Fiscal Multipliers with Time-inconsistent Preferences

Similar documents
DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations?

Lecture on State Dependent Government Spending Multipliers

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Macroeconomics Theory II

Equilibrium Conditions (symmetric across all differentiated goods)

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018

1 The social planner problem

Chapter 11 The Stochastic Growth Model and Aggregate Fluctuations

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

1 The Basic RBC Model

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Graduate Macro Theory II: Business Cycle Accounting and Wedges

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 Solutions

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Advanced Macroeconomics

Lecture 2 Real Business Cycle Models

Analysis of the Government Expenditure Multiplier under Zero Lower Bound: the Role of Public Investment 1

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

Nonlinearity. Exploring this idea and what to do about it requires solving a non linear model.

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Relative Deep Habits

Housing and the Business Cycle

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Foundation of (virtually) all DSGE models (e.g., RBC model) is Solow growth model

Advanced Macroeconomics

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

COMPANION APPENDIX TO Fiscal Consolidation with Tax Evasion and Corruption (not intended for publication)

Deep Habits: Technical Notes

Business Failure and Labour Market Fluctuations

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Monetary Policy with Heterogeneous Agents: Insights from Tank Models

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0

Shiftwork in the Real Business Cycle

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Chap. II: Fiscal Multipliers. L3 TSE: Macroeconomics 2014

Markov Perfect Equilibria in the Ramsey Model

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth

Optimal Monetary Policy with Informational Frictions

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8

Macroeconomics Field Exam. August 2007

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING

Seminar Lecture. Introduction to Structural Estimation: A Stochastic Life Cycle Model. James Zou. School of Economics (HUST) September 29, 2017

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Advanced Macroeconomics

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle

Interest Rate Liberalization and Capital Misallocation 1

Macroeconomics Theory II

What are we going to do?

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

The Real Business Cycle Model

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

Explaining the Effects of Government Spending Shocks on Consumption and the Real Exchange Rate. M. Ravn S. Schmitt-Grohé M. Uribe.

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Reconciling Jaimovich-Rebello Preferences, Habit in Consumption and Labor Supply

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 2: Dynamics in Aggregate Demand and Supply

Stochastic simulations with DYNARE. A practical guide.

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

Introduction to Macroeconomics

Econ 5110 Solutions to the Practice Questions for the Midterm Exam

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

The Smets-Wouters Model

Advanced Macroeconomics II The RBC model with Capital

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Foundations of the Sticky Wage Approach and a Critical Commentary

Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model.

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Transcription:

Fiscal Multipliers with Time-inconsistent Preferences Richard W. Evans Kerk L. Phillips Benjamin Tengelsen May 2012

Multiplier definitions and considerations dy t+s dg t and dy t+s dt t Short-term, medium-term, or long-term s Temporary or permanent shock How stimulus is financed (balanced budget or deficit) Where taxing comes from (capital or labor tax) Where is spending (household transfers, gov t consumption, gov t investment) How much slack (expansion or recession) Do constraints bind (ZLB, borrowing constraints)

Multiplier research: vast and varied Standard RBC models: -2.5 to 1.2 multipliers increase with: shock permanence deficit financing Most multipliers less than 1 Barro and King (1984), Aiyagari, Christiano, and Eichenbaum (1992), Baxter and King (1993) New Keynesian RE models: 0.5 to 1.0 Price frictions increase multipliers Demand determined employment increases multipliers Cogan, Cwik, Taylor, and Weiland (2010): 0.64 at peak Galí, Lopéz-Salido, and Vallés (2007): Up to 2.0 if: 50% of workers are rule-of-thumb employment demand determined

Multiplier research: vast and varied Standard RBC models: -2.5 to 1.2 multipliers increase with: shock permanence deficit financing Most multipliers less than 1 Barro and King (1984), Aiyagari, Christiano, and Eichenbaum (1992), Baxter and King (1993) New Keynesian RE models: 0.5 to 1.0 Price frictions increase multipliers Demand determined employment increases multipliers Cogan, Cwik, Taylor, and Weiland (2010): 0.64 at peak Galí, Lopéz-Salido, and Vallés (2007): Up to 2.0 if: 50% of workers are rule-of-thumb employment demand determined

Multiplier research: vast and varied Standard RBC models: -2.5 to 1.2 multipliers increase with: shock permanence deficit financing Most multipliers less than 1 Barro and King (1984), Aiyagari, Christiano, and Eichenbaum (1992), Baxter and King (1993) New Keynesian RE models: 0.5 to 1.0 Price frictions increase multipliers Demand determined employment increases multipliers Cogan, Cwik, Taylor, and Weiland (2010): 0.64 at peak Galí, Lopéz-Salido, and Vallés (2007): Up to 2.0 if: 50% of workers are rule-of-thumb employment demand determined

Multiplier research: vast and varied Standard RBC models: -2.5 to 1.2 multipliers increase with: shock permanence deficit financing Most multipliers less than 1 Barro and King (1984), Aiyagari, Christiano, and Eichenbaum (1992), Baxter and King (1993) New Keynesian RE models: 0.5 to 1.0 Price frictions increase multipliers Demand determined employment increases multipliers Cogan, Cwik, Taylor, and Weiland (2010): 0.64 at peak Galí, Lopéz-Salido, and Vallés (2007): Up to 2.0 if: 50% of workers are rule-of-thumb employment demand determined

Multiplier research: vast and varied New Keynesian RE models with constraints: 1.0+ Zero lower bound: as high as 2.3 Egertsson(2001,2012), Woodford (2003,2011), Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (2011) Borrowing constraints: Parker (2011) argues for including these Keynesian non-re models: 1.5 to 2+ Fixed expectations (irrationality) increases multiplier Evans (1969): 2+ Romer and Bernstein (2009): 1.5

Multiplier research: vast and varied New Keynesian RE models with constraints: 1.0+ Zero lower bound: as high as 2.3 Egertsson(2001,2012), Woodford (2003,2011), Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (2011) Borrowing constraints: Parker (2011) argues for including these Keynesian non-re models: 1.5 to 2+ Fixed expectations (irrationality) increases multiplier Evans (1969): 2+ Romer and Bernstein (2009): 1.5

Multiplier research: vast and varied Regression, VAR, SVAR: -0.5 to 2+ Many of these are above unity (0.6 to 1.5) Barro (1981), Hall (1986,2009) Ramey and Shapiro (1998), Fisher and Peters (2010), Ramey (2011), Barro and Redlick (2011), Blanchard and Perotti (2002) Notable exceptions (-0.5 to 0.0) are Taylor (2009,2011), Pereira and Lopes (2010), Kirchner, Cimadomo, and Hauptmeir (2010) Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012): expansion -0.3 to 0.8; recession 1.0 to 3.6

Our question: rationality We focus on the effect of time-inconsistent preferences on multipliers (a la Galí, Lopéz-Salido, and Vallés, 2007) 1 Estimate discount factor in standard model stochastic capital tax balanced budget spending 2 Estimate discount factors in quasi-hyperbolic model 3 Compare multipliers in each Results We estimate quasi-hyperbolic parameters similar to micro-studies Multipliers bigger with quasi-hyperbolic households Estimation tempers how much bigger the multipliers can be

Our question: rationality We focus on the effect of time-inconsistent preferences on multipliers (a la Galí, Lopéz-Salido, and Vallés, 2007) 1 Estimate discount factor in standard model stochastic capital tax balanced budget spending 2 Estimate discount factors in quasi-hyperbolic model 3 Compare multipliers in each Results We estimate quasi-hyperbolic parameters similar to micro-studies Multipliers bigger with quasi-hyperbolic households Estimation tempers how much bigger the multipliers can be

Hyperbolic discounting Standard exponential discounting [ ] E 0 ξ t u(c t, h t ) where ξ t = δ t t t=0 Quasi-hyperbolic discounting { 1 if t = 0 ξ t = βδ t 1 if t 1 with β < δ Discount factors are {1, β, βδ, βδ 2, βδ 3,...} Implies two Euler equations, rather than one recursive

Hyperbolic discounting Standard exponential discounting [ ] E 0 ξ t u(c t, h t ) where ξ t = δ t t t=0 Quasi-hyperbolic discounting { 1 if t = 0 ξ t = βδ t 1 if t 1 with β < δ Discount factors are {1, β, βδ, βδ 2, βδ 3,...} Implies two Euler equations, rather than one recursive

