic foresight allows, under certain conditions, to know the dynamics under perfect foresight. 2. Perfect and myopic foresight In a standard overlapping generations model with capital accumulation, we denote the life-cycle utility function u(c, d) where c is consumption when young and d consumption when old. The savings function s(w, R) is derived from the maximization of the life-cycle utility subject to the inter-temporal budget constraint and depends on wages and the interest rate. It is defined as the implicit function u 9(w 2 s, Rs) 5 Ru 9(w 2 s, Rs) c d The perfect foresight equilibrium is defined as follows: Given an initial capital stock k 0, an inter-temporal equilibrium with perfect foresight is a sequence of capital (k t) t$0 that satisfies for all t $ 0 e R 5 R 5 f 9(k ) () t t t kt 5]] s(v(k t), R t) (2) n e t where k denotes per capita capital. R denotes the expectations on the factor of interest R t, f(.) is the production function in intensive form, n is the growth rate of the population and v(k t) 5 f(k t) 2 ktf9(k t) is the wage function. Hence, at the inter-temporal equilibrium with perfect foresight the stock of capital of period t should verify the following implicit equation: ( n)k 2 s(v(k ), f 9(k )) 5 0. (3) t t t The existence of such equilibrium can be proved under fairly general assumptions on the technology and preferences. For the equilibrium to be unique the following additional assumption should be made: Assumption H. For all w. 0 and all k. 0, where D(k, w) 5 0 D 9k (k, w). 0, D(k, w) 5 ( n)k 2 s(w, f 9(k)) D 9(k, w) 5 n 2 s 9(w, f 9(k))f 0(k) k R One important difficulty for applications is that the hypothesis H is not directly formulated in terms of preferences and technologies but depends on the equilibrium values of k and w. A more appealing assumption on preferences is when the utility function verifies ;c. 0, u9(c) cu0(c) $ 0. This

P. Michel, D. de la Croix / Economics Letters 67 (2000) 53 60 55 condition is equivalent to assuming that the inter-temporal elasticity of substitution s(c) is greater or equal to. This implies that s 9R$ 0 and hence D 9k $ n for all w, k. 0: assumption H holds. Moreover, an interesting sufficient condition for H is if the utility function has a constant inter-temporal elasticity s and the production function is a CES with an elasticity of substitution /(r). In that case: with w D(k, w) 5 ( n) k 2]]]]] 2s 2s b R R 5 f 9(k) 5 aa 2r sf(k)/kd r The solution k of D(k, w) 5 0 is obtained by solving w/( n) 5 c(k) ; k k b 2s f 9(k) 2s 2s for k. Asc(k) is bounded above by k kb f 9(k)f 9() for k, and as limk 0 kf 9(k) 5 0, we have that c(0 ) 5 0. As c( `) 5`, the condition c9(k). 0 for all k guarantees the uniqueness of k. Recognizing that c(k) can be rewritten as t 2s 2r l 2l c(k) 5 k b saa df(k) k with l 5 ( r)( 2 s), the condition c9(k). 0 holds if l #, i.e. if s # 2 ]]. r Hence, the condition on s is more restrictive when possibilities for technological substitution are low. When r # 0, there is no restriction on s. Under assumption H, the equilibrium is unique and we may apply the implicit function theorem. Equilibrium is then characterized by the sequence of capital stocks kt defined by the difference equation k 5 g(k ) D(k, v(k )) 5 0 (4) t t t t where the derivative of g is s 9w (v(k), f 9( g(k)))v9(k) g9(k) 5 ]]]]]]]]]]].0 n 2 s 9 (v(k), f 9( g(k))) f 0( g(k)) R and the dynamics are monotonic. The uniqueness of the equilibrium is a fundamental property to interpret the perfect foresight assumption in a non ad-hoc way. In the case of uniqueness there is no exogenous problem of coordinating expectations, as each agent can solve the model and calculate the next period equilibrium kt which is necessary to obtain the rate of return f 9(k t). In the case of multiplicity of equilibria, agents do not know what the expectations of the others are and thus face a non-unique forward rate of 2s

56 P. Michel, D. de la Croix / Economics Letters 67 (2000) 53 60 return, unless some exogenous coordination device is assumed (like, e.g., sunspots). Notice finally that a sufficient condition for H to hold is that savings are non-decreasing in the interest rate. With the assumption of myopic foresight, e R 5 R 5 f 9(k ) t t t the inter-temporal equilibrium with initial capital stock k by the dynamics of k t : 0 is necessarily unique and is characterized kt 5]] s(v(k t), f 9(k t)) ; m(k t). (5) n The derivative of m(k) is m9(k) 5 ]] (s 9w(v(k), f 9(k))v9(k) s 9R(v(k), f 9(k))f 0(k)). (6) n 3. The steady states Proposition. The two dynamics with perfect and myopic foresight have the same positive steady states. Proof. k. 0 is a steady state for the dynamics with myopic foresight if and only if k 5 m(k ) 5]] s(v(k ), f 9(k )). n For the dynamics with perfect foresight, k. 0 is a steady state if and only if k 5 g(k ) 5]] s(v(k ), f 9( g(k ))) n and the two conditions are equivalent. h Notice that Proposition applies to positive steady states only. For the dynamics described by x 5 f(x ) with f: R R, we say that 0 is a corner steady state if t t f(0 ) 5 lim f(x) 5 0 x 0 We can then show by a simple counter-example that when 0 is a corner steady state of the dynamics with myopic foresight it is not necessarily a corner steady state of the dynamics with perfect foresight. The example is as follows: For a CES production function with r, 0 we have v(0 ). 0 and 2/s f 9(0 ) 5`. For a utility function u /(2 /s) with s, we have s(v(0 ), f 9(0 )) 5 0. Hence m(0 ) 5 0 but g(0 ). 0 and 0 is a corner steady state for the dynamics with myopic foresight only. In this situation, although wages are positive at k 5 0, savings are zero in the myopic foresight case because the interest factor forecasted on the basis of the current capital stock is infinite (agents do not forecast that the capital stock can be higher tomorrow). In the perfect foresight case savings are positive as agents expect the interest rate to be finite.

P. Michel, D. de la Croix / Economics Letters 67 (2000) 53 60 57 4. Local stability For the myopic dynamics (5), the derivative m9(k) is given by (6). The value of this derivative at the steady state determines the local stability of the steady state. For the rational dynamics, k 5 g(k ), we have at a steady state k. 0, g(k ) 5 k and t t s 9 (v(k ), f 9(k )) v9(k w ) g9(k ) 5 ]]]]]]]]].0. n 2 s 9R (v(k ), f 9(k )) f 0(k ) 99 If g9(k ),, k is locally stable. Under assumption H this is equivalent to s9wv9,n2s9rf or to m9(k ), (but m9(k ) may be smaller than 2 ). If g9(k )., k is unstable. The condition g9(k ). is equivalent to m9(k ).. Proposition 2. Consider a steady state k. 0 and assume H. In the case where m9(k ) $ 0(monotonic dynamics with myopic foresight), k is respectively stable, unstable or non-hyperbolic for the two dynamics when m9(k ) is respectively,,. or 5. In the case where m9(k ), 0, k is stable for the rational dynamics but may be stable (m9(k ).2) or unstable (m9(k ),2) for the myopic dynamics. Proof. When m9(k ) $ 0 we have um9(k )u 5 m9(k ) and the first order stability conditions for the two dynamics are identical. When m9(k ), 0, s9 v9, n 2 s9 f0, g9(k ), and k w R is stable for the rational dynamics. h Corollary. When the rational dynamics are defined (hyp. H) and the myopic dynamics are monotonic, the two dynamics have the same structure in the sense that the positive steady states are the same and the first order stability conditions are equivalent. This is a useful result in the case of monotonic myopic dynamics: indeed, the study of these dynamics, which are much simpler, allows to characterize the dynamics under perfect foresight. 5. Uniqueness of the steady state The savings function depends on the first derivatives of u and f. A general condition which is sufficient for uniqueness, e.g. the concavity of g, involves the third derivatives of u and f (see Galor and Ryder, 989). However, to study the number of steady states, we can use the results on the myopic dynamics and derive a simpler sufficient condition for uniqueness. Proposition 3. No more than one positive steady state k of the dynamics with perfect foresight exists when 9 s(v(k), f 9(k)) s 9(v(k), f 9(k))v (k) s 9 (v(k), f 9(k)) f 0(k),]]]], ;k. 0 w R k Such a steady state exists if and only if

