Modified Neoclassical Growth Models with Delay: A Critical Survey and Perspectives

Similar documents
AN AK TIME TO BUILD GROWTH MODEL

2 The model with Kaldor-Pasinetti saving

Another Proof for the Stability of a Modified Solow Model

A Note on the Ramsey Growth Model with the von Bertalanffy Population Law

A Generalized Solow Nonautonomous Model with Delay and Bounded Population Growth

Direction and Stability of Hopf Bifurcation in a Delayed Model with Heterogeneous Fundamentalists

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

A modification of Kaldor-Kalecki model and its analysis

1 The Basic RBC Model

Stability and nonlinear dynamics in a Solow model with pollution

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

THE SOLOW-SWAN MODEL WITH A NEGATIVE LABOR GROWTH RATE

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

The Ramsey Model. Alessandra Pelloni. October TEI Lecture. Alessandra Pelloni (TEI Lecture) Economic Growth October / 61

Endogenous Growth: AK Model

The Real Business Cycle Model

1. Money in the utility function (start)

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Introduction to Recursive Methods

Delay Kaldor-Kalecki Model Revisited. September 2014

The Cai Model with Time Delay: Existence of Periodic Solutions and Asymptotic Analysis

Research Article Center Manifold Reduction and Perturbation Method in a Delayed Model with a Mound-Shaped Cobb-Douglas Production Function

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

"0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

Dynamic Optimization Using Lagrange Multipliers

Chapter 9 Solow. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos. Computational Economics: a concise introduction

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA

Econ 204A: Section 3

Endogenous Growth Theory

On the dynamics of basic growth models: Ratio stability versus convergence and divergence in state space

Chapter 11 The Stochastic Growth Model and Aggregate Fluctuations

Problem Set #2: Overlapping Generations Models Suggested Solutions - Q2 revised

14.05: Section Handout #1 Solow Model

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Stochastic shocks in a two-sector Solow model

Time-varying Consumption Tax, Productive Government Spending, and Aggregate Instability.

Macroeconomics Theory II

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy: Basic features

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization

Neoclassical Growth Model: I

Advanced Macroeconomics

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

Advanced Macroeconomics

Economics 202A Lecture Outline #3 (version 1.0)

Monetary Policy and Equilibrium Indeterminacy in a Cash in Advance Economy with Investment. Abstract

Generic Analysis of Endogenous Growth Models

The Neoclassical Growth Model

The Pasinetti-Solow Growth Model With Optimal Saving Behaviour: A Local Bifurcation Analysis

FLUCTUATIONS IN A MIXED IS-LM BUSINESS CYCLE MODEL

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Endogenous Growth. Lecture 17 & 18. Topics in Macroeconomics. December 8 & 9, 2008

Economic Growth (Continued) The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model. 1 Literature. Ramsey (1928) Cass (1965) and Koopmans (1965) 2 Households (Preferences)

Chapter 12 Ramsey Cass Koopmans model

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Technology Di usion, Trade and Interdependencies: Di usion of Technology

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

Hopf Bifurcation Analysis of a Dynamical Heart Model with Time Delay

On the dynamics of an endogenous growth model with learning by doing. Alfred Greiner

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

On the Dynamic Implications of the Cobb- Douglas Production Function

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Catastrophe Theory and Postmodern General Equilibrium: Some Critical Observations

A Summary of Economic Methodology

Endogenous growth, and time to build: the AK case

Lecture 1: Overview, Hamiltonians and Phase Diagrams. ECO 521: Advanced Macroeconomics I. Benjamin Moll. Princeton University, Fall

The Growth Model in Continuous Time (Ramsey Model)

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework

ECON 582: The Neoclassical Growth Model (Chapter 8, Acemoglu)

Topic 5: The Difference Equation

Modeling Economic Growth Using Differential Equations

Adjustment Costs and Long Run Spatial Agglomerations 1

Lecture 5: The neoclassical growth model

Lecture 1: The Classical Optimal Growth Model

2 JOHN STACHURSKI collection of all distributions on the state space into itself with the property that the image of the current distribution ' t is t