Hyperbolic discounting Standard exponential discounting [ ] E 0 ξ t u(c t, h t ) where ξ t = δ t t t=0 Quasi-hyperbolic discounting { 1 if t = 0 ξ t = βδ t 1 if t 1 with β < δ Discount factors are {1, β, βδ, βδ 2, βδ 3,...} Implies two Euler equations, rather than one recursive

Hyperbolic discounting micro estimates Standard exponential discount factors: δ = 0.96 Life cycle consumption and wealth data Engen, Gale, and Scholz (1994), Hubbard, Skinner, and Zeldes (1994), Laibson, Repetto, and Tobacman (1998), Engen, Gale, Uccello (1999) Quasi-hyperbolic estimates Shui and Ausubel (2005): β = 0.81 0.83 and δ = 0.999 Passerman (2008): β = 0.52 0.90 and δ = 0.99 Fang and Silverman (2009): β = 0.48 and δ = 0.88 Laibson, Repetto, and Tobacman: β = 0.70 and δ = 0.95 Percent population hyperbolic discounters Eisenhauer and Ventura (2006) Italian and Dutch survey data Less than 25% hyperbolic

Hyperbolic discounting micro estimates Standard exponential discount factors: δ = 0.96 Life cycle consumption and wealth data Engen, Gale, and Scholz (1994), Hubbard, Skinner, and Zeldes (1994), Laibson, Repetto, and Tobacman (1998), Engen, Gale, Uccello (1999) Quasi-hyperbolic estimates Shui and Ausubel (2005): β = 0.81 0.83 and δ = 0.999 Passerman (2008): β = 0.52 0.90 and δ = 0.99 Fang and Silverman (2009): β = 0.48 and δ = 0.88 Laibson, Repetto, and Tobacman: β = 0.70 and δ = 0.95 Percent population hyperbolic discounters Eisenhauer and Ventura (2006) Italian and Dutch survey data Less than 25% hyperbolic

Hyperbolic discounting micro estimates Standard exponential discount factors: δ = 0.96 Life cycle consumption and wealth data Engen, Gale, and Scholz (1994), Hubbard, Skinner, and Zeldes (1994), Laibson, Repetto, and Tobacman (1998), Engen, Gale, Uccello (1999) Quasi-hyperbolic estimates Shui and Ausubel (2005): β = 0.81 0.83 and δ = 0.999 Passerman (2008): β = 0.52 0.90 and δ = 0.99 Fang and Silverman (2009): β = 0.48 and δ = 0.88 Laibson, Repetto, and Tobacman: β = 0.70 and δ = 0.95 Percent population hyperbolic discounters Eisenhauer and Ventura (2006) Italian and Dutch survey data Less than 25% hyperbolic

Model Standard representative agent RBC model Quasi-hyperbolic discounting Flexible prices Perfectly competitive firms Aggregate uninsurable shocks Distortionary stochastic capital tax Balanced budget constraint with public goods

Model: Households and firms Households [ ] max E 0 ξ tu (c t, h t, G t) c t,h t s.t. where t=0 c t + k t+1 = w th t + (1 + r t τ t κ)k t + X t u (c t, h t, G t) = c1 σc t 1 + A (1 ht)1 σh 1 + χ G1 σg t 1 1 σ c 1 σ h 1 σ g Firms Y t = e z t Kt θ L 1 θ t where U }{{} t 1 2 = [1 U t 1 ] }{{} 1 3 U t = [z t τ t], and ε t N (0, Σ) r t = θe z t ( ) 1 θ Lt K t w t = (1 θ)e z t ( ) θ Kt L t }{{} Γ 3 2, }{{} 1 2 + ε t

Model: Households and firms Households [ ] max E 0 ξ tu (c t, h t, G t) c t,h t s.t. where t=0 c t + k t+1 = w th t + (1 + r t τ t κ)k t + X t u (c t, h t, G t) = c1 σc t 1 + A (1 ht)1 σh 1 + χ G1 σg t 1 1 σ c 1 σ h 1 σ g Firms Y t = e z t Kt θ L 1 θ t where U }{{} t 1 2 = [1 U t 1 ] }{{} 1 3 U t = [z t τ t], and ε t N (0, Σ) r t = θe z t ( ) 1 θ Lt K t w t = (1 θ)e z t ( ) θ Kt L t }{{} Γ 3 2, }{{} 1 2 + ε t

Model: Households and firms Households [ ] max E 0 ξ tu (c t, h t, G t) c t,h t s.t. where t=0 c t + k t+1 = w th t + (1 + r t τ t κ)k t + X t u (c t, h t, G t) = c1 σc t 1 + A (1 ht)1 σh 1 + χ G1 σg t 1 1 σ c 1 σ h 1 σ g Firms Y t = e z t Kt θ L 1 θ t where U }{{} t 1 2 = [1 U t 1 ] }{{} 1 3 U t = [z t τ t], and ε t N (0, Σ) r t = θe z t ( ) 1 θ Lt K t w t = (1 θ)e z t ( ) θ Kt L t }{{} Γ 3 2, }{{} 1 2 + ε t

Model: Households and firms Households [ ] max E 0 ξ tu (c t, h t, G t) c t,h t s.t. where t=0 c t + k t+1 = w th t + (1 + r t τ t κ)k t + X t u (c t, h t, G t) = c1 σc t 1 + A (1 ht)1 σh 1 + χ G1 σg t 1 1 σ c 1 σ h 1 σ g Firms Y t = e z t Kt θ L 1 θ t where U }{{} t 1 2 = [1 U t 1 ] }{{} 1 3 U t = [z t τ t], and ε t N (0, Σ) r t = θe z t ( ) 1 θ Lt K t w t = (1 θ)e z t ( ) θ Kt L t }{{} Γ 3 2, }{{} 1 2 + ε t

Model: Market clearing and government Market clearing K t = k t L t = h t Government balanced budget constraint τ t k }{{} t = γg t + (1 γ)x }{{} t revenues expenditures

Equilibrium definition Recursive rational expectations equilibrium Policy functions c(k, z, τ), k (k, z, τ), and h(k, z, τ) and price functions r(k, z, τ) and w(k, z, τ) such that: households maximize lifetime expected utility firms maximize profits markets clear government budget constraint holds

Equilibrium: standard exponential households u c (c t, h t ) = δe t [(1 + r t+1 τ t+1 κ)u c (c t+1, h t+1 )] w t u c (c t, h t ) = u h (c t, h t ) r t = θe z t ( ) 1 θ Lt w t = (1 θ)e z t K t = k t L t = h t K t ( ) θ Kt L t τ t k t = γg t + (1 γ)x t

Equilibrium: quasi-hyperbolic households u c (c t, h t ) = βe t [(1 + r t+1 τ t+1 κ)u c (c t+1, h t+1 )] E t [u c (c t+1, h t+1 )] = δe t [(1 + r t+2 τ t+2 κ)u c (c t+2, h t+2 )] w t u c (c t, h t ) = u h (c t, h t ) r t = θe z t ( ) 1 θ Lt w t = (1 θ)e z t K t = k t L t = h t K t ( ) θ Kt L t τ t k t = γg t + (1 γ)x t

simulate N times Intro Model Estimation IRFs and Multipliers Conclusion compute simulated moments M o M Calibrated parameters choose new ι Table 1: Calibration of parameters Parameter Source to match Value σ c,σ h,σ g log utility 1 A shape parameter on leisure 1 h t in utility function, set to 1.72 match steady-state hours worked h = 0.3. a χ shape parameter on public goods spending G t in utility function 1 θ capital share of income 0.36 κ annual depreciation rate 0.06 γ percent of government revenues spent on public goods G t, set to 0.7 match avg. household transfers percent of revenues. b a This approach to calibrating A follows Hansen (1984). b Total tax revenue data (SCTAX+W055RC1+AFLPITAX) and household transfers (PCTR) come from St. Louis Fed FRED, 1947-2011. exponential and quasi- Table 2: Method of simulated moments estimation: hyperbolic models

Other government expenditures: γ 90.0% gamma 80.0% government spending as a percentage of tax receipts 70.0% 60.0% 50.0% 40.0% 30.0% 20.0% 10.0% 0.0% 1950 1952 1954 1956 1958 1960 1962 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

Calibration: VAR estimation [z t, τ t ] τ t, use real federal corporate tax revenues as percent of total revenues z t, use Solow residual approach from production function z t = log(y t ) θ log(k t ) (1 θ) log(l t ) Y t, real GDP 1951-2011 K t, capital stock series from BEA L t, nonfarm employment times average annual hours VAR: Ũ t = Ũ t 1ˆΓ + ε t, ε t N(0, ˆΣ), Ũ t = [ z t, τ t ] [ ] [ ] 0.1298 0.2551 0.000057 0.000007 ˆΓ = and ˆΣ = 0.0571 0.9030 0.000007 0.000062

Calibration: VAR estimation [z t, τ t ] τ t, use real federal corporate tax revenues as percent of total revenues z t, use Solow residual approach from production function z t = log(y t ) θ log(k t ) (1 θ) log(l t ) Y t, real GDP 1951-2011 K t, capital stock series from BEA L t, nonfarm employment times average annual hours VAR: Ũ t = Ũ t 1ˆΓ + ε t, ε t N(0, ˆΣ), Ũ t = [ z t, τ t ] [ ] [ ] 0.1298 0.2551 0.000057 0.000007 ˆΓ = and ˆΣ = 0.0571 0.9030 0.000007 0.000062

Calibration: VAR estimation [z t, τ t ] τ t, use real federal corporate tax revenues as percent of total revenues z t, use Solow residual approach from production function z t = log(y t ) θ log(k t ) (1 θ) log(l t ) Y t, real GDP 1951-2011 K t, capital stock series from BEA L t, nonfarm employment times average annual hours VAR: Ũ t = Ũ t 1ˆΓ + ε t, ε t N(0, ˆΣ), Ũ t = [ z t, τ t ] [ ] [ ] 0.1298 0.2551 0.000057 0.000007 ˆΓ = and ˆΣ = 0.0571 0.9030 0.000007 0.000062

Tax rates: R t /Y t 35.0% taxes / GDP 30.0% 25.0% 20.0% 15.0% 10.0% 5.0% 0.0% 1950 1952 1954 1956 1958 1960 1962 1964 1966 1968 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

MSM Estimation Data moments (1951-2011, annual) mean(i/y ), mean(k /Y ), mean(c/y ), mean(mpk ) standard deviation(i/y ) corr(c t+1, C t ), corr(c t, h t ), PCE, detrended Estimate standard exponential model β = δ and z Estimate quasi-hyperbolic model β, δ, and z Choose parameters to minimize error between model moments and data moments 2,000 simulations per iteration of 61 periods each Log-linear solution technique for policy functions

MSM Estimation exponential and quasi- ble 2: Method of simulated moments estimation: hyperbolic models Exponential Quasi-hyperbolic Moments Data a Model Model moment std. err. b moment std. err. b mean(i/y ) 0.129 0.125 (0.003) 0.132 (0.004) mean(c/y ) 0.653 0.507 (0.002) 0.478 (0.002) mean(k/y ) 2.204 2.090 (0.038) 2.209 (0.043) mean(mp K) 0.164 0.172 (0.003) 0.163 (0.003) st.dev.(i/y ) 0.021 0.030 (0.004) 0.033 (0.004) corr(c t, C t+1 ) 0.269 0.624 (0.118) 0.589 (0.127) corr(c t, h t ) 0.108-0.843 (0.031) -0.856 (0.037) Estimated parameters β 0.774 (?) δ 0.921 (0.160) 0.948 (?) z 1.170 (0.469) 1.388 (?) a Data sample is 1948 to 2011 annual data. b MSM standard errors are derived from 50,000 simulations.

IRFs and Multipliers We set z t = z for all t and set τ t = τ for all t except for impulse τ 1 = τ σ 1/2 τ,τ Multiplier definition: Y t+s τ t k t for s 0 Look at both short-run and medium-run multipliers

Output multipliers 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 exponen3al 0.3 hyperbolic 0.2 0.1 0-1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38

Results We estimate quasi-hyperbolic discount factors in DSGE model with values close to Laibson, et al (2012) Degree of irrationality probably not large Increase in multipliers minimal

Further work Use better tax series Add two types and estimate percent quasi-hyperbolic Add price or wage frictions Deficit financing Try nonlinear solution methods: DYNARE VFI probably not feasible