58 P. Michel, D. de la Croix / Economics Letters 67 (2000) 53 60 s(v(k), f 9(k) lim ]]]]. n k 0 k Proof. No more than one positive steady state k exists if the function s(w(k), f 9(k)) /k is strictly decreasing, i.e. S d s(w(k), f 9(k))) s ]]]]]] 5] s9w v9sr9 f02 ],0, ;k. 0. dk k k k This condition can be rewritten s(v(k), f 9(k)) m9(k),]]]]]], ;k. 0 n k which leads to the expression in the proposition. The function s(w(k), f 9(k)) /k starts above n if and only if s(w(k), f 9(k) lim ]]]]. n k 0 k D holds, and, as it is decreasing and goes to 0, takes the value n only once?. Hence the steady state is unique. h As s(v(k), f 9(k)), v(k), a necessary condition of existence is limk 0 v(k)/k. n (see Galor and Ryder, 989). The interest of this proposition is to propose a condition of uniqueness that bears only on the second derivatives of the functions u and f. 6. Example To illustrate the conclusions of the this note, we take a CES production function f(k) 5 A(ak 2/r 2 a)) and the following utility function: 2r 2/s 2/s c bd ]]]]]] 2 /s 30 30 We assume that A 5 0, n 5.0 2, b 5 0.98 and a 5 0.35. In the first panel of Fig. we have chosen a production function with high substitution possibilities, r 520.5, and a low level of the inter-temporal elasticity of substitution, s 5 0.5. The dotted line represents the function kt 5 g(k t) (perfect foresight) and the solid line represents the function k 5 m(k ) (myopic foresight). Fig. t t illustrates the fact that the corner steady state can be different in the two dynamics. In the second panel of Fig., we keep s 5 0.5 and take a production function with low substitution possibilities, r 5 2. As the rational dynamics are defined and the myopic dynamics are monotonic, studying the

P. Michel, D. de la Croix / Economics Letters 67 (2000) 53 60 59 Fig.. Examples of dynamics under perfect foresight (???) and myopic foresight ( ). myopic dynamics is sufficient to characterize the stability type of the steady states under perfect foresight. In the last panel we have chosen a Cobb Douglas production function, r 0, and a high value of the inter-temporal elasticity of substitution, s 5 4. In this case, the dynamics with myopic foresight are oscillatory. For these parameter values, the positive steady state is stable in both cases. We have seen in the last panel of Fig. that the dynamics under myopic foresight oscillate near k*; k* is stable as long as m9(k*).2. When m9(k*),2, k* is unstable for the myopic dynamics. In this case the two steady states k* and 0 are unstable but the dynamics are bounded, as the function m has a finite maximum. To analyze the effect of the inter-temporal elasticity of substitution on the nature of the dynamics we present the bifurcation diagram (Fig. 2) for the parameter s given the other parameters (r 5 0). s lies on the horizontal axis, and we plot vertically limit values of the equilibrium sequences (k t). For relatively low s we observe a unique limit point which is a stable steady state. There is then an interval in which period doubling bifurcations occur more and more rapidly, showing the existence of deterministic stable cycles. Beyond a certain value, one enters into the chaotic region. Fig. 2. Bifurcation diagram for s.

60 P. Michel, D. de la Croix / Economics Letters 67 (2000) 53 60 7. Conclusion In this paper we have compared the dynamics under myopic foresight and those under perfect foresight in an overlapping generations model with capital accumulation. Our results are the following The two dynamics have the same positive steady state(s). When 0 is a corner steady state of the dynamics with myopic foresight, it is not necessary a corner steady state of the dynamics with perfect foresight. When the rational dynamics are defined and the myopic dynamics are monotonic, the study of myopic dynamics, which are much simpler, allows to characterize the dynamics under perfect foresight. The study of myopic dynamics allows to obtain a condition of uniqueness of the steady state that bears only on the second derivatives of the functions u and f. Acknowledgements The financial support of the PAI programme P4/ 0 is gratefully acknowledged. We thank Raouf Boucekkine for his comments on an earlier draft. References Diamond, P., 965. National debt in a neoclassical growth model. American Economic Review 55, 26 50. Galor, O., Ryder, H., 989. Existence, uniqueness and stability of equilibrium in overlapping generations model with productive capital. Journal of Economic Theory 49, 360 375.