Neoclassical Models of Endogenous Growth

Stability Analysis of Uzawa-Lucas Endogenous Growth Model

Business Cycles: The Classical Approach

The Ramsey/Cass-Koopmans (RCK) Model

Dynamic Three-Factor Models of International Trade *

Lecture 3 - Solow Model

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth

Volume 29, Issue 4. Stability under learning: the neo-classical growth problem

Endogenous growth with addictive habits

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Macroeconomics Theory II

On Returns to Scale Assumption in Endogenous Growth

Macroeconomics II Dynamic macroeconomics Class 1: Introduction and rst models

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2015 P. Gourinchas/D. Romer MIDTERM EXAM

Problem 1 (30 points)

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

Welfare Equivalent NNP and Habit Formation

Transcription:

Applied Mathematical Sciences, Vol. 7, 2013, no. 86, 4249-4257 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/10.12988/ams.2013.36318 Modified Neoclassical Growth Models with Delay: A Critical Survey and Perspectives Massimiliano Ferrara Department of Law and Economics University Mediterranea of Reggio Calabria Via dei Bianchi 2, 89127 Reggio Calabria, Italy massimiliano.ferrara@unirc.it Luca Guerrini Department of Management Polytechnic University of Marche Piazza Martelli 8, 60121 Ancona, Italy luca.guerrini@univpm.it Roberto Mavilia Foreigners University Dante Alighieri of Reggio Calabria and MEDAlics Research Centre for Mediterranean Relations Via del Torrione 95, 89125 Reggio Calabria, Italy roberto.mavilia@unistrada.it Copyright c 2013 Massimiliano Ferrara et al. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. Abstract This paper reviews the relationship between lags and cycles into classical structures of growth models (see Solow-Swan and Ramsey models). Some remarks and perspectives of research are determined. Mathematics Subject Classification: 91B62 Keywords: Growth models, delay, general equilibrium

4250 Massimiliano Ferrara, Luca Guerrini and Roberto Mavilia 1 Introduction All production takes time, that is the transformation of inputs into outputs does not occur instantaneously but exhibits a gestation lag. Jevons (1871), was one of the first economists which underlined the important property that capital is concerned with time. In his work The Theory of Political Economy he quoted the following passage from Hearn s work (1864) entitled Plutology : A vineyard is unproductive for at least three years before it is thoroughly fit for use. In gold mining there is often a long delay, sometimes even of five or six years, before gold is reached. The time dimension of capital was further studied by Hayek (1931), who identified in the time of production one of the possible sources of aggregate fluctuation. Hayek s analysis was based on Böhm-Bawerk s work (1891) on concept of the average period of production. The Hayek s insight was formally confirmed for the first time by Kalecki (1935), who rigorously showed that lags in the production of capital goods produce cycles endogenously, rather than being driven by exogenous shocks. Other early works in this area were done by Frisch and Holme (1935), and by Belz and James (1938). Notice that Kalecki frequently referred to a paper by Tinbergen (1931) on shipbuilding as guiding his mode of analysis. This is not, however, direct quotation of Tinbergen, rather, Kalecki often expanded and explained that which in Tinbergen is unclear and non-obvious. For example, as Kalecki noted, Tinbergen did not carry out a full analysis of the stability of the system, which was of fundamental importance to the conclusions. From a mathematical point of view, Kalecki s model of the economic cycle is a differential equation with a delay parameter, i.e. a delay differential equation (DDE). Kalecki significantly contributed to the development of mathematical techniques used to characterize stability in linear DDEs that were widely applicable across a number of scientific fields. We must strongly emphasize that the general stability properties of a linear one delay differential equation, such as Kalecki s model of business cycle, were not fully understood until a 1950 s theorem of Hayes, although Kalecki did a quite thorough analysis of stability. Delay differential equations, and in general functional differential equations are very interesting but, at the same time, quite complicated mathematical objects. Since the first contributions of Kalecki (1935), Frisch and Holme (1935), and Belz and James (1938), very few authors have used this mathematical instrument for modelizing the time structure of capital. This line of argument was revived by the seminal article of Kydland and Prescott (1982), who empirically analyzed how far time consuming investment, which they called time to build (capital goods need some time over which they require investments in order to be produced), could explain real business cycles. While Kydland and Prescott

Modified neoclassical growth models with delay 4251 (1982) argued that the time to build feature is essential to cyclical fluctuations in their model, this was doubted by Ioannides and Taub (1992). Rustichini (1989) and Asea and Zak (1999) showed, in simple delayed continuous time optimal control models with one capital good (but a different lag structure) that the time to build feature is the driving force for the oscillatory system dynamics. More recently, this issue has been extensively addressed in the literature, see, e.g., Szydlowski (2002),(2003), Krawiec and Szydlowski (2004), Brons and Jensen (2007), Bambi (2008), Collard, Licandro and Puch (2008), Matsumoto and Szidarovszky (2011), Yuksel (2011), Winkler (2011), Bambi, Fabbri and Gozzi (2012), Ferrara (2009,2010,2011). This paper review the relationship between lags and cycles in general equilibrium. The general equilibrium cases considered are production lag augmented versions of the Solow-Swan (1956) growth model as well as the single-good optimal growth model of Ramsey (1928), Cass (1965) and Koopmans (1965). 2 Solow-Swan model with time delay In a Kaleckian spirit, we consider a version of the 1956 model of Solow and Swan in which there is a delay of T 0 periods before capital can be used for produc- tion. This delay captures the time it takes to produce and install capital goods. At time t, the productive capital stock is k(t T ). By assumption, the saving rate s is constant, a proportion of the capital stock, δ, depreciates during production, and we have a constant population normalized to unity (n = 0). As a result the model of economic growth with a built-in delay parameter in delivering capital goods is given by the following dynamic equation with a delayed argument: k t = sf(k t T ) δk t T (1) for some initial function k t = φ, t [ T,0]. Instead of an initial point value for an ordinary differential equation, the initial function φ t is required, which is defined over the range of time delimited by the delay. To analyse the properties of equation (1) it is useful to carry out a local stability analysis. Equation (1) has exactly the same equilibrium point of the standard Solow-Swan model (T = 0) since time delay does not change the equilibria of the equation. Linearizing the right hand-side of equation (1) at its unique non-trivial steady state k, and then making the change of variables x t = k t k, we get x t = Ax t T (2) where A = sf (k ) δ < 0. We consider the characteristic equation for equation (2) which can formally be obtained by the substitution of a probe

4252 Massimiliano Ferrara, Luca Guerrini and Roberto Mavilia solution k t = e λt into equation (2). Then we obtain λ Ae λt = 0 (3) Equation (3) is a quasi-polynomial, which exhibits an infinite number of (complex) roots. For roots of equation (3) that have real parts that are negative, the model has damped cycles, positive roots correspond to explosive cycles, while purely imaginary roots, if they exist, indicate that the model has periodic cycles. The Poincar-Andronov-Hopf (PAH) theorem states the conditions that are necessary to produce such a bifurcation and a limit cycle. There is the generalisation of the PAH theorem to the case of functional differential equations. Therefore it is sufficient to check all the assumptions of this theorem to prove the existence of endogenous cycles in equation (2). The first step is to find the value of the time delay parameter, T = T 0, for which the Hopf bifurcation takes place. The method employed is to posit that such a purely imaginary solution exists and to rule out contradictions that would show the supposition to be false. A pair of purely imaginary roots means that solutions to equation (3) have the form λ = iω 0,ω 0 > 0. After some simple manipulation we obtain ω 0 = A and T 0 = π/( 2A). The next step in proving the existence of the Hopf bifurcation is checking that there is no other eigenvalues with Reλ = 0. The last step in proving the existence of Hopf cycles is to check the transversality condition [dreλ(t )/dt ] T =T0 0. The confirmation of this property ends our proof of the existence of the Hopf cycle in this model. We have thus shown that augmenting the Solow model with a production lag changes the interior steady state from being stable to being, in general, a saddle for most initial functions φ T and values of the lag T. For a particular value of the production lag, T = T 0, there is a corresponding initial function so that only the dynamics of the model lie on the center manifold, a two-dimensional subspace of the eigenspace that contains purely imaginary roots to the characteristic equation. On the center manifold, we have proved that the model exhibits endogenous cycles. A separate issue is the problem of the stability of the limit cycle itself. To prove this fact one has to use normal coordinates and the theorem of the center manifold. To our knowledge the only work for determining the direction of the Hopf bifurcation and the stability of bifurcating periodic solutions in the delayed Solow-Swan model is due to by Brons and Jensen (2007), but using a different approach: the Poincare-Lindstedt s perturbation method. However, their calculations contains some mistakes. 3 Ramsey model with time delay Now we examine whether production-lag-induced cycles will emerge in a more complicated setting, that of the optimal growth model, where consumers choose

Modified neoclassical growth models with delay 4253 savings each period as a function of their labor income, wealth, and the interest rate. Consider an economy that is inhabited by a continuum of infinitely-lived in- dividuals. The representative individual s preferences are represented by a continuous, strictly increasing and concave utility function u(c t )=(c 1 σ t 1)/(1 σ), with σ>0 and c t consumption, satisfying the Inada conditions and a subjective discount rate ρ>0. In this economy it takes T > 0 periods to produce and install new capital equipment. The infinite horizon planning problem for this economy is given by max u(c 0 t )e ρt dt, subject to k t = f(k t T ) δk t T c t, with initial conditions k t = φ t,t [ T,0]. The problem of optimising the functional can be solved by using standard Hamiltonian methods and the generalised version of Pontryagin s maximum principle (El-Hodiri et al., 1972, Kolmanovskii and Myshkis, 1999). Asea and Zak (1999) arrived to the following optimality conditions: { kt = f(k t T ) δk t T c t, c t = ct [ρ + δ f (4) (k σ t T )]. The first-order conditions are similar to the standard optimal growth model with the exception of the time delay in production. The interior steady state is exactly the same as the standard optimal growth model, again because the time delay is irrelevant at a steady state. As in the delayed Solow-Swan model, Asea and Zak (1999) analyzed the production-lag optimal growth model to see if it produces Hopf cycles. The analysis proceeds by linearizing system (4) about the interior steady state. Then, the dynamics near the steady state can be determined using the associated characteristic equation. They demonstrated that the steady state, though typically a saddle, may exhibit Hopf cycles. Furthermore, the optimal path to the steady state is oscillatory. However, their result is puzzling because a time-to-build assumption should lead to a system of mixed functional differential equations: { kt = f(k t T ) δk t T c t, c t = ct {[f (k σ t T ) δ]( ct c t+t ) σ e ρt (5) ρ}. Asea and Zak s mistake (1999) was in a wrong application of the Pontryagin s maximum principle. This is not a minor point, and makes the resolution of this problem an important open issue. A special case, the AK growth model, was analyzed in detail by Bambi (2008)and Winkler (2009). They showed that the optimal system dynamics converges in an oscillatory manner toward the long run balanced growth path or exhibits a limit cycle around it. Furthermore, the oscillatory behavior is the more pronounced the larger is the delay.

4254 Massimiliano Ferrara, Luca Guerrini and Roberto Mavilia 4 Open problems In this frame of research it would be interesting to trying to solve the following open problems: Delayed neoclassical models where population growth n 0. This will lead to a more complicated setting: an equation with delay dependent parameters. Delayed neoclassical models where population growth follows the logistic law. Delayed neoclassical models, where time delay is not constant but variable. Stochastic analogue of delayed neoclassical models. References [1] Asea, P., and Zak P., Time to build and cycles, Journal of Economic Dynamic and Control, 23 (1999), 1155-1175. [2] Bambi M., Endogenous growth and time to build: the AK case, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 32 (2008), 1015-1040 [3] Bambi M.,Fabbri G., and Gozzi F., Optimal policy and consumption smoothing effects in the time-to-build AK model, Economic Theory, 50 (2012), 635-669. [4] Belz M.H., and James R.W., The significance of the characteristic solutions of mixed difference and differential equations, Econometrica, 6 (1938),326-343. [5] Böhm-Bawerk E., The Positive Theory of Capital, translated by William A. Smart, Macmillan & Co Ltd., London, 1891. [6] Brons M., and Jensen B.S., Hopf bifurcation in growth models with time delays. In: Stochastic Economic Dynamics. ed. / Bjarne S.Jensen ; TapioPalokangas. Frederiksberg : Copenhagen Business School Press,(2007), 247-268. [7] Cass D., Optimum growth in an aggregative model of capital accumulation, Review of Economic Studies, 32 (1965), 233-240.

Modified neoclassical growth models with delay 4255 [8] Collard F., Licandro O. and Puch L., The short run dynamics of optimal growth models with delays. Annales d Economie et Statistique, 90 (2008),127-144. [9] El-Hodiri M.A., Loehman E. and Whinston A., An optimal growth model with time lags. Econometrica, 40 (1972), 1137-1146. [10] Ferrara, M., Guerrini, L., The Ramsey model with von Bertalanffy population law and Benthamite function, (2010) Far East Journal of Mathematical Sciences, 45 (1), 135-140. [11] Ferrara, M., Guerrini, L., The neoclassical model with variable population change, (2009) Proceedings of the 11th WSEAS International Conference on Mathematical and Computational Methods in Science and Engineering, MACMESE 09, 119-123. [12] Ferrara, M., An AK Solow model with a non-positive rate of population growth, (2011) Applied Mathematical Sciences, 5 (25-28), 1241-1244. [13] Ferrara, M., Another proof for the stability of a modified Solow model, (2011) Applied Mathematical Sciences, 5 (25-28), 1229-1233. [14] Ferrara, M., A note on convergence speed and population in the AK model with habit formation, (2011) International Journal of Pure and Applied Mathematics, 67 (3), pp. 327-335. [15] Ferrara, M., An AK Solow model with logistic law technology, (2011) International Journal of Pure and Applied Mathematics, 67 (3), 337-340. [16] Ferrara, M., Technological diffusion and Benthamite utility in the Ramsey model: An analytical exploration, (2011) International Journal of Pure and Applied Mathematics, 67 (2), 225-236. [17] Ferrara, M., A new proof of the global asymptotic stability of the Solow growth model with migration, (2011) Far East Journal of Mathematical Sciences, 50 (1), 55-58. [18] Frisch R., and Holme H., The characteristic solutions of a mixed difference and differential equation occuring in economic dynamics, Econometrica, 3 (1935), 225-239. [19] Hayek F. von, Prices and Production, George Routledge & Sons, Ltd., Broadway House, 68-74 Carter Lane (1931), London. [20] Hayes N., Roots of transcendental equation associated with certain differential difference equation, Journal of London Mathematical Society, 25 (1950), 226-232.

4256 Massimiliano Ferrara, Luca Guerrini and Roberto Mavilia [21] Hearn W.E., Plutology; or The Theory of the Efforts to Satisfy Human Wants, (Macmillan), 139 (1864). [22] Jevons W.S., The theory of political economy. A.M. Kelly, (1871). [23] Kalecki M., A macroeconomic theory of the business cycle, Econometrica, 3 (1935), 327-344. [24] Kydland F.E., and Prescott E.C., Time to build and aggregate fluctuations, Econometrica, 50 (1982), 1345-1370. [25] Kolmanovskii V.B. and Myshkis A.D., Introduction to the Theory and Applications of Functional Differential Equations. Dordrecht, The Netherlands. Kluwer, (1999). [26] Koopmans T., On the concept of optimal growth, in: The Econometric Approach to Development Planning (Chicago, Rand McNally), (1965). [27] Krawiec A., and Szydlowski M., A note on the Kaleckian lags in the Solow model. Review of Political Economy, 16 (2004), 501-506. [28] Ioannides Y.M., and Taub B., On dynamics with time-to-build investment and non-separable leisure, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 16 (1992), 225-241. [29] Matsumoto A., and Szidarovszky F., Delay differential neoclassical growth Model, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 78 (2011), 272-289. [30] Ramsey F.A., A mathematical theory of savings. Economic Journal, 38 (1928), 543-559. [31] Rustichini A., Hopf bifurcation for functional differential equation of mixed type, Journal of Dynamics and Differential Equation, 1 (1989), 145-177. [32] Solow R.M., A contribution to the theory of economic growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70 1956), 65-94. [33] Swan T.W., Economic growth and capital accumulation, Economic Record, 32 (1956), 334-361. [34] Szydlowski M., Time-to-build in dynamics of economic models I: Kalecki s model. Chaos, Solitons & Fractals, 14 (2002), 697-703. [35] Szydlowski M., Time-to-build in dynamics of economic models II: models of economic growth. Chaos, Solitons & Fractals, 14 (2003), 355-364.

Modified neoclassical growth models with delay 4257 [36] Tinbergen J., Ein Schijfbauzyklus, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv., 34 (1931),152-164. [37] Udriste, C., Ferrara, M., Multitime models of optimal growth, (2008) WSEAS Transactions on Mathematics, 7 (1), 51-55. [38] Yüksel M.K., Capital dependent population growth induces cycles, Chaos, Solitons & Fractals, 44 (2011), 759-763. [39] Winkler R., Time-to-build in the ak growth model: short-run dynamics and response to exogenous shocks. Mimeo, Center of Economic Research at ETH Zurich, (2009). [40] Winkler R., A note on the optimal control of stocks accumulating with a delay, Macroeconomic Dynamics, 15 (2011), 565-578. Received: June 1, 2013