Games on Social Networks: On a Problem Posed by Goyal

Similar documents
Volume 31, Issue 3. Games on Social Networks: On a Problem Posed by Goyal

INFORMATION AS PUBLIC GOOD IN NETWORKS

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Supermodular Games

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 11: Introduction to Game Theory 3

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 10: Introduction to Game Theory 2

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 8: Supermodular and Potential Games

Application of Fixed point Theorem in Game Theory

Existence of Nash Networks in One-Way Flow Models

Chapter 9. Mixed Extensions. 9.1 Mixed strategies

1 Lattices and Tarski s Theorem

Bayesian Learning in Social Networks

Supermodular Network Games

Entropic Selection of Nash Equilibrium

Constructive Proof of the Fan-Glicksberg Fixed Point Theorem for Sequentially Locally Non-constant Multi-functions in a Locally Convex Space

Rate of Convergence of Learning in Social Networks

Preliminary Results on Social Learning with Partial Observations

Collaborative Network Formation in Spatial Oligopolies

Sion s minimax theorem and Nash equilibrium of symmetric multi-person zero-sum game

Positive Models of Private Provision of Public Goods: A Static Model. (Bergstrom, Blume and Varian 1986)

On the relation between Sion s minimax theorem and existence of Nash equilibrium in asymmetric multi-players zero-sum game with only one alien

Economics of Networks III

Informed Principal in Private-Value Environments

Multimarket Oligopolies with Restricted Market Access

Strategic Properties of Heterogeneous Serial Cost Sharing

Local public good provision in networks: A Nash implementation mechanism

Extensive Form Games I

Tijmen Daniëls Universiteit van Amsterdam. Abstract

Network Topology, Higher Orders of Stability and Efficiency

Economics 703 Advanced Microeconomics. Professor Peter Cramton Fall 2017

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. Modeling Resource Flow Asymmetries using Condensation Networks

NASH IMPLEMENTATION USING SIMPLE MECHANISMS WITHOUT UNDESIRABLE MIXED-STRATEGY EQUILIBRIA

On the existence of Pairwise stable weighted networks

Mixed Nash Equilibria

Strategic complementarities, network games and endogenous network formation

Mechanism Design: Implementation. Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham

NEW MAXIMUM THEOREMS WITH STRICT QUASI-CONCAVITY. Won Kyu Kim and Ju Han Yoon. 1. Introduction

CORE AND NO-TREAT EQUILIBRIUM IN TOURNAMENT GAMES WITH EXTERNALITIES

Local-Effect Games. Kevin Leyton-Brown. Moshe Tennenholtz. Stanford UBC. Technion

Dynamic Games with Asymmetric Information: Common Information Based Perfect Bayesian Equilibria and Sequential Decomposition

1. Introduction. 2. A Simple Model

Selecting Efficient Correlated Equilibria Through Distributed Learning. Jason R. Marden

NOTES ON COOPERATIVE GAME THEORY AND THE CORE. 1. Introduction

Epsilon Ex Post Implementation

Random Extensive Form Games and its Application to Bargaining

7.1: Games on Networks

AVERAGE TREE SOLUTION AND SUBCORE FOR ACYCLIC GRAPH GAMES

Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences. Sums of sets, etc.

Competition relative to Incentive Functions in Common Agency

On the existence of pairwise stable weighted networks

Mathematical Economics - PhD in Economics

SF2972 Game Theory Exam with Solutions March 15, 2013

On the Existence of Price Equilibrium in Economies with Excess Demand Functions

CS364A: Algorithmic Game Theory Lecture #13: Potential Games; A Hierarchy of Equilibria

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 7: PPAD and Fixed-Point Theorems

Mechanism design and allocation algorithms for energy-network markets with piece-wise linear costs and quadratic externalities

Columbia University. Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 23 Sep 2016

CS 781 Lecture 9 March 10, 2011 Topics: Local Search and Optimization Metropolis Algorithm Greedy Optimization Hopfield Networks Max Cut Problem Nash

Belief-free Equilibria in Repeated Games

A hierarchical network formation model

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. Existence of Nash Networks in One-Way Flow Models. Pascal Billand CREUSET, Jean Monnet University

Payoff Continuity in Incomplete Information Games

Existence of Nash Networks in One-Way Flow Models

An Introduction to Social and Economic Networks. Lecture 4, Part II

Inducing Peer Pressure to Promote Cooperation (Supporting Information)

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016

SONDERFORSCHUNGSBEREICH 504

On the Interaction between Heterogeneity and Decay in Two-way Flow Models*

Pure Strategy Equilibria in Symmetric Two-Player Zero-Sum Games

Tilburg University. Social Network Formation with Consent Gilles, R.P.; Sarangi, S. Publication date: Link to publication

13 Social choice B = 2 X X. is the collection of all binary relations on X. R = { X X : is complete and transitive}

Part II: Integral Splittable Congestion Games. Existence and Computation of Equilibria Integral Polymatroids

Convex Sets Strict Separation. in the Minimax Theorem

Inequality and Network Structure

5.2 A characterization of the nonemptiness of the core

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP A new look at the classical Bertrand duopoly

Utilitarian Preferences and Potential Games

An Infinitely Farsighted Stable Set

Crowdsourcing contests

Realization Plans for Extensive Form Games without Perfect Recall

Notes on Blackwell s Comparison of Experiments Tilman Börgers, June 29, 2009

Combinatorial Agency of Threshold Functions

Hannu Salonen Utilitarian Preferences and Potential Games. Aboa Centre for Economics

1 The General Definition

THE CANTOR GAME: WINNING STRATEGIES AND DETERMINACY. by arxiv: v1 [math.ca] 29 Jan 2017 MAGNUS D. LADUE

The Core of a Strategic Game *

Existence of Equilibria in Games with Arbitrary Strategy Spaces and Preferences: A Full Characterization

Social and economic network formation: a dynamic model

Thomas Demuynck, P. Jean-Jacques Herings, Riccardo D. Saulle, Christian Seel. The Myopic Stable Set for Social Environments RM/17/002

arxiv: v2 [cs.gt] 1 Dec 2018

A Generic Approach to Coalition Formation

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 1 Apr 2013

On the Nash Stability in the Hedonic Coalition Formation Games

Network Games with Friends and Foes

Introduction to Game Theory

Structural holes in social networks

Blackwell s Informativeness Theorem Using Diagrams

Applied Mathematics Letters

arxiv: v1 [cs.gt] 10 Apr 2018

Transcription:

Games on Social Networks: On a Problem Posed by Goyal Ali Kakhbod Demosthenis Teneketzis November 13, 2017 arxiv:1001.3896v4 [cs.gt] 9 Feb 2012 Abstract Within the context of games on networks S. Goyal (Goyal (2007), pg. 39) posed the following problem. Under any arbitrary but fixed topology, does there exist at least one pure Nash equilibrium that exhibits a positive relation between the cardinality of a player s set of neighbors and its utility payoff? In this paper we present a class of topologies in which pure Nash equilibria with the above property do not exist. 1 Introduction-Motivation Games on social networks is a rapidly developing discipline the importance of which has been extensively discussed in recent publications Goyal (2007), Jackson (2008) and Vega-Redondo (2007). One of the goals of this discipline is the development of a framework within which the effect of the structure of relationships on individual behavior and well-being as well as on aggregate outcomes can be examined systematically. The social sharing of information (Bramoulle and Kranton (2007)) which is privately costly to collect is one of the economic contexts within which the effect of network structure on individual behavior and aggregate outcomes are currently being studied. Within this context Goyal posed a question that addresses the effect of ones s neighbors on his/her payoff at equilibrium. In this paper we provide an answer to Goyal s problem. The paper is organized as follows: In section 2 we present the social network model and Goyal s problem. In section 3 we present preliminary results that are essential in determining a solution to Goyal s problem. In section 4 we present an example that provides a negative answer to Goyal s problem. We conclude in section 5. University of Michigan, Ann Arbor. Email: akakhbod@umich.edu University of Michigan, Ann Arbor. Email: teneket@umich.edu 1

