Monetary Policy E ectiveness in a Dynamic AS/AD Model with Sticky Wages

Similar documents
Monetary Policy Effectiveness in a Dynamic AS/AD Model with Sticky Wages

Optimal Pigouvian Taxation when Externalities Affect Demand

Deflation of the I-O Series Some Technical Aspects. Giorgio Rampa University of Genoa April 2007

Endowment Structure, Industrialization and Post-industrialization: A Three-Sector Model of Structural Change. Abstract

On the Macroeconomic and Welfare Effects of Illegal Immigration

Is Walras s Theory So Different From Marshall s?

A Simple Model of Reliability, Warranties, and Price-Capping

Soft Computing Techniques Help Assign Weights to Different Factors in Vulnerability Analysis

2.003 Engineering Dynamics Problem Set 2 Solutions

Proc. of the IEEE/OES Seventh Working Conference on Current Measurement Technology UNCERTAINTIES IN SEASONDE CURRENT VELOCITIES

ma x = -bv x + F rod.

Block designs and statistics

COS 424: Interacting with Data. Written Exercises

Data-Driven Imaging in Anisotropic Media

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Some Perspective. Forces and Newton s Laws

An Extension to the Tactical Planning Model for a Job Shop: Continuous-Time Control

Force and dynamics with a spring, analytic approach

8.1 Force Laws Hooke s Law

Chapter 1: Basics of Vibrations for Simple Mechanical Systems

2 Q 10. Likewise, in case of multiple particles, the corresponding density in 2 must be averaged over all

Physics 215 Winter The Density Matrix

Aggregate Supply. A Nonvertical AS Curve. implications for unemployment, rms pricing behavior, the real wage and the markup

LONG-TERM PREDICTIVE VALUE INTERVAL WITH THE FUZZY TIME SERIES

Figure 1: Equivalent electric (RC) circuit of a neurons membrane

Handwriting Detection Model Based on Four-Dimensional Vector Space Model

12 Towards hydrodynamic equations J Nonlinear Dynamics II: Continuum Systems Lecture 12 Spring 2015

U V. r In Uniform Field the Potential Difference is V Ed

Tactics Box 2.1 Interpreting Position-versus-Time Graphs

Physically Based Modeling CS Notes Spring 1997 Particle Collision and Contact

Pivots Versus Signals in Elections

26 Impulse and Momentum

XI PHYSICS M. AFFAN KHAN LECTURER PHYSICS, AKHSS, K.

Q5 We know that a mass at the end of a spring when displaced will perform simple m harmonic oscillations with a period given by T = 2!

Sophisticated Monetary Policies

A Simple Regression Problem

USEFUL HINTS FOR SOLVING PHYSICS OLYMPIAD PROBLEMS. By: Ian Blokland, Augustana Campus, University of Alberta

Now multiply the left-hand-side by ω and the right-hand side by dδ/dt (recall ω= dδ/dt) to get:

BALLISTIC PENDULUM. EXPERIMENT: Measuring the Projectile Speed Consider a steel ball of mass

MSEC MODELING OF DEGRADATION PROCESSES TO OBTAIN AN OPTIMAL SOLUTION FOR MAINTENANCE AND PERFORMANCE

ASSIGNMENT BOOKLET Bachelor s Degree Programme (B.Sc./B.A./B.Com.) MATHEMATICAL MODELLING

Bootstrapping Dependent Data

Analysis of Impulsive Natural Phenomena through Finite Difference Methods A MATLAB Computational Project-Based Learning

Inflation Forecasts: An Empirical Re-examination. Swarna B. Dutt University of West Georgia. Dipak Ghosh Emporia State University

A DESIGN GUIDE OF DOUBLE-LAYER CELLULAR CLADDINGS FOR BLAST ALLEVIATION

An Approximate Model for the Theoretical Prediction of the Velocity Increase in the Intermediate Ballistics Period

AVOIDING PITFALLS IN MEASUREMENT UNCERTAINTY ANALYSIS

Lecture 6, January 7 and 15: Sticky Wages and Prices (Galí, Chapter 6)

Chapter 5, Conceptual Questions

In this chapter, we consider several graph-theoretic and probabilistic models

I. Understand get a conceptual grasp of the problem

NB1140: Physics 1A - Classical mechanics and Thermodynamics Problem set 2 - Forces and energy Week 2: November 2016

MATHEMATICAL MODEL OF THE ENERGETIC CONSUMPTION FOR SOIL DIGGING MACHINES IN GREENHOUSES

Feature Extraction Techniques

Revealed Preference with Stochastic Demand Correspondence

Supervised assessment: Modelling and problem-solving task

Physics 139B Solutions to Homework Set 3 Fall 2009

Support Vector Machine Classification of Uncertain and Imbalanced data using Robust Optimization

Testing for a Break in the Memory Parameter

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Polygonal Designs: Existence and Construction

Estimation of Korean Monthly GDP with Mixed-Frequency Data using an Unobserved Component Error Correction Model

The Lagrangian Method vs. other methods (COMPARATIVE EXAMPLE)

Hierarchical central place system and agglomeration economies on households

On the Existence of Pure Nash Equilibria in Weighted Congestion Games

7. Renormalization and universality in pionless EFT

Information Loss in Volatility Measurement with Flat Price Trading 1

INTELLECTUAL DATA ANALYSIS IN AIRCRAFT DESIGN

Donald Fussell. October 28, Computer Science Department The University of Texas at Austin. Point Masses and Force Fields.

SCHOOL OF FINANCE AND ECONOMICS

Keywords: Estimator, Bias, Mean-squared error, normality, generalized Pareto distribution

Anisotropic reference media and the possible linearized approximations for phase velocities of qs waves in weakly anisotropic media

The Wilson Model of Cortical Neurons Richard B. Wells

The Characteristic Planet

CSE525: Randomized Algorithms and Probabilistic Analysis May 16, Lecture 13

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010

In the session you will be divided into groups and perform four separate experiments:

Revealed Preference and Stochastic Demand Correspondence: A Unified Theory

2.9 Feedback and Feedforward Control

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

The Weierstrass Approximation Theorem

Electromagnetic fields modeling of power line communication (PLC)

Graphical Models in Local, Asymmetric Multi-Agent Markov Decision Processes

Lecture #8-3 Oscillations, Simple Harmonic Motion

1 Bounding the Margin

Physics 2107 Oscillations using Springs Experiment 2

Using EM To Estimate A Probablity Density With A Mixture Of Gaussians

A Better Algorithm For an Ancient Scheduling Problem. David R. Karger Steven J. Phillips Eric Torng. Department of Computer Science

Modeling the Structural Shifts in Real Exchange Rate with Cubic Spline Regression (CSR). Turkey

Analyzing Simulation Results

Contractual Frictions and Global Sourcing

THE KALMAN FILTER: A LOOK BEHIND THE SCENE

An analytical relation between relaxation time spectrum and molecular weight distribution

Equilibria on the Day-Ahead Electricity Market

Supplementary Information for Design of Bending Multi-Layer Electroactive Polymer Actuators

Chapter 10 Atmospheric Forces & Winds

Lost-Sales Problems with Stochastic Lead Times: Convexity Results for Base-Stock Policies

C na (1) a=l. c = CO + Clm + CZ TWO-STAGE SAMPLE DESIGN WITH SMALL CLUSTERS. 1. Introduction

Probability Distributions

A Simplified Analytical Approach for Efficiency Evaluation of the Weaving Machines with Automatic Filling Repair

Transcription:

Monetary Policy E ectiveness in a Dynaic AS/AD Model with Sticky Wages Henrik Jensen Departent of Econoics University of Copenhagen y Version.0, April 2, 202 Teaching note for M.Sc. course on "Monetary Econoics: Macro Aspects". c 202 Henrik Jensen. All rights reserved. The note builds on, and extends, a odel laid out in Walsh (200), as well as y earlier teaching aterial on this subject. I thank Christian Groth and Carl E. Walsh for coents and discussions on earlier versions. y Address: Øster Fariagsgade 5, Building 26, Dk-353 Copenhagen K, Denark. E-ail: Henrik.Jensen@econ.ku.dk. Web: hjeconoics.dk.

Preface This note deals with onetary policy e ectiveness in a New-Classical odel with icrofoudations. The odel is a siple oney-in-the-utility function odel with one-period noinal wage rigidity. The aggregate supply curve of the odel is akin to the Lucas supply function, which is a de ning eleent of New-Classical econoics. This research progra, focusing on rational expectations, gave rise to the faous Policy Ine ectiveness Proposition, stating that systeatic coponents in policy design had no in uence on real activity. This note shows how systeatic coponents of policyaking a ect the variability output, thereby ephasizing that even within early rational-expectations odels of this type, there is real ipact of systeatic policy intervention. Henrik Jensen, April 202

Introduction Consider the log-linearized, sipli ed oney-in-the utility function odel with exible prices as presented in Walsh (200) p. 227. All lower-case letters denote log-deviations fro steady state, except interest rates which are absolute deviations of respective rates fro their steady-state values. See Walsh (200, Section 2.7.) for the derivation of the full version of the odel. Output, y t, is produced by labor, n t, according to a Cobb-Douglas technology: y t = ( ) n t e t ; 0 < < ; (6.) where e t is a ean-zero supply shock assued to be serially uncorrelated (this akes a distinction between the supply shock e t and the shock " t e t E t e t de ned in Walsh, 200, irrelevant). All output is consued in equilibriu: y t = c t ; (6.2) where c t is consuption. Firs hire labor up to the point where the arginal product of labor equals the real wage, such that labor deand is characterized by y t n t = w t p t ; (6.3) where w t is the noinal wage and p t is the price level. Consuers choose consuption over tie so as to satisfy the conventional Keynes-Rasey rule, which in logs can be written as E t (c t c t ) r t = 0; > 0; (6.4) where r t is the real interest rate and is the coe cient of relative risk aversion in consuption, which in this setting equals the inverse of the interteporal rate of substitution. E t is the rational-expectations operator conditional on all inforation up until, and including, period t. Consuers choose to supply labor such that the arginal rate of substitution between leisure and consuption equals the real wage; in logs this is n ss n n ss t c t = w t p t ; > 0; (6.5) where n ss is the steady-state value of labor, and is the coe cient of relative risk aversion in leisure, which in this setting can be interpreted as the inverse (Frisch) elasticity of labor In order to facilitate the coparison with Walsh (200), I retain his equation nubering when adequate.

supply. With exible wages, as well as prices, (6.) (6.5) deterine y t, c t, n t, r t and w t p t. Monetary policy will have no role for output deterination. Money deand is given by t p t = c t i bi ss t ; b = > 0; (6.6) where t is the noinal oney supply, i t is the noinal interest rate, i ss is the steady-state noinal interest rate, and b is a utility function paraeter deterining the interest-rate elasticity of oney deand. This version of the odel assues b =, so as to focus on the siple version with separable utility of consuption, real oney holdings and leisure. (The paraeters b and will, however, be used independently throughout so as to highlight their di erent roles.) The Fisher equation links the noinal interest rate to the real rate and expected in ation: i t = r t E t p t p t : (6.7) Finally, the odel is closed by a speci cation of the process for the oney supply: t = t s t ; 0 j j ; (6.8) where the shock s t has ean zero and is serially uncorrelated. To introduce a role for onetary policy, soe noinal stickiness is assued. Speci - cally, it is stipulated that noinal wages are xed for one period, and are deterined the period before according to: w t = E t p t E t y t E t n t ; () = E t p t E t! t : I.e., the expected real wage is set so as to atch the expected arginal product of labor, labelled E t! t. With this wage-setting rule, equation (6.5) becoes redundant. Also, equation (6.8) is replaced by the slightly ore general expression t = t s t : where is soe constant. Note that in Appendix 6.5, Walsh (200) considers the special case of t = t s t. This sipli cation unintentionally hides the e ectiveness of systeatic onetary policy as will be clear below. 2 We now turn to the solution of the odel under sticky wages. 2 He acknowledges this in Footnote 6 on p. 230. 2

2 Solving the odel 2. Fleshing out an AS/AD structure It is appropriate to ake soe sipli cations of the presented syste of equations. Here, it will be easy to substitute out c t by y t and r t by r t = i t (E t p t p t ). Also, one can iediately substitute the noinal wage rule, (), into (6.3). Then, a sipler syste is: y t = ( ) n t e t ; (2) y t n t = E t p t E t y t E t n t p t ; (3) E t (y t y t ) = i t (E t p t p t ) ; (4) t p t = y t i t ; (5) bi ss t = t s t : (6) This syste of ve equations will deterine the rational-expectations solutions for the ve variables y t, n t, i t, p t, and t, given the shocks e t and s t and given t. Now we proceed as in Walsh (200, Appendix 6.5) by splitting up the syste into the aggregate supply and deand sides. Equations (2) and (3) constitute the supply side, and give supply of output and eployent as function of prices, whereas equations (4), (5) and (6) give output deand and the noinal interest rate (via oney deand) as functions of prices. These aggregate supply and deand schedules then provide the equilibriu output and price level. Let us start with the supply side. Fro (3) we get which inserted into (2) gives n t = E t n t y t E t y t p t E t p t ; y t = ( ) (E t n t y t E t y t p t E t p t ) e t ; and therefore y t = ( ) (E t n t E t y t p t E t p t ) e t : Take period-t expectations on both sides of (2) to get (reebering that E t e t = 0 by assuption): E t y t = ( ) E t n t ; and substitute out ( )E t n t above: y t = E t y t ( ) ( E t y t p t E t p t ) e t ; y t = E t y t ( ) (p t E t p t ) e t ; 3

thereby providing the output equation y t = E t y t (p t E t p t ) e t; or, y t = E t y t a (p t E t p t ) ( a) e t ; a ( ) = > 0: As E t e t = 0, it follows that E t y t = 0 (as E t n t = 0). 3 We therefore have: y t = a (p t E t p t ) ( a) e t : (7) This aggregate supply schedule is a version of the Lucas supply curve that has been central in uch acroeconoics since the 970s. Now consider the deand side. Equations (4) and (5) can iediately be rewritten as a dynaic IS curve and a standard LM curve: y t = E t y t (i t [E t p t p t ]) ; (8) t = p t y t i bi ss t : (9) Following the approach in Walsh, we rewrite the oney deand equation in ters of expected in ation and expected output growth using the dynaic IS curve: t = p t y t bi ss (E tp t p t ) bi ss (E ty t y t ) : Using the exogenous process for the oney supply, we get a characterization of the aggregate deand side in ters of output and prices: t s t = p t y t bi ss (E tp t p t ) bi ss (E ty t y t ) : (0) Equation (0) indeed characterizes, for given expectations and oney supply, a negative relationship between prices and output. The reasons are partly the standard one fro the IS/LM story: Higher prices will increase noinal oney deand. To secure oney arket equilibriu, the noinal interest rate will increase, which depresses deand. 3 This follows fro the underlying odel when the real wage target! t fro () is consistent with the exible-wage eployent level; i.e., the real wage that equates labor deand with labor supply. This results in the following expression for eployent (see Walsh, 200, p. 228): n t = e t : n ss n ( ) ( ) ss This is derived by cobining (6.), 6.2), (6.3) and (6.5). 4

In this interteporal odel, an additional channel is present. For given period-t price expectations, a higher price in period t reduces in ation expectations, E t p t p t, and increases the real interest rate. This causes consuers to substitute deand fro now to later for given expectations about future deand, period-t deand decreases. The sae will happen if, for exaple, expectations about future prices go down. This expected in ation channel is norally not presented in standard IS/LM expositions, where there is no distinction between noinal and real interest rates in the IS relationship. distinction, arising naturally fro the underlying icro-founded odel, is crucial for the results on policy e ectiveness as will be clear below. 2.2 Applying the ethod of undeterined coe cients With (7) and (0) we have a two-equation rational expectations odel for y t and p t. This is solved by the ethod of undeterined coe cients. For this purpose we conjecture, or guess, a solution in ters of undeterined coe cients. In this odel, we conjecture the following solution for prices: The p t = 0 t 2 s t 3 e t : () Knowing what to conjecture is not always obvious, but in linear rational expectations odels, it is safe to ake a conjecture that is a linear function of shocks, constants and state variables. In a oent we will verify the that this for of the conjecture is indeed consistent with a solution of the odel, and we can derive the values of 0,, 2, and 3 as function of the odel s paraeters. Now, insert y t and E t y t as given by (7) into (0) so as to obtain an expression in prices only: t s t = p t a [p t E t p t ] ( a) e t bi ss (E tp t p t ) bi ss (E t [a fp t E t p t g f ag e t ] [a fp t E t p t g f ag e t ]) : We readily see that E t [a fp t E t p t g f ag e t ] = E t y t = 0; as E t e t = 0 by assuption, and as E t [a fp t E t p t g] = 0. Hence, we have t s t = p t a [p t E t p t ] ( a) e t bi ss (E tp t p t ) bi ss (a [p t E t p t ] [ a] e t ) : (2) 5

as a rational-expectations equation deterining prices. This is what we need, as we have ade a conjecture for the solution for prices. We can therefore apply that the conjecture, (), iplies p t E t p t = 2 s t 3 e t ; E t p t p t = t t 2 s t 3 e t ; as E t e t = E t s t = 0 for all t. Using this in (2) then gives t s t = 0 t 2 s t 3 e t (3) a [ 2 s t 3 e t ] ( a) e t bi ( ss t t 2 s t 3 e t ) bi (a [ 2s ss t 3 e t ] [ a] e t ) ; Equation (3) is a linear equation involving a constant, the shocks, and past and current oney supply. The latter is eliinated by use of (6), such that we nally get: t s t (4) = 0 t 2 s t 3 e t a [ 2 s t 3 e t ] ( a) e t bi ( ss [ t s t ] t 2 s t 3 e t ) bi (a [ 2s ss t 3 e t ] [ a] e t ) : Equation (4) veri es the conjecture that in a rational expectations equilibriu satisfying the odel s equations, prices are a linear function of a constant, the shocks, and the past period s oney supply. We have not solved for the price level yet, but looking closer at (4), we will (hopefully) realize that the solution is right in front of us. Equation (4) ust hold for any values of, s t, e t and t. So, di erentiating the left- and right-hand sides of (4) with respect to these variables in turn, provides exactly four equations that will give the solutions for the four unknown coe cients. Thus, we obtain the rational expectations solution for p t of the for conjectured. The four equations are: = 2 a 2 bi ss ( = 0 ; (5) biss 2 ) bi ss a 2; (6) 0 = 3 a 3 a bi ss 3 bi ss (a 3 a) ; (7) = bi ss ( ) : (8) 6

Notice that (8) gives the solution for, (7) gives the solution for 3, (6) gives the solution for 2 given, and (5) gives the solution for 0 given. Fro (8) we get and fro (7) we recover Using (9) in (6) gives 3 = = bi ss bi ss ; (9) ( a) (bi ss ) bi ss a (bi ss ) : (20) = 2 a 2 bi ss 2 bi a ss 2 bi ss bi ss bi ss = ( bi ss a [bi ss ]) 2 ; bi ss ( bi ss ) bi ss = ( bi ss a [bi ss ]) 2 ; 2 = and using (9) in (5) gives Hence, the solution for p t is p t = bi ss ; bi ss ( bi ss ) ( bi ss ) ( bi ss a [bi ss ]) ; (2) = 0 bi ss ; 0 = bi ss bi ss : (22) bi ss bi ss bi ss bi ss t (23) bi ss ( bi ss ) ( bi ss ) ( bi ss a [bi ss ]) s ( a) (bi ss ) t bi ss a (bi ss ) e t: We can iediately see that E t p t = bi ss bi ss bi ss bi ss t ; and insert these solutions for p t and E t p t into (7) so as to get the solution for y t : y t = bi ss ( bi ss ) a ( bi ss ) ( bi ss a [bi ss ]) s ( a) (bi ss ) t bi ss a (bi ss ) e t ( a) e t ; = abi ss ( bi ss ) ( bi ss ) ( bi ss a [bi ss ]) s t biss a (bi ss ) a (bi ss ) bi ss a (bi ss ) y t = ( a) e t ; abi ss ( bi ss ) ( bi ss ) ( bi ss a [bi ss ]) s t ( biss ) ( a) bi ss a (bi ss ) e t: (24) 7

With the solutions for p t and y t, we can nd the equilibriu noinal interest rate fro the dynaic IS curve (8), since it with use of (23) and (24) becoes y t = E t y t (i t [E t p t p t ]) abi ss ( bi ss ) ( bi ss ) ( bi ss a [bi ss ]) s t ( biss ) ( a) bi ss a (bi ss ) e t = 0 i t bi ss bi ss bi ss bi ss t bi ss bi ss bi ss bi ss t bi ss ( bi ss ) ( bi ss ) ( bi ss a [bi ss ]) s t ( a) (bi ss ) bi ss a (bi ss ) e t ; i t = abi ss ( bi ss ) ( bi ss ) ( bi ss a [bi ss ]) s t ( bi ss ) ( a) bi ss a (bi ss ) e t bi ss ( bi ss t s t ) bi ss bi ss ( bi ss ) bi ss t ( bi ss ) ( bi ss a [bi ss ]) s t ( a) (bi ss ) bi ss a (bi ss ) e t ; where in the second equation, the exogenous process for t has been inserted. This equation is further sipli ed as i t = abi ss ( bi ss ) ( bi ss ) ( bi ss a [bi ss ]) s t ( bi ss ) ( a) bi ss a (bi ss ) e t = bi ss ( bi ss t s t ) bi ss bi ss ( bi ss ) bi ss t ( bi ss ) ( bi ss a [bi ss ]) s t ( a) (biss ) bi ss a (bi ss ) e t; bi ss bi ss bi ss bi ss bi ss bi ss t bi ss a ( bi ss ) ( bi ss ) bi ss a (bi ss ) bi ss ( bi ss ) bi ss a (bi ss ) ( ) ( bi ss ) ( a) bi ss a (bi ss ) e t; s t 8

leading to i t = bi ss bi ss ( ) bi ss bi ss t bi ss ( bi ss ) [ a] ( bi ss ) bi ss a (bi ss ) s t ( ) ( bi ss ) ( a) bi ss a (bi ss ) e t: (25) 3 The econoics of the solution and the e ectiveness of onetary policy We now have the solutions for output, prices and the noinal interest rate fro (24), (23) and (25), respectively. These are stated again for convenience, and then the properties of the solution are thoroughly discussed with focus on the role of the oney supply process paraeter for the transission of shocks. y t = abi ss ( bi ss ) ( bi ss ) ( bi ss a [bi ss ]) s t ( biss ) ( a) bi ss a (bi ss ) e t: p t = bi ss bi ss bi ss bi ss t bi ss ( bi ss ) ( bi ss ) ( bi ss a [bi ss ]) s t ( a) (bi ss ) bi ss a (bi ss ) e t: i t = bi ss bi ss ( ) bi ss bi ss t bi ss ( bi ss ) [ a] bi ss bi ss a (bi ss ) s t ( ) ( bi ss ) ( a) bi ss a (bi ss ) e t: 3. Supply shocks Consider a positive supply shock, e t > 0. Inspection of the AS and AD schedules, (7) and (0), reveals that insofar E t y t and E t p t are una ected, these schedules deterine the output and price response directly. As the shock is white noise, we iediately have that E t y t = 0. Moreover, expected future prices will also be una ected be the supply shock. This follows as E t p t = 0 t by (), and because the process for t is independent of the supply shock. It is thus convenient to frae the discussion of the econoy s output and price response in ters of AS and AD schedules in a (y t,p t ) space, and then trace out the noinal interest rate e ects by the IS/LM schedules underlying the AD schedule in a (y t,i t ) space. A 9

graphical representation is provided by Figure. 4 The supply shock oves the AS curve to the right, i.e., fro AS 0 to AS, such that the new equilibriu will be at point A. This involves an increase in output fro y 0 to y and lower prices. This can also be con red by inspection of (24) and (23), respectively. The lower price level will atter for the IS and LM curves. For a given noinal interest rate, a lower price level increases the real oney supply and oves the LM curve to the right, fro LM 0 to LM, which puts downward pressure on the noinal interest rate so as to clear the oney arket. This would be the only e ect of lower prices in a standard IS/LM odel. But in this dynaic odel, a lower price level also plays a role by lowering the real interest rate since expected in ation, E t p t p t, increases. This increases deand, i.e., oves the IS curve fro IS 0 to IS, and puts upward pressure on the noinal interest rate. This expected in ation e ect thus ake the ipact of the shock stronger point C, which corresponds to point A in the AS/AD graph of Figure, involves higher output than point B, which is the intersection point of the IS and LM curves when the IS curve does not ove. A further iplication is that the e ect on the noinal interest rate is abiguous. I will depend on whether the IS- or the LM- e ect is the strongest. When >, the real interest-rate channel is rather weak (the elasticity of interteporal substitution is relatively sall), and the IS curve oves less than the LM curve. This is the case depicted in Figure. In that case, the noinal interest rate will fall when a positive supply shock hits. This can be seen atheatically by inspection of (25); the opposite, of course, holds for <. Note that the oney supply process paraeter, a systeatic part of onetary policyaking in the odel, has no e ect on how the supply shock is transitted. Any change in this paraeter will therefore not in uence output uctuations arising fro supply shocks. The crucial factor behind this result is that E t p t is una ected, when t is. This will be evident, when we turn to the response of the econoy to the shock that does a ect the process for the oney supply, and thereby E t p t, naely s t : 3.2 Monetary policy shocks Consider a positive noinal oney supply shock, s t > 0. In a standard, static IS/LM odel with xed prices, this will increase output and lower the noinal interest rate as the real oney supply is increased. In this odel, the equilibriu response will be di erent 4 In this, and the other gures, it should be noted that the subscripts do not represent periods, but are erely used to distinguish di erent values. 0

as p t is endogenous, and of particular interest in this dynaic context because E t p t is a ected as E t p t = 0 t. I.e., the expected in ation e ect working through the real interest rate will play a crucial role. Is is instructive to split up the analysis up two parts. First, consider the special case of = 0. This case iplies that the oney supply shock will not a ect the next period s oney supply or expected prices. The latter can be con red analytically, as = 0 applies when = 0; cf. (9). With the shock, the LM curve oves to the right. This is depicted in Figure 2 as the ove fro LM 0 to LM. In absence of any e ects on the real interest rate, i.e., any price e ects, this would increase output fro y 0 to y, and the econoy would end in point A. In the associated AS/AD graph, the AD curve would ove fro AD 0 to AD. The increase in aggregate deand will increase output and put upward pressure on prices, and the increase in p t will dapen the increase in the real oney supply oving the LM curve back to LM 2 as well as put upward pressure on the real interest rate oving the IS curve fro IS 0 to IS 2. Both oveents serve to dapen the output increase, and output becoes y 2 (and the associated deand curve is AD 2 ). So, for a given E t p t the e ect of s t > 0 is an increase in output and prices and a fall in the noinal interest rate. The positive ipact on prices, not present in standard IS/LM analysis, dapens the e ect on output partly through the contractive e ects of the associated decrease in expected in ation. Now consider the case of > 0. The shock to noinal oney in period t under consideration then a ects the noinal oney supply in period t positively, and thus period-t prices and the period t expectations of these. Indeed, as > 0 when > 0, E t p t will increase, which exerts upward pressure on expected in ation. The e ect of the shock will therefore we very di erent fro the case of = 0. The case is shown in Figure 3. Point A is the sae point as in Figure 2. I.e., the point where output has increased to y due to the increase in the oney supply for given prices. As in the previous case, this increases deand and puts upward pressure on current prices. This e ect will, as in the case of = 0, reduce the real oney stock and reduce in ation expectations oving both the IS and LM curves inwards. Iportantly, when > 0, expectations about the future feed back and a ect current variables in this rational expectations fraework. And the higher is, the stronger is the current ipact of the expected future prices. Indeed, if is su ciently high, the increase E t p t stiulates deand through the downward pressure on the real interest rate, pushing the IS curve outwards. In Figure 3, the IS curve settles at IS 2 i.e., the expansive e ects of higher E t p t doinates the contractive e ects of higher p t. The

equilibriu will be characterized by point B, with an output level y 2 which is higher than the output response when = 0. Hence, the size of, a systeatic coponent of onetary policy, has iplications for the transission of the shock onto real variables in the odel. Speci cally, a higher iplies that the e ects of the oney-supply shock on output and prices becoe stronger (analytically it is seen fro the coe cients to s t in (24) and (23), which are increasing in ). In addition, the agnitude of expected future price e ects ay be so strong that the associated upward pressure on the noinal interest rate ay doinate the fall in the noinal rate found in conventional static odels. See (25), where it is seen that a high ay turn the coe cient on s t positive. 5 While this odel is erely an exaple of policy e ectiveness under rational expectations, it has generality for the role of stabilization policies in such settings. A shock that persists into the future (either by itself of through a policy response), a ects expectations about future variables, which ay have current e ects. Policy ay then be designed so as to a ect expectations about future variables appropriately. In this odel, for exaple, a policy rule that stabilizes output as uch as possible would be (6) with! ; i.e., any positive oney supply shock should be reversed in the following period. In that case, E t p t would fall, putting upward pressure on the real interest rate, and thus downward pressure on aggregate deand. See (24) where the coe cient on s t is iniized when is a sall as possible (while still retaining stationarity of the oney supply). 4 General policy iplications and discussion of soe early literature The iplication of the previous discussion is that under rational expectations, onetary policy is generally not ine ective. Systeatic coponents of the onetary policy rule do not a ect average output, but it can a ect its variability. This odel is just one exaple of this violation of the policy ine ectiveness proposition. Interestingly, the early and very in uential literature on the policy liitations under rational expectations generally did not acknowledge this at all. Papers like Sargent and Wallace (975), Barro (976), Woglo (979), McCallu (980), Canzoneri et al. (983) were very focused on presenting Lucas-style aggregate supply equations satisfying the natural-rate hypothesis. They therefore sipli ed the speci cation of the deand side such that in their odels, systeatic onetary policy rule paraeters had no in uence 5 When deand is highly real interest-rate elastic, <, this occurs when!. 2

on output deterination. These sipli cations included either an ad hoc de nition of the real interest rate that failed to account for period-t expectations of future prices, or a speci cation of aggregate deand that eliinated any real interest rate e ects by replacing the IS/LM equations by a quantity equation t = p t y t. As evident by this odel, such sipli cations are way too strong when it coes to aking stateents about policy ine ectiveness. Ine ectiveness fails when there are oney supply shocks. Moreover, if the process for the oney supply rule is further aended by, e.g., inclusion of the supply shock and/or proper responses to output, the policy ine ectiveness proposition fails ore generally. In this odel, any policy rule that will a ect price expectations, i.e., E t p t, will a ect the real interest rate and thereby aggregate deand and output in the short run. Sargent (973) odels the real interest rate as a function of expected prices, and his rational-expectations solution derived in the article s appendix reveal upon inspection that policy rule paraeters do a ect output deterination. To the best of y reading, he does not ake coent of that fact. Dotsey and King (983), on the other hand, did note how a feedback policy could a ect future prices and thereby current prices and output volatility. Their odel is a Lucas-style iperfect inforation odel, and the coputation of rational expectations equilibria under di erent feedback policies is coplicated as the coe cients of the odel are functions of the variances of underlying shocks and thus to what extent they are stabilized. They are able to show, however, that a oney supply feedback rule that abstains fro responding to past period s oney supply reduces output variance (in this odel, it would correspond to setting = 0), as does a countercyclical response to past period s output. 6 Groth (997) also deonstrates how a countercyclical oney supply rule stabilizes output. He lets t be a negative function of y t in a odel very siilar to the one of this exercise. This eans that a shock (e.g., a supply shock) that increases output in period t, is expected to be followed by a lower oney stock in period t ; E t p t go down, the real interest rate increases and the expansive e ects of the shock are reduced. So, by appropriate policy design, uctuation due to supply shocks can also be reduced by systeatic onetary policy. The introduction of rational expectations into acroeconoics was by any seen as paving the death for deand-oriented public policies (and still is for soe), as the 6 As they can only deonstrate it for a particular case, they write in their Footnote 2 (p. 370): We do not attach a great deal of iportance to the particular exaple chosen, as it was selected for analytical convenience. 3

policy ine ectiveness proposition was considered central. The upshot of this analysis is, ironically, that it is indeed the rational expectations about future prices that create a scope for policy e ectiveness in an otherwise standard New-Classical odel fraework. References [] Barro, R. J., 976, Rational Expectations and the Roles of Monetary Policy, Journal of Monetary Econoics 85, 32. [2] Canzoneri, M. B., D. W. Henderson, and K. S. Rogo, 983, The Inforation Content of the Interest Rate and Optial Monetary Policy, The Quarterly Journal of Econoics, 546 566. [3] Dotsey, M. and R. G. King, 983, Monetary Instruents and Policy Rules in a Rational Expectations Environent, Journal of Monetary Econoics 2, 357 382. [4] Groth, C., 997, Nyklassisk akroteori. In: C. Groth, L. H. Pedersen and P. B. Sørensen, Noter til Makroøkonoi, Undervisningsnoter nr. 75, Departent of Econoics, University of Copenhagen, 47 94. [5] McCallu, B. T., 980, Rational Expectations and Macroeconoic Stