Mohsen Bahmani-Oskooee, Tsangyao Chang, Tsung-Hsien Chen & Han-Wen Tzeng

Similar documents
Purchasing Power Parity in the 34 OECD Countries: Evidence from Quantile-Based Unit Root Tests with both Smooth and Sharp Breaks

Testing Purchasing Power Parity Hypothesis for Azerbaijan

Applied Econometrics and International Development Vol.9-1 (2009)

Purchasing power parity over two centuries: strengthening the case for real exchange rate stability A reply to Cuddington and Liang

Are real GDP levels nonstationary across Central and Eastern European countries?

Real exchange rate behavior in 4 CEE countries using different unit root tests under PPP paradigm

Inflation Revisited: New Evidence from Modified Unit Root Tests

Is Real Exchange Rates Nonlinear with A Unit Root? A Note on Romania s Experience

Frederick Wallace Universidad de Quintana Roo. Abstract

A New Nonlinear Unit Root Test with Fourier Function

Sustainability of balancing item of balance of payment for OECD countries: evidence from Fourier Unit Root Tests

Rejection Probabilities for a Battery of Unit-Root Tests

Purchasing Power Parity and the European Single Currency: Some New Evidence

Technical Appendix-3-Regime asymmetric STAR modeling and exchange rate reversion

PRAGUE ECONOMIC PAPERS / ONLINE FIRST

Parity Reversion of Absolute Purchasing Power Parity Zhi-bai ZHANG 1,a,* and Zhi-cun BIAN 2,b

A Panel Test of Purchasing Power Parity. under the Null of Stationarity.

Purchasing power parity: A nonlinear multivariate perspective. Abstract

Department of Economics, UCSB UC Santa Barbara

PURCHASING POWER PARITY BEFORE AND AFTER THE ADOPTION OF THE EURO

Purchasing Power Parity in South East Asian Countries Economies: A Cointegration Approach *

Volume 29, Issue 1. On the Importance of Span of the Data in Univariate Estimation of the Persistence in Real Exchange Rates

NONLINEAR DYNAMICS UNDER UNCOVERED INTEREST RATE PARITY: CASES OF THE CZECH REPUBLIC, HUNGARY AND SLOVAKIA 1

Szilárd MADARAS, 1 Lehel GYÖRFY 2 1. Introduction. DOI: /auseb

Oil price and macroeconomy in Russia. Abstract

The Dynamic Relationships between Oil Prices and the Japanese Economy: A Frequency Domain Analysis. Wei Yanfeng

Co-Integration and Causality among Borsa Istanbul City Indices and Borsa Istanbul 100 Index 1

OUTWARD FDI, DOMESTIC INVESTMENT AND INFORMAL INSTITUTIONS: EVIDENCE FROM CHINA WAQAR AMEER & MOHAMMED SAUD M ALOTAISH

Stationarity of South Asian Real Exchange Rates Under Exponential Star (ESTAR) Framework

Cointegration tests of purchasing power parity

Unit Roots, Nonlinear Cointegration and Purchasing Power Parity

Cointegration and Tests of Purchasing Parity Anthony Mac Guinness- Senior Sophister

Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme?

The Bootstrap: Theory and Applications. Biing-Shen Kuo National Chengchi University

Are PPP Tests Erratically Behaved? Some Panel Evidence

Choice of Spectral Density Estimator in Ng-Perron Test: Comparative Analysis

Output correlation and EMU: evidence from European countries

BALASSA-SAMUELSON EFFECTS, DEMAND SHIFTS AND REAL EXCHANGE RATE DETERMINATION: A non-linear analysis for Central European countries

Spatial Considerations on the PPP Debate *

THE LONG-RUN DETERMINANTS OF MONEY DEMAND IN SLOVAKIA MARTIN LUKÁČIK - ADRIANA LUKÁČIKOVÁ - KAROL SZOMOLÁNYI

Nikolaos Giannellis (University of Crete) and Athanasios Papadopoulos (University of Crete) Abstract

Are Forecast Updates Progressive?

Further evidence on the Real Interest Rate Parity hypothesis in Central and Eastern European Countries: unit roots and nonlinearities

Do Regions Matter for the Behavior of City Relative Prices in the U. S.?

7. Integrated Processes

The Prediction of Monthly Inflation Rate in Romania 1

The Panel Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle

The causal relationship between energy consumption and GDP in Turkey

Purchasing Power Parity in economies in transition: evidence from Central and East European countries.

Does Real Interest Rate Parity hold in Central and Eastern European Countries?

Nikolaos Giannellis (University of Crete) and Athanasios Papadopoulos (University of Crete) Abstract

Modelling real interest rate differentials: Evidence from the newly-accession EU countries

7. Integrated Processes

Trends and Unit Roots in Greek Real Money Supply, Real GDP and Nominal Interest Rate

On Perron s Unit Root Tests in the Presence. of an Innovation Variance Break

An Econometric Modeling for India s Imports and exports during

An Empirical Analysis of RMB Exchange Rate changes impact on PPI of China

Are Forecast Updates Progressive?

Inference in VARs with Conditional Heteroskedasticity of Unknown Form

The Analysis of External Debt Sustainability by Periodic Unit Root Test with Structural Break: The Case of Turkey

Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme?

Do real exchange rates really display parity-reverting behavior? In summarizing. An Unbiased Appraisal of Purchasing Power Parity

Projektbereich B Discussion Paper No. B-393. Katrin Wesche * Aggregation Bias in Estimating. European Money Demand Functions.

Estimates of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve for the USA with the General to Specific Method

Existence of Export-Import Cointegration: A Study on Indonesia and Malaysia

Warwick Business School Forecasting System. Summary. Ana Galvao, Anthony Garratt and James Mitchell November, 2014

A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED

Do exchange rates in caribbean and latin american countries exhibit nonlinearities? Abstract

Volume 29, Issue 2. Is Malaysian Stock Market Efficient? Evidence from Threshold Unit Root Tests

1 Regression with Time Series Variables

Panel Threshold Regression Models with Endogenous Threshold Variables

Asymmetry of the exchange rate pass-through: An exercise on the Polish data

The PPP Hypothesis Revisited

Periklis. Gogas. Tel: +27. Working May 2017

Frederick H. Wallace Universidad de Quintana Roo Chetumal, Quintana Roo México

ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN SWEDEN: A LEVERAGED BOOTSTRAP APPROACH, ( ) HATEMI-J, Abdulnasser * IRANDOUST, Manuchehr

Unit Roots and Structural Breaks in Panels: Does the Model Specification Matter?

Monitoring Euro Area Real Exchange Rates

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

A Non-Parametric Approach of Heteroskedasticity Robust Estimation of Vector-Autoregressive (VAR) Models

SHSU ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER

NON-LINEARITIES AND HYSTERESIS IN OECD UNEMPLOYMENT *

Volume 31, Issue 1. Mean-reverting behavior of consumption-income ratio in OECD countries: evidence from SURADF panel unit root tests

growth in a time of debt evidence from the uk

International Monetary Policy Spillovers

Predicting bond returns using the output gap in expansions and recessions

OLS Assumptions Violation and Its Treatment: An Empirical Test of Gross Domestic Product Relationship with Exchange Rate, Inflation and Interest Rate

Nonlinearity and Inflation Rate Differential Persistence: Evidence from the Eurozone.

University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series

CHAPTER III RESEARCH METHODOLOGY. trade balance performance of selected ASEAN-5 countries and exchange rate

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1

Do Markov-Switching Models Capture Nonlinearities in the Data? Tests using Nonparametric Methods

Cointegration tests of purchasing power parity

Research Statement. Zhongwen Liang

Volume 03, Issue 6. Comparison of Panel Cointegration Tests

Testing for Unit Roots with Cointegrated Data

Time scale regression analysis of oil and interest rate on the exchange rate: a case study for the Czech Republic

Introduction to Modern Time Series Analysis

Slides to Lecture 3 of Introductory Dynamic Macroeconomics. Linear Dynamic Models (Ch 2 of IDM)

Volatility. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University

Transcription:

Revisiting purchasing power parity in Eastern European countries: quantile unit root tests Mohsen Bahmani-Oskooee, Tsangyao Chang, Tsung-Hsien Chen & Han-Wen Tzeng Empirical Economics Journal of the Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna, Austria ISSN 0377-7332 Volume 52 Number 2 Empir Econ (2017) 52:463-483 DOI 10.1007/s00181-016-1099-z 1 23

Your article is protected by copyright and all rights are held exclusively by Springer- Verlag Berlin Heidelberg. This e-offprint is for personal use only and shall not be selfarchived in electronic repositories. If you wish to self-archive your article, please use the accepted manuscript version for posting on your own website. You may further deposit the accepted manuscript version in any repository, provided it is only made publicly available 12 months after official publication or later and provided acknowledgement is given to the original source of publication and a link is inserted to the published article on Springer's website. The link must be accompanied by the following text: "The final publication is available at link.springer.com. 1 23

Empir Econ (2017) 52:463 483 DOI 10.1007/s00181-016-1099-z Revisiting purchasing power parity in Eastern European countries: quantile unit root tests Mohsen Bahmani-Oskooee 1 Tsangyao Chang 2 Tsung-Hsien Chen 3 Han-Wen Tzeng 4 Received: 28 June 2015 / Accepted: 6 April 2016 / Published online: 8 June 2016 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2016 Abstract This study applies quantile unit root test proposed by Koenker and Xiao (J Am Stat Assoc 99(467):775 787, 2004) and Galvao (J Econom 152:165 178, 2009) to revisit the purchasing power parity in 7 transition countries: Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Hungary, Lithuania, Poland, Romania, and Russia over 1998M1 to 2015M3. While traditional unit root tests fail to reject unit root hypothesis, the two quantile unit root tests did reject unit root null hypothesis in all countries, providing support for the PPP and solving the PPP puzzle. The estimated half-life based on quantile autoregressive model is about 12 25 months (1 2 year). Keywords Purchasing power parity Quantile unit root test Transition countries Valuable comments of two anonymous referees are very much appreciated. Remaining errors, however, are our own. B Mohsen Bahmani-Oskooee bahmani@uwm.edu Tsangyao Chang tychang@mail.fcu.edu.tw Tsung-Hsien Chen cheng523@cyut.edu.tw Han-Wen Tzeng hann@ocu.edu.tw 1 The Center for Research on International Economics and Department of Economics, University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee, Milwaukee, WI, USA 2 Department of Finance, Feng Chia University, Taichung, Taiwan 3 Department of Insurance, Chaoyang University of Technology, Taichung, Taiwan 4 Department of Finance, Overseas Chinese University, Taichung, Taiwan

464 M. Bahmani-Oskooee et al. JEL Classification C22 F31 1 Introduction Purchasing power parity (hereafter, PPP) remains an interesting research topic in international macroeconomics. Validating the PPP is critical not only for empirical researchers but also for policymakers. PPP states that due to arbitrage activities in the international commodities market, the real exchange rates that combine the movements of relative prices with nominal exchange rates are expected to return to a constant equilibrium value in the long run. This means real exchange rate will be a mean-reverting process stationary in the long run. In particular, a non-stationary real exchange rate indicates that there is no long-run relationship between nominal exchange rate and domestic and foreign prices, thereby invalidating the PPP hypothesis (Lin et al. 2011). As such, PPP cannot be used to determine the equilibrium exchange rate, and an invalid PPP also disqualifies the monetary approach to exchange rate determination, which requires PPP to hold true. Empirical evidence on the stationarity of real exchange rates is abundant but inconclusive thus far. Previous studies by MacDonald and Taylor (1992), Taylor (1995), Taylor (2006), Peel and Venetis (2003), Lothian and Taylor (2000), Sarno and Taylor (2002), Taylor and Taylor (2004), Sjolander (2007), Bahmani-Oskooee et al. (2008), Bahmani-Oskooee and Hegerty (2009), Chang and Tzeng (2013), He and Chang (2013), He et al. (2014) and Bahmani-Oskooee et al. (2014)have provided in-depth information on its theoretical and empirical aspects. However, the above tests usually focus on the average behavior of real exchange rate without considering the influence of various sizes of shocks on real exchange rate. In other words, the speed of adjustment in real exchange rate toward its equilibrium is usually assumed to be constant, no matter how big or what sign the shock is. As a result, the commonly used conventional unit root tests possibly lead to a widespread failure in the rejection of unit root null hypothesis in real exchange rates. This paper intends to deal with the above deficiency by employing two newly developed quantile unit root tests by Koenker and Xiao (2004) and quantile unit root test with stationary covariates by Galvao (2009) to enhance estimation accuracy. In this study, we use quantile unit root tests to reinvestigate validity of the PPP in seven transition countries of Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Hungary, Lithuania, Poland, Romania, and Russia over 1998M1 to 2015M3. According to Hosseinkouchack and Wolters (2013), there are several advantages of these new tests. First, a quantile-based unit root test can allow for the possibility that shocks of different sign and magnitude to have different impacts on real exchange rate. Second, this approach is not restricted to a specific number of regimes. Indeed, it allows generally for differences in the transmission of all kinds of different shocks. Third, the tests avoid the estimation of additional regime parameters and therefore reduces estimation uncertainty. Fourth, the tests have higher powers than conventional unit root tests as shown by Koenker and Xiao (2004). Finally, the quantile-based unit root test is superior to standard unit root tests in case of departure from Gaussian residuals The transition countries in our sample have recently moved from centrally planned economies toward market-driven economies that motivate us to investigate the behav-

Revisiting purchasing power parity in Eastern European 465 ior of real exchange rate. Determining the behavior of exchange rates in such countries would provide information not only to policy makers in developing sound exchange rate and monetary policies but also to traders and global investors in their trade and investment strategies. Even though a number of studies have tested the PPP hypothesis in the transition economies (see, among others, Baharumshah and Borsic 2008; Lin et al. 2011; Solakoglu 2006; Cuestas 2009; Telatar and Hasanov 2009), this study differs from those studies by applying the quantile-based unit root tests for the first time. The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the data used in our study. Section 3 first briefly describes the quantile unit root tests proposed by Koenker and Xiao (2004) and Galvao (2009). Empirical results in support of PPP are reported in Sect. 4. Finally, a summary and conclusion appears in Sect. 5. 2Data This empirical analysis covers seven transition countries: Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Hungary, Lithuania, Poland, Romanian, and Russia. We employ monthly data in our empirical study, and the time span is from January 1998 to March 2015. 1 Due to data availability, our study can only focus on these seven transition countries. Some transition countries are excluded because they joined the European community and no longer have its own currency such as Estonia and Latvia. All consumer price indices, CPI (based on 2000 = 100), and nominal exchange rates relative to the USA dollar data, respectively, are taken from the Datastream. Each of the consumer price index and nominal exchange rate series was transformed into natural logarithms before performing the econometric analysis. Testing for the PPP against the USA is based on the argument that internal foreign exchange markets are mostly dollar dominated. In addition, funds for economic reconstructions are being provided by US-sponsored institutions (Bahmani-Oskoee et al. 2015). We define the bilateral real exchange rate, RE, as: ( P ) RE t = NE t (1) P where NE t is the nominal exchange rate defined as number of units of local currency per US dollar; P t and Pt are the domestic and US price levels, respectively, measured by consumer price indices (CPI). Taking log from both sides of (1) and denoting the log of each variable by small letter corresponding to that variable yield: t re t = ne t + p t P t (2) From a statistical point of view, the validity of the purchasing power parity (PPP) hypothesis reduces to a unit root test of re t. The presence of a unit root in the real 1 The period prior to 1998 was eliminated from the analysis because changes in overall inflation during the early years of the transition process (especially appreciation of the real exchange rate) were dominated by firm-level restructuring involving massive lay-offs, the adjustment of distorted relative prices from the Communist era and pegged exchange rate regimes motivated by concerns for macroeconomic stabilization.

466 M. Bahmani-Oskooee et al. Table 1 Summary statistics of real exchange rate Bulgaria Czech Hungary Lithuania Poland Romanian Russia Mean 2.695402 3.407058 3.927358 1.919865 1.576201 1.666739 3.315126 Median 2.740203 3.352193 3.858835 1.895301 1.539342 1.780723 3.242040 Maximum 2.180030 3.949979 4.439596 2.246229 1.915200 2.259344 3.958503 Minimum 3.091108 2.936943 3.480149 1.603565 1.127907 0.210172 2.874580 SD 0.284944 0.273464 0.238043 0.210025 0.174235 0.441420 0.343416 Skewness 0.383448 0.359096 0.473229 0.283116 0.113267 1.785139 0.485502 Kurtosis 1.635511 1.838082 2.030560 1.596982 2.261174 5.767393 1.826913 Jarque Bera 21.13089 16.09299 15.83202 19.74329 5.150695 175.9961 20.00121 Probability 0.000026 0.000320 0.000365 0.000052 0.076127 0.000000 0.000045 Observations 207 207 207 207 207 207 207 exchange rate series would imply that PPP does not hold in the long run. If PPP holds, it implies that nominal exchange rate is corrected for inflation differentials, as shown by (2). Chang et al. (2011) note that non-stationarity in real exchange rates has many macroeconomic implications. For example, Dornbusch (1987) has argued that if real exchange rate depreciates, it could bring a gain in international competitiveness, which in turn could shift the employment toward the country whose currency depreciates. Therefore, it is important to establish the empirical validity of the purchasing power parity theory. Another important implication of non-stationary in real exchange rate is that unbounded gains from arbitrage in traded goods are possible. In fact, Parikh and Williams (1998) have mentioned that a non-stationary real exchange rate can cause severe macroeconomic disequilibrium that would lead to real exchange rate devaluation in order to correct for external imbalance. Table 1 reports summary statistics of data, and we find that all data series are non-normal. As pointed by Koenker and Xiao (2004), the quantile-based unit root test has higher power than conventional unit root tests in case of departure from Gaussian residuals, and these further confirm the use of quantile unit root test in this paper. 3 The methods: quantile autoregressive unit root tests Let re t denote the log of real exchanger rate in our case and ε t a serially uncorrelated error term. An AR(q) process for re t with drift a is given by: re t = a + q γ i re t 1 + ε t, t = q + 1, q + 2,...,n. (3) i=1 The sum of the autoregressive coefficients is α = q i=1 γ i a measure of persistence that we will focus on in our study. We can rewrite Eq. (3) as:

Revisiting purchasing power parity in Eastern European 467 q 1 re t = αre t 1 + a + φ i re t i + ε t (4) Here we can run the usual unit root test. If α = 1, then the real exchange rate has a unit root, and therefore, shocks have permanent effects on real exchange rate. If we have α<1, then real exchange rate is stationary. In this case, shocks have only temporary effects on real exchange rate and this means PPP holds in this case. To gain more detailed estimates to analyze persistence, we can focus not only on the conditional mean, but also in the tails of the conditional distribution of re t, and here we can estimate Eq. (4) using quantile autoregression methods. The τth conditional quantile is defined as the value Q τ (re t ret 1,...,re t q ) such that the probability that output conditional on its recent and past history will be less than Q τ (re t ret 1,...,re t q ) is τ. For example, if exchange rate is very high (low) relative to recent exchange rate level, this means that a large positive (negative) shock has occurred and that re t is located above (below) the mean conditional on past observations re t 1,...,re t q somewhere in the upper (lower) conditional quantiles. The AR(q) process of real exchange rate at quantile τ can be written as: i=1 ( ) q 1 Q τ ret ret 1,...,re t q = α(τ)ret 1 + a(τ) + φ i (τ) re t i. (5) The test has been extended by Galvao (2009) to include deterministic components which is essential for unit root tests of drifting time series like real exchange rate in our case. Following Galvao (2009), we can extend Eq. (5) to include stationary covariates for unit root testing. Galvao (2009) has proved that his proposed model has more power than standard quantile unit test model. We can express his model as: ( ) q 1 Q τ ret ret 1,...,re t q = α(τ)ret 1 + a(τ) + φ i (τ) re t i + q2 I = q1 i=1 i=1 γ I (τ) X t I + F 1 u (τ) (6) where F u denotes the common distribution function of errors. Let a(τ) = a + Fu 1 (τ) define Z = (1, re t 1, re t 2,..., re t q+1, X t q2..., X t+q1 ) T. Here we can define X t I as stationary covariates (such as difference nominal exchange rate, stock returns, and inflation rate in our study). By estimating Eqs. (5) and (6) at different quantiles τ (0, 1), we can get a set of estimates of the persistence measure as α(τ). We can test α(τ) = 1 at different values of τ to analyze the persistence of the exchange rate impact of positive and negative shocks and shocks of different magnitude using the quantile autoregression-based unit root test proposed by Koenker and Xiao (2004). Let α(τ) be the quantile regression estimator. To test H 0 : α(τ) = 1, we use the t-stat for α(τ) proposed by Koenker and Xiao (2004) which can be written as

468 M. Bahmani-Oskooee et al. t n (τ) = f (F 1 (τ)) τ (1 τ) ( er 1 M Z er 1 ) 1/2 (α(τ) 1), (7) where f (u) and F(u) are the probability and cumulative density functions of ε t,re 1 is the vector of lagged log-real exchange rate, and M z is the projection matrix onto the space orthogonal to Z = (1, re t 1, re t 2,..., re t q+1 ) T for Koenker and Xiao (2004) approach or Z = (1, re t 1, re t 2,..., re t q+1, X t q2..., X t+q1 ) T for Galvao (2009) approach. 2 We use the results derived by Koenker and Xiao (2004) and Galvao (2009) to find the critical values of t n (τ) for different quantile levels. We can estimate f (F 1 (τ)) following the rule given in Koenker and Xiao (2004) and Galvao (2009). Besides allowing for asymmetric effects of shocks on real exchange rate, an important advantage of QAR-based unit root tests over standard unit root tests is that they have more power (Koenker and Xiao 2004; Galvao 2009). In contrast, a more complete inference of the unit root process based on the quantile approach involves exploring the unit root property across a range of quantiles. To this end, both Koenker and Xiao (2004) and Galvao (2009) suggest the Quantile Kolmogorov Smirnov (QKS) test, which is given as QKS = sup t n (τ) (8) τ Ɣ where t n (τ) is given by Eq. (7) and Ɣ = (0.1, 0.2,...0.9) in our later applications. In other words, we first calculate t n (τ) for all τ s in Ɣ and then construct the QKS test statistic by selecting the maximum value across Ɣ. While the limiting distributions of both t n (τ) and QKS tests are nonstandard, both Koenker and Xiao (2004) and Galvao (2009) also suggest the use of a resampling (number of bootstrap = 10000 in our case) procedure to approximate their small-sample distributions. 3 4 Empirical results We begin our empirics by first applying three conventional unit root tests ADF, PP, and KPSS tests. The results in Table 2 clearly indicate that both the ADF and the PP tests fail to reject the null of non-stationary real exchange rate for all 7 transition countries, with the exception of Romania. KPSS test get similar results. These results are consistent with those of Baharumshah and Borsic (2008), Liu et al. (2012), Chang and Tzeng (2013), and Bahmani-Oskoee et al. (2015), indicating that PPP does not hold in most transition countries. As mentioned before, due to deficiencies associated with conventional unit root tests, we now consider the quantile unit root of Koenker and Xiao (2004) first.here we test the null of α(τ) = 1forτ = 0.1, 0.2, 0.3, 04,...,0.9 byusingt statistic (t n (τ)) based on Eq. (7). Table 3 show the point estimates, the t statistics, the critical 2 Details about the selection of bandwidth, of kernel, and of truncation parameters, we follow the suggestion of Koenker and Xiao (2004) and Galvao (2009). Interested reader can refer to Koenker and Xiao (2004) and Galvao (2009). 3 For more details, see Koenker and Xiao (2004)andGalvao (2009).

Revisiting purchasing power parity in Eastern European 469 Table 2 Univariate unit root tests Level 1st Difference ADF PP KPSS ADF PP KPSS Bulgarian 1.253(0) 1.261[1] 1.587(11) 13.587(0) 13.587[0] 0.278(0) Czech 1.523(0) 1.514[3] 1.506(11) 15.150(0) 15.135[3] 0.271(2) Hungarian 1.529(0) 1.516[3] 1.346(11) 14.506(0) 14.509[2] 0.203(2) Lithuanian 1.382(0) 1.384[3] 1.581(11) 14.446(0) 14.446[3] 0.286(3) Poland 1.868(0) 1.930[4] 1.312(11) 14.379(0) 14.380[3] 0.(3) Romanian 4.516(0) 4.084[7] 1.204(11) 13.424(0) 14.209[8] 0.585(8) Russian 1.247(1) 1.234[6] 1.478(11) 11.341(0) 11.379[4] 0.187(6),,and indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 level, respectively. Bold values represent the significant relation to the critical values. The number in parentheses indicates the lag order selected based on the recursive t statistic, as suggested by Perron (1989). The number in the brackets indicates the truncation for the Bartlett Kernel, as suggested by the Newey West test (1987) values, half-life of a shock, and QKS for each country. We find that H 0 : α(τ) = 1 can be rejected at the 10 % significance level over the whole conditional real exchanger rate distribution based on Quantile Kolmogorov Smirnov test (QKS) for 3 out of 7 countries (i.e., Bulgaria, Lithuania, and Romania). The results confirm that all types of shocks to real exchange rate lead to temporary effects in these 3 transition countries. This means that PPP holds in these 3 transition countries (i.e., Bulgaria, Lithuania, and Romania). Table 3 also shows the persistent estimates of α(τ)for τ = 0.1, 0.2, 0.3,...,0.9 in each transition country. The persistence parameter estimates are close to one for all the quantiles considered in Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, and Russia. The persistent point estimate is slightly above one at the upper tail quantile for Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Hungary, and Poland and lower tail quantile for Lithuania. Overall, the parameter estimates are relatively homogeneous over the conditional exchange rate distribution. 4 Because PPP holds in Bulgaria, Lithuania, and Romania, Table 3 also calculate half-life of a shock for those 3 countries. We find that the estimated half-life based on quantile autoregressive model is about 12 25 months (1 2 year). Can we improve the results by shifting to Galvao (2009) test? Galvao (2009) points out that his proposed quantile unit root test with stationary covariates has more power than that of Koenker and Xiao (2004). We follow Elliott and Pesavento (2006), Su et al. (2012) and Liu and Chang (2013) to choose the stationary covariates according to economic theory. In our study, we use the first differences in nominal exchange rates, inflation, and stock returns. Results for these three stationary covariates are reported in Tables 4, 5, and 6, respectively. Based on results from Table 4, we can see that PPP now holds in all seven transition countries when difference nominal exchange rates serve as stationary covariates, based on QKS statistics. Table 5 reports our empirical results when we use stock returns to serve as our stationary covariates, and we find that PPP holds in four of these seven transition 4 Significant results in certain quantiles indicate asymmetric adjustment of real exchange rate process.

470 M. Bahmani-Oskooee et al. Table 3 Empirical results of quantile estimation and unit root tests for each quantile (without taking into stationary covariates) Koenker and Xiao (2004) τ 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Bulgaria α1(τ) 0.945 0.972 0.980 0.987 0.994 0.996 1.004 1.016 1.045 Half-lives 12.345 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 3.478 (0.009) Czech Republic α1(τ) 0.957 0.964 0.982 0.976 0.992 0.995 1.009 1.016 1.032 Half-lives 19.013 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 2.636 Hungary α1(τ) 0.981 0.982 0.990 0.985 0.993 0.996 1.004 1.011 1.001 Half-lives QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 1.283 Lithuania α1(τ) 1.009 1.026 1.008 1.007 0.998 0.991 0.978 0.973 0.955 Half-lives 25.612 15.192 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 2.973 (0.012) Poland α1(τ) 0.991 0.988 0.995 0.978 0.979 0.984 1.007 0.987 0.989 Half-lives QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 1.368

Revisiting purchasing power parity in Eastern European 471 Table 3 continued τ 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Romania α1(τ) 0.944 0.964 0.978 0.981 0.985 0.995 0.999 1.008 1.020 Half-lives 12.161 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 2.809 (0.022) Russia α1(τ) 0.989 0.988 0.993 0.992 0.991 0.987 0.989 0.988 0.984 Half-lives QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 2.483 and denotes significance at 5 and 1 % levels, respectively. Bold values represent the significant relation to the critical values. Numbers in parentheses denote bootstrap p values with the bootstrap replications set to be 10,000. For α1(τ), the unit root null is examined with the tn(τ) statistic. The lag length q is selected based on robust Schwarz information criterion as suggested by Galvao (2009) with a maximum lag set to be 12. The number in parentheses is p value.

472 M. Bahmani-Oskooee et al. Table 4 Empirical results of quantile estimation and unit root tests for each quantile (taking into account stationary covariates first difference of nominal exchange rate) Galvao (2009) τ 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Bulgaria α1(τ) 0.964 0.974 0.984 0.987 0.997 1.001 1.004 1.007 1.022 ˆδ 2 0.004 0.098 0.027 0.005 0.007 0.002 0.0003 0.0002 0.0012 Half-lives 18.905 26.311 42.974 52.971 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 5.834 (0.000) [8, 1, 1] Czech Republic α1(τ) 0.958 0.981 0.982 0.987 0.992 1.003 1.005 1.011 1.015 ˆδ 2 0.002 0.050 0.056 0.0066 0.0385 0.0127 0.0654 0.1012 0.003 Half-lives 16.154 36.134 38.160 52.971 86.296 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 7.764 (0.000) [1, 1, 1] Hungary α1(τ) 0.977 0.982 0.986 0.989 0.993 1.000 1.003 1.004 1.011 ˆδ 2 0.0034 0.0003 0.003 0.001 0.0245 0.0672 0.0032 0.0357 0.158 Half-lives 29.788 38.160 49.163 62.666 98.674 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 4.493 (0.000) [1, 1, 1] Lithuania α1(τ) 0.996 0.999 0.998 1.0004 1.0009 1.004 1.008 1.0.10 1.010 ˆδ 2 0.029 0.101 0.0169 0.0417 0.0323 0.007 0.0039 0.0686 0.0022 Half-lives QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 4.455 (0.000) [1, 1, 1]

Revisiting purchasing power parity in Eastern European 473 Table 4 continued τ 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Poland α1(τ) 0.987 0.984 0.985 0.989 0.991 0.995 0.997 1.006 1.011 ˆδ 2 0.0018 0.0040 0.0173 0.0612 0.0135 0.0533 0.0458 0.0702 0.0684 Half-lives 42.974 45.862 62.666 76.669 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 3.996 (0.000) [8, 1, 1] Romania α1(τ) 1.007 1.012 1.0185 1.019 1.0158 1.0154 1.0149 1.0154 1.0173 ˆδ 2 0.415 0.0949 0.0716 0.0047 0.0065 0.0646 0.0796 0.0191 0.3152 Half-lives QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 4.861 (0.000) [1, 2, 1] Russia α1(τ) 0.987 0.9884 0.9885 0.9894 0.9912 0.9946 0.9957 0.9981 1.0018 ˆδ 2 0.0618 0.0031 0.0732 0.0267 0.0364 0.00005 0.0231 0.0200 0.1293 Half-lives 52.971 59.406 59.926 65.044 78.419 128.104 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 6.454 (0.000) [11, 1, 2] and denotes significance at 5 and 1 % levels, respectively. Bold values represent the significant relation to the critical values. Numbers in parentheses denote bootstrap p values with the bootstrap replications set to be 10,000. For α1(τ), the unit root null is examined with the tn(τ) statistic. The lag lengths p and q in the bracket are selected based on robust Schwarz information criterion as suggested by Galvao (2009) with a maximum lag set to be 12. The number in parentheses is p value

474 M. Bahmani-Oskooee et al. Table 5 Empirical results of quantile estimation and unit root tests for each quantile (taking into account stationary covariates Stock Return) Galvao (2009) τ 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Bulgaria α1(τ) 0.9506 0.9619 0.9626 0.9584 0.9551 0.9735 0.9737 0.9952 1.0416 ˆδ 2 0.0416 0.0374 0.1161 0.0329 0.0980 0.1243 0.1269 0.3535 0.2921 Half-lives 13.681 17.844 18.185 16.313 15.088 25.808 26.007 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 4.1657 (0.006) [1, 1, 1] Czech Republic α1(τ) 0.9465 0.9763 0.9787 0.9815 0.9913 1.0048 1.0139 1.0233 1.0229 ˆδ 2 0.0689 0.0006 0.0350 0.0069 0.0227 0.0469 0.0253 0.1724 0.1966 Half-lives 12.606 17.844 32.194 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 3.4376 (0.009) [1, 1, 1] Hungary α1(τ) 0.9679 0.9711 0.9811 0.9941 0.9988 1.007 1.004 1.0159 1.0163 ˆδ 2 0.3464 0.0417 0.0009 0.0055 0.0009 0.0044 0.0241 0.0924 0.0620 Half-lives 23.553 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 2.1851 [1, 1, 1] Lithuania α1(τ) 0.9744 1.0139 0.9989 0.9981 0.9944 0.9876 0.9782 0.9718 0.9607 ˆδ 2 0.0173 0.0465 0.0243 0.0095 0.0243 0.0103 0.1275 0.0884 0.2551 Half-lives 26.727 31.447 32.194 17.288 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 2.0911 [1, 1, 1] Poland α1(τ) 0.9746 0.9713 0.9827 0.9719 0.9996 1.0033 1.0227 1.0302 1.0030 ˆδ 2 0.0934 0.1269 0.0005 0.0525 0.0176 0.0011 0.0265 0.1068 0.0528 Half-lives

Revisiting purchasing power parity in Eastern European 475 Table 5 continued τ 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 1.6817 [1, 1, 1] Romania α1(τ) 0.9591 0.9349 0.9777 0.9820 1.0035 1.0021 0.9953 0.9854 1.0116 ˆδ 2 0.0281 0.1089 0.1348 0.1201 0.0141 0.0455 0.2059 0.1455 0.0000 Half-lives 10.287 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 2.8618 (0.075) [1, 1, 3] Russia α1(τ) 0.9818 0.9856 0.9888 0.9912 0.9883 0.9898 0.9923 0.9908 0.9855 ˆδ 2 0.2338 0.1430 0.0693 0.0222 0.0914 0.2238 Half-lives 37.737 47.787 61.540 78.419 58.896 67.608 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 3.2667 (0.035) [8, 1, 5] and denotes significance at 5 and 1 % levels, respectively. Bold values represent the significant relation to the critical values. Numbers in parentheses denote bootstrap p values with the bootstrap replications set to be 10,000. For α1(τ), the unit root null is examined with the tn(τ) statistic. The lag lengths p and q in the bracket are selected based on robust Schwarz information criterion as suggested by Galvao (2009) with a maximum lag set to be 12. The number in parentheses is p value

476 M. Bahmani-Oskooee et al. Table 6 Empirical results of quantile estimation and unit root tests for each quantile (taking into account stationary covariates Inflation) Galvao (2009) τ 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Bulgaria α1(τ) 0.954 0.972 0.980 0.991 1.001 1.004 1.011 1.032 1.038 ˆδ 2 0.1198 0.0579 0.1071 0.0053 0.0393 0.0091 0.2027 0.0117 0.0428 Half-lives 14.719 24.407 34.309 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 3.0178 (0.046) [1, 1, 1] Czech Republic α1(τ) 0.9592 0.9565 0.9801 0.9852 0.9873 0.9951 1.006 1.0127 1.0189 ˆδ 2 0.009 0.0587 0.0444 0.0067 0.0144 0.0146 0.0398 0.2173 0.0087 Half-lives 16.639 15.585 34.483 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 3.0101 (0.049) [1, 1, 1] Hungary α1(τ) 0.9723 0.9884 0.9916 0.9941 0.9979 0.9969 1.0131 1.0035 1.0028 ˆδ 2 0.4529 0.1367 0.0160 0.0028 0.0830 0.0013 0.0032 0.1553 0.0097 Half-lives QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 1.1356 [1, 1, 1] Lithuania α1(τ) 1.0069 1.005 1.0146 1.0062 1.0003 0.9901 0.9802 0.9644 0.9472 ˆδ 2 0.0141 0.0001 0.0357 0.0231 0.0079 0.0000 0.1158 0.0395 0.2385 Half-lives 34.659 19.122 12.778 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 3.6988 (0.008) [1, 1, 2] Poland α1(τ) 0.9581 0.9945 0.9846 0.9751 0.9761 0.9914 1.0022 1.0155 1.0067 ˆδ 2 0.3591 0.0487 0.0282 0.2471 0.1639 0.0784 0.1919 0.0332 0.0148 Half-lives

Revisiting purchasing power parity in Eastern European 477 Table 6 continued τ 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 1.4606 [1, 1, 1] Romania α1(τ) 0.9476 0.9653 0.9789 0.9829 0.9895 0.9960 1.005 1.009 1.0069 ˆδ 2 0.4235 0.9574 0.3186 0.1973 0.1908 0.0843 0.2506 0.4127 0.1368 Half-lives 12.878 19.627 32.503 40.187 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 2.9253 (0.08) [1, 1, 2] Russia α1(τ) 0.9746 0.9793 0.9868 0.9916 0.9876 0.9818 0.9818 0.9802 0.9653 ˆδ 2 0.1245 0.2737 0.4356 0.0206 0.0020 0.0088 0.0535 0.0088 0.3335 Half-lives 12.878 33.138 52.163 82.170 55.552 37.737 37.737 34.669 19.626 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 2.9689 (0.047)[1, 12, 4] and denotes significance at 5 and 1 % levels, respectively. Bold values represent the significant relation to the critical values. Numbers in parentheses denote bootstrap p values with the bootstrap replications set to be 10,000. For α1(τ), the unit root null is examined with the tn(τ) statistic. The lag lengths p and q in the bracket are selected based on robust Schwarz information criterion as suggested by Galvao (2009) with a maximum lag set to be 12. The number in parentheses is p value

478 M. Bahmani-Oskooee et al. countries (i.e., Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Romania, and Russia). On the other hand, Table 6 reports our empirical results when we use inflation rates to serve as our stationary covariates, and we find that PPP holds in five of these seven transition countries (i.e., Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Lithuania, Romania, and Russia). Based on these findings, we can conclude that quantile unit root test with stationary covariates proposed by Galvao (2009) provides more evidence in support of the PPP. Perron (1989) has pointed out that failure to account for structural breaks in testing for unit root could result in misleading findings. We, therefore, extend quantile-based unit root test model by incorporating both sharp shifts and smooth breaks proposed by Bahmani-Oskooee et al. (2014) to enhance estimation accuracy. We model the mean reversion properties in the real exchange rates series with both sharp shifts and smooth breaks for estimation of a level equation following Bahmani-Oskooee et al. (2014) and specify its function as: m+1 re t = α + θ l DU l,t + l=1 n ( 2πkt γ 1,k sin T k=1 ) + n ( 2πkt γ 2,k cos T k=1 ) + ε t (9) In Eq. (9), re t follows the same definition as before, and t, T, and m are time trend, sample size, and the optimum number of breaks, respectively. The other regressors are defined as: { 1 if TBk 1 < t < TB DU k,t = k 0 otherwise (10) Note that DU is entered into the specification in order to capture sharp shifts. 5 Following Gallant (1981), in order to obtain a global approximation from the smooth transition, Bahmani-Oskooee et al. (2014) use the Fourier approximation and enter both n k=1 γ 1,k sin( 2πkt T ) and n k=1 γ 2,k cos( 2πkt T ) into the model. Here n and k present the number of frequencies that are contained in the approximation where n T 2. Estimation of Eq. (9) involves selecting values for m, n, and k. As noted by Becker et al. (2004), it is reasonable that we restrict n = 1 because if γ 1,k = γ 2,k = 0 can be rejected for one frequency, then the null hypothesis of time invariance is also rejected. Also Enders and Lee (2012) noted that imposing the restriction n = 1 is useful in order to save the degrees of freedom and avoid over-fitting problem. Hence, we re-specify Eq. (9) as follows: m+1 re t = α + θ l DU l,t + γ 1 sin l=1 ( 2πkt T ) + γ 2 cos ( 2πkt T ) + ε t (11) The approach is to remove the impact of possible structural breaks (sharp and smooth) from the real exchange rate once we approximate the break dates. To this end, we 5 Equation (9) is not only an extension of Enders and Holt (2012) but also a combination of Carrión-i- Silvestre et al. (2006)andBecker et al. (2006) tests.

Revisiting purchasing power parity in Eastern European 479 Table 7 Empirical results of quantile estimation and unit root tests for each quantile (taking into account both sharp and smooth breaks) τ 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Bulgaria α 1 (τ) 0.790 0.831 0.828 0.869 0.877 0.863 0.824 0.805 0.780 Half-lives 3.744 3.672 4.936 5.281 4.704 3.580 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 3.400 (0.032) Czech Republic α 1 (τ) 0.743 0.783 0.837 0.788 0.798 0.805 0.801 0.736 0.671 Half-lives 2.833 3.895 2.909 3.071 3.195 3.124 2.261 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 4.329 (0.023) Hungary α 1 (τ) 0.790 0.807 0.829 0.768 0.723 0.718 0.776 0.791 0.678 Half-lives 3.232 3.696 2.626 2.137 2.092 2.733 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 5.112 0.009 Lithuania α 1 (τ) 0.649 0.673 0.712 0.793 0.774 0.751 0.770 0.719 0.677 Half-lives 1.603 1.750 2.041 2.989 2.705 2.421 2.652 2.101 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 4.846 (0.019) Poland α 1 (τ) 0.712 0.723 0.781 0.797 0.759 0.765 0.691 0.718 0.674 Half-lives 2.137 2.804 3.054 2.514 2.588 1,875 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 3.949 (0.034) Romania α 1 (τ) 0.487 0.626 0.784 0.808 0.845 0.878 0.824 0.788 0.787 Half-lives 0.963 1.479 2.848 3.251 4.265 5.323 3.581 2.909 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 4.836 (0.002) Russia α 1 (τ) 0.928 0.947 0.955 0.933 0.977 0.979 1.002 0.981 0.936 Half-lives 12.728 9.955 QKS for quantiles of 10 90 %: 3.919 (0.017) denotes significance at 5 % level. Bold values represent the significant relation to the critical values. Numbers in parentheses denote bootstrap p values with the bootstrap replications set to be 10,000. The lag length p and q are selected based on robust Schwarz information criterion as suggested by Galvao (2009) with a maximum lag set to be 12. For α1(τ), the unit root null is examined with the tn (τ) statistic. The number in parentheses is p value follow the procedure adopted by Tsong and Lee (2011) and reconstruct a new time series of the real exchange rate by taking into account both sharp shifts and smooth breaks as: m+1 y t = re t ˆα l=1 ( 2πkt ˆθ l DU l,t ˆγ 1 sin T ) ˆγ 2 cos ( 2πkt T ) + ε t (12)

480 M. Bahmani-Oskooee et al. Table 8 Estimation results for the mean-reverting function in Eq. (11) Countries Optimum frequency F stat 90 % 95 % 97.50 % 99 % Panel A: The results for optimum frequency and the F statistic and its critical values Bulgarian 2 39.234 2.268 2,939 3.651 4.501 Czech Rep 1 473.321 2.285 3.056 3.712 4.587 Hungary 2 38.534 2.340 3.011 3.782 4.709 Lithuania 1 121.506 2.399 3.099 3.755 4.592 Poland 1 124.572 2.353 3.132 3.770 4.743 Romania 1 73.521 2.457 3.161 3.874 4.810 Russian 3 51.917 2.381 3.093 3.936 4.774 Countries Break dates Panel B: The results for sharp drift dates in Eq. (11) Bulgarian 2001.09 2005.01 2010.11 2011.11 Czech Rep 2001.02 2002.03 2009.04 Hungary 2001.02 2002.03 2003.12 2006.11 2007.09 2010.08 Lithuania 2001.06 2002.04 2004.02 2006.08 2010.10 2012.12 Poland 2001.11 2003.06 2007.09 Romania 1999.08 2000.04 2005.09 2006.02 2009.10 2011.12 Russian 1999.08 2002.03 2008.11 2009.09 2012.03 where y t is real exchange rate adjusted by the effects of possible structural breaks (for both sharp shifts and smooth breaks). 6 We then apply quantile unit root test proposed by Koenker and Xiao (2004) to test for unit root in our adjusted new series y t.we report these empirical results in Table 7. Table 7 also shows the point estimates, t statistics, critical values, half-life of a shock, and QKS for each country. We find that H 0 : α(τ) = 1 can be rejected at the 5 % significance level over the whole conditional real exchanger rate distribution based on Quantile Kolmogorov Smirnov test (QKS) for all seven countries (i.e., Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Lithuania, Hungary, Poland, Romania, and Russia). These results confirm that all types of shocks to real exchange rates lead to temporary effects which implies that PPP holds in these seven transition countries after we take into account both sharp shifts and smooth breaks. From Table 7, we also gather that the estimated half-life based on quantile autoregressive model is about 1 12 months (1 month to 1 year). Our empirical results highlight the importance of modeling both sharp shifts and smooth breaks into quantile-based unit root test model. Table 8 reports the estimation results for the mean-reverting function in Eq. (11) which further confirm our findings. Figure 1 displays the time paths of the real exchange rates where a positive change in the exchange rate indicates real depreciation. We can clearly observe structural 6 For details of how to estimate (11) and(12) refer to Bahmani-Oskooee et al. (2014), Bahmani-Oskoee et al. (2015).

Revisiting purchasing power parity in Eastern European 481.12.11.10.09.08.07.06.05.04 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 55 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 BULGARIA BULGARIAH CZECH CZECHH HUNGARY HUNGARYH 10 9 8 7 6 5 7.0 6.5 6.0 5.5 5.0 4.5 4.0 3.5 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 4 3.0 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 1 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 LITHUANIA LITHUANIAH POLAND POLANDH ROMANIAN ROMANIANH 55 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 RUSSIA RUSSIAH Fig. 1 Time series plot of real exchange rates and fitted nonlinear flexible intercept with sharp shifts and smooth breaks for each country shifts in the trend of the data. Accordingly, it appears sensible to allow for both sharp shifts and smooth breaks in testing for a unit root (and/or stationary). The estimated time paths of the time-varying intercepts are also shown in all figures. Because the actual nature of break(s) is generally unknown, there is no specific guide as to where and how many breaks to use in testing for a unit root or stationarity. Using an incorrect specification for the form and number of breaks can be as problematic as ignoring the breaks altogether. A further examination of the figures indicates that both dummy variables (sharp shifts) and Fourier approximations (smooth beaks) seem reasonable and support the notion of long swings in real exchange rates. Accordingly, it appears sensible to allow for both sharp drifts and smooth breaks in our approach. One major policy implication of our study is that the validity of using PPP to determine the equilibrium exchange is unambiguous for all of these seven transition countries. In these countries, the PPP could be used to determine whether a currency is over- or undervalued. Nevertheless, reaping unbounded gains from arbitrage in traded goods is not possible. Furthermore, the findings in support of the PPP imply that deviations in the short run from the PPP are not prolonged for most of the transition countries and there are some forces which are capable of bringing the exchange rate back to its PPP values in the long run. Our results have important policy implication on cross-border agreement for international trade and investment with these countries. Given the goods and services markets appear quite integrated, future liberalization will likely affect financial markets. If we envision this process of integration continuing, in particular in the transition

482 M. Bahmani-Oskooee et al. countries, and to the extent that this process requires even more political engagement, we believe the prospects for cooperation along a variety of dimensions are good. It is noteworthy that the results here are in contrast with those of Beko and Borsic (2007), Baharumshah and Borsic (2008), Acaravci and Ozturk (2010) and Liu et al. (2012) who provided weak (or no) support for PPP in various groups of transition countries using traditional unit root tests. 5 Conclusions This study applies quantile unit root test proposed by Koenker and Xiao (2004) and Galvao (2009) to revisit the purchasing power parity (PPP) in seven transition countries: Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Hungary, Lithuania, Poland, Romania, and Russia using monthly data over January 1998 to March 2015. While traditional unit root tests fail to support PPP, quantile unit root tests provide strong support for the PPP even after accounting for sharp shifts and smooth breaks in all seven countries. The estimated half-life based on quantile autoregressive model is about 12 25 months (1 2 year). The transition countries started their liberalization programs in the late 1980s and early 1990s. In some of these countries, this period was characterized by dramatic improvements in budget deficits, debts, and inflation. As these countries became increasingly open to trade (and inflation and growth rates converged to those of developed countries), we would expect to find more favorable evidence of the parity condition using data for recent years (Bahmani-Oskoee et al. 2015). In fact, many of these countries adopted trade policies that mimic those of the European Union (EU), with a view to alignment in readiness for membership. As the reform process (price liberalization and trade opening) intensified, we could expect a reduction in persistent shocks to international parity (Bahmani-Oskoee et al. 2015). Our empirical results seem to support these claims. References Acaravci A, Ozturk I (2010) Testing purchasing power parity in transition countries: evidence from structural breaks. Amfiteatru econ 12(27):190 198 Bahmani-Oskooee M, Kutan AM, Zhou Z (2008) Do real exchange rates follow a nonlinear mean reverting process in developing countries. South Econ J 74:1049 1069 Bahmani-Oskooee M, Hegerty S (2009) Purchasing power parity in less-developed and transition economies: a review article. J Econ Surv 23:617 658 Bahmani-Oskooee M, Chang T, Wu TP (2014) Revisiting purchasing power parity in African countries: panel stationary test with sharp and smooth breaks. Appl Financ Econ 24:1429 1438 Bahmani-Oskoee M, Chang T, Wu TP (2015) Purchasing power parity in transition countries: panel stationary test with smooth and sharp breaks. Int J Financ Stud 3:153 161 Baharumshah AZ, Borsic D (2008) Purchasing power parity in central and Eastern European countries. Econ Bull 6:1 8 Becker R, Enders W, Lee J (2004) A general test for time dependence in parameters. J Appl Econom 19:899 906 Becker R, Enders W, Lee J (2006) A stationairy test in the presence of an unknown number of smooth breaks. J Time Ser Anal 27:381 409 Beko J, Borsic D (2007) Purchasing power parity in transition economies: does it hold in the Czech Republic, Hungary and Slovenia? Post Commun Econ 19:417 432

Revisiting purchasing power parity in Eastern European 483 Carrión-i-Silvestre J, Del Barrio L, Sansó A (2006) A guide to the computation of stationarity tests. Empir Econ 31:48 433 Chang T, Chiu CC, Tzeng HW (2011) Revisiting purchasing power parity for nine transition countries using the rank test for nonlinear cointegration Romanian. J Econ Forecas 14:19 30 Chang T, Tzeng HW (2013) Purchasing power parity in nine transition countries: panel SURKSS test. Int J Finance Econ 18:74 81 Cuestas JC (2009) Purchasing power parity in Central and Eastern European countries: an analysis of unit roots and nonlinearities. Appl Econ Lett 16:87 94 Dornbusch R (1987) Purchasing power parity. In: Eatwell J, Milgate M, Nweman P (eds) The New Palgrave: a dictionary of economics. Macmillan Press, London, pp 1075 1085 Elliott G, Pesavento E (2006) On the failure of purchasing power parity for bilateral exchange rates after 1973. J Money Credit Bank 38:1405 1430 Enders W, Holt TM (2012) Sharp breaks or smooth shifts? an investigation of the evolution of primary commodity prices. Am J Agricult econ 94(3):659 673 Enders W, Lee J (2012) A unit root test using a Fourier series to approximate smooth breaks. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 74:574 599 Gallant AR (1981) On the bias in flexible functional forms and an essentially unbiased form: the Fourier flexible form. J Econ 15(2):211 245 Galvao AF Jr (2009) Unit root quantile autoregression testing using covariates. J Econom 152:165 178 He H, Chang T (2013) Purchasing power parity in transition countries: sequential panel selection method. Econ Model 35:604 609 He H, Chou M, Chang T (2014) Purchasing power parity for 15 Latin American countries: panel SURKSS test with a Fourier function. Econ Model 36:37 43 Hosseinkouchack M, Wolters MH (2013) Do large recession reduce output permanently? Econ Lett 121:516 519 Koenker R, Xiao Z (2004) Unit root quantile autoregression inference. J Am Stat Assoc 99(467):775 787 Lin SY, Chang T, Chang HJ (2011) Purchasing power parity for nine transition countries: Fourier stationary test. Post Commun Econ 23:210 221 Liu S, Zhang D, Chang TY (2012) Purchasing power parity-nonlinear threshold unit root test for transition countries. Appl Econ Lett 19:1781 1785 Liu S, Chang TY (2013) Purchasing power parity in Latin American countries: linear and nonlinear unit root tests with stationary covariates. Econ Comput Econ Cybern Stud Res 47:297 305 Lothian JR, Taylor MP (2000) Purchasing power parity over two centuries: strengthening the case for real exchange rate stability, reply to Cuddington and Liang. J Int Money Finance 19:759 764 MacDonald R, Taylor MP (1992) Exchange rate economics: a survey. IMF Staff Papers 39:1 57 Parikh A, Williams G (1998) Modelling real exchange rate behavior: a cross-country study. Appl Financ Econ 8:577 587 Peel DA, Venetis LA (2003) Purchasing power parity over two centuries: trends and nonlinearity. Appl Econ 35:609 617 Perron P (1989) The great crash, the oil price shock and the unit root hypothesis. Econometrica 57:1361 1401 Sarno L, Taylor MP (2002) Purchasing power parity and the real exchange rate. IMF Staff Papers 49:65 105 Sjolander P (2007) Unreal exchange rates: a simulation based approach to adjust misleading PPP estimates. J Econ Stud 34:256 288 Solakoglu EG (2006) Testing purchasing power parity hypothesis for transition economies. Appl Financ Econ 16:561 568 Su CW, Chang HL, Chang TY, Lee CH (2012) Purchasing power parity for BRICS countries: linear and nonlinear unit root tests with stationary covariates. Appl Econ Lett 19:1587 1591 Taylor MP (1995) The economics of exchange rates. J Econ Lit 33:13 47 Taylor MP (2006) Real exchange rates and purchasing power parity: mean-reversion in economic thought. Appl Financ Econ 16:1 17 Taylor AM, Taylor MP (2004) The purchasing power parity debate. J Econ Perspect 18:135 158 Telatar E, Hasanov M (2009) Purchasing power parity in transition economies: evidence from the commonwealth of independent states. Post Commun Econ 21:157 173 Tsong CC, Lee CF (2011) Asymmetric inflation dynamics evidence from quantile regression analysis. J Macroecon 33:668 680