2 The Model and Goyal s Problem We consider a set N := {1, 2, 3, N} of players. These players are connected, directly or indirectly, with one another through a network whose topology is denoted by g; g is fixed. Since g is fixed the set N i (g), i N, of neighbors of player i is well-defined; two players i, j are called neighbors if they are directly connected with a link in the graph that corresponds to the topology g. Each player can choose a strategy/effort s i S, where S is compact and convex in R. Let s S N, s := (s 1, s 2,, s N ) denote a strategy profile. Given s S, the payoff of player i, i N, is given Π i (s g) = f s i cs i, (1) s j N i (g) where c is the marginal cost of effort and it is a fixed positive constant. The function f is such that f(0) = 0, f ( ) > 0, f ( ) < 0, and there is a constant δ such that f (δ) = c. The function f and the constants c and δ are common knowledge among the players. Consider a game played by the N players, with strategy space and utility functions described above. Assume for the moment that there exist Nash equilibria in pure strategies, called pure Nash equilibria (PNE), for this game. Denote by PNE g the set of PNE of the game when the network topology is g. Denote by PNE g the subset of PNE g that have the following property: PNE g = { } s PNE g : i, j N, N i (g) > N j (g) Π i (s g) Π j (s g), (2) where N i (g) denotes the cardinality of the set N i (g). PNE g is called the set of PNE g that exhibit for every player i N a positive relation between the cardinality of N i (g) and the player s utility/payoff under g. Let G denote the set of the all possible topologies of the N players network. Goyal (2007), pg. 39, posed the following problem: s j Goyal s Problem: Under any arbitrary but fixed topology g G is the set PNE g nonempty? One would expect a positive answer to the above question. In the model under consideration the players payoff functions are identical. Thus, it is reasonable to expect that players with a higher number of neighbors would earn a higher payoff at equilibrium. In this paper we provide a negative (thus, in our opinion counterintuitive) answer to Goyal s problem. We present, via an example, a class of topologies for which PNE g is empty. 2

3 Preliminaries First we assert that for every topology g G the corresponding game possesses PNE. This assertion follows from the compactness of the space S, continuity of f( ) in the players strategies, the concavity of f( ) in each player s strategy, and a result of Debreu, Glicksberg and Fan (Fudenberg and Tirole (1991) pg. 34). For any g G all PNE g can be characterized by the following result. Theorem 1 (Goyal (2007), pg. 35) For a given g G, a strategy profile s = (s 1, s 2,, s N) PNE g, if and only if for every i N s i = { δ j N i (g) s j, if j N i (g) s j < δ, 0 if j N i (g) s j δ. The following lemma reveals a property of PNE g. This property along with the result of Theorem 1 are critical in establishing our answer to Goyal s problem. Lemma 2 Let s := (s 1, s 2,, s N) PNE g. Then for any u, v N, if N u (g) < N v (g) and s u = 0, then s v = 0. Proof: We prove the result by contradiction. Consider s PNE g. Let u, v N, assume that N u (g) < N v (g), s u = 0, and suppose s v = ε > 0. Then, since s PNE g, by Theorem 1 we must have j N u(g) (3) s j δ. (4) Furthermore, since ε > 0, f is increasing, and j N u(g) s j δ, it follows that Π v (s g) = f(δ) cε < f j N u(g) s j = Π u (s g), (5) which contradicts the fact that s PNE g. Consequently, we must have s v = 0. (6) Remark 3 Using the arguments in the proof of Lemma 2 we can also establish the following results: Independently of an agent s degree, if s PNE g and s i < s j then Π i (s g) > Π j (s g). Equivalently, if at equilibrium agent i is no better off than agent j then agent i contributes no more than agent j. 3

Let s PNE g be such that k N i (g) s k s i = µ for all i N. Then, s i s j Π i (s g) Π j (s g). Using the results on the existence of PNE, Theorem 1 and Lemma 2, we present an example that provides a negative answer to Goyal s problem. 4 An Example Consider the network depicted in Figure 4, and denote it by g. Assume there exists s PNE g. Restrict attention to node v 2. We show that no matter what value s v 2 takes, s can not be in PNE g, thus PNE g is empty. We consider six cases that exhaust all possibilities. Case 1: s v 2 = 0. Then s v 2 = 0 along with Lemma 2 imply that therefore, = s v 4 = s v 5 = 0, (7) s v 2 s v 4 = 0 (8) Since by assumption s PNE g, s PNE g. Therefore, s must satisfy the condition of Theorem 1. This further implies that s v j = s v 2 s v 4 δ. (9) v j N v3 (g) But (9) contradicts (7), thus we can not have any s PNE g with s v 2 = 0. Case 2: 0 < s v 2 < δ and := s v 4 = 0. Consider node v 6. Since N v6 (g) = 5 > 4 = N v5 (g) and s v 5 = 0, Lemma 2 implies that By the same argument, s v 6 = 0 implies that s v 6 = 0. (10) s v 16 = s v 17 = s v 18 = s v 19 = 0, (11) On the other hand, by Theorem 1 we must have s v 6 s v j δ (12) v j N v6 (g) 4

Equation (12) contradicts Eq. (11). Case 3: 0 < s v 2 < δ, 0 < := s v 4 < δ and 0 < s v 2 < δ. Since s PNE g, by Theorem 1 we must have Furthermore, by assumption s v 4 s v 2 = s v 2 δ. (13) s v 2 < δ. (14) Then Eqs. (13), (14) and Theorem 1 imply that = δ ( s v 2 ), or, equivalently, s v 2 = δ < δ, (15) because > 0. On other other hand, Theorem 1 applied to node v 2 gives Equations (15) and (16) contradict one another. s v 2 δ. (16) Case 4: 0 < s v 2 < δ, 0 < := s v 4 < δ and s v 2 δ. In this case, Theorem 1 applied to node v 3 gives s v j δ (17) v j N v3 (g) Inequality (17) combined with the assumption s v 2 δ result in Equation (18) and Lemma 2 in turn imply that = 0. (18) s v 5 = s v 6 = s v 7 = s v 8 = 0. (19) On the other hand, by Theorem 1 we must have s v 5 s vj δ. (20) which contradicts (19). v j N v5 (g) Case 5: 0 < s v 2 < δ, := s v 4 δ. 5

The result of Theorem 1 for node v 3 along with the above conditions imply Then, by Eq. (21) and Lemma 2 we must have which contradicts the assumption = 0. (21) s v 4 = s v 5 = 0, (22) s v 4 δ. (23) Case 6: s v 2 δ. Then, the result of Theorem 1 for node v 2 and s v 2 δ imply Equation (24) and lemma 2 result in which along with Lemma 2 imply that = 0. (24) s v 5 = 0, (25) s v 6 = s v 7 = s v 8 = 0. (26) On the other hand, the result of Theorem 1 for node v 5 requires that s v 5 s vj δ (27) which contradicts (26). v j N v5 (g) The analysis of cases 1-6 demonstrates that no matter what value s v 2 takes, s / PNE g. Consequently, the set PNE g is empty. 5 Conclusion/Discussion Note that the example presented here is not necessarily minimal, but it introduces a class of topologies (games) with finite tree structure such that (i) the degree of nodes (except the terminal/leaf nodes) increases monotonically as their distance from the root of the tree increases. (ii) the depth of the tree is at least 5. 6

v 94 v 93 v 92 v 91 v 90 v 79 v 78 v 77 v 76 v 75 v 22 v 89 v 88 v 87 v 86 v 85 v 84 v 83 v 82 v 81 v 80 v 20 v 74 v 95 v 19 v 73 v 96 v 21 v 21 v 72 v 97 v 98 v 99 v 100 v 101 v 23 v 69 v 71 v 68 v 70 v 67 v 102 v 24 v 7 v 18 v 66 v 103 v 6 v 65 v 104 v 64 v 105 v 8 v 17 v 63 v 106 v 62 v 107 v 25 v 61 v 59 v 110 v 108 v 60 v 58 v 111 v 109 v 57 v 112 v 26 v 5 v 16 v 56 v 113 v 114 v 3 v 55 v 2 v 54 v 115 v 4 := v 4 v 5 v 15 v 53 v 116 v 52 v 117 v 118 v 119 v 120 v 121 v 27 v 49 v 51 v 48 v 50 v 47 v 122 v 28 v 14 v 46 v 123 v 45 v 124 v 44 v 125 v 9 v 10 v 11 v 43 v 126 v 42 v 127 v 29 v 13 v 41 v 39 v 130 v 128 v 40 v 38 v 131 v 129 v 37 v 132 v 30 v 32 v 33 v 12 v 36 v 133 v 134 v 31 v 140v 141v 142v 143v 144v 145v 146v 147v 148v 149 v 34 v 35 v 135v 136v 137 v 138 v 139 v 150v 151v 152v 153v 154 Figure 1: g: An example For any game on a network with topology g that belongs to the above described class, the set PNE g is empty. This can be proved by exactly the same arguments (Cases 1-6) as those presented in the tree structure of Section 4. Furthermore, consider any topology/game that results in from arbitrary extensions along the leaf nodes of the tree structure of Section 4. By the same arguments as in Section 4 we can show that PNE g is empty for those topologies/games. The form of the utility function, namely the fact that the function f has all the properties stated in the model and is the same for all players, is critical in establishing a negative answer to Goyal s problem. The class of network topologies g for which PNE g is nonempty remains unknown. References Bramoulle, Y. and R. Kranton (2007), Public Goods in Networks, Journal of Eco- 7

nomic Theory 135, 478-494. Goyal, S. (2007) Connections, An Introduction to the economics of Networks, Princeton University Press. Jackson, M. (2008) Social and Economic Networks, Princeton University Press. Vega-Redondo, F. (2007) Complex Social Networks, Cambridge University Press. Fudenberg, D. and Tirole, J. (1991) Game Theory, MIT Press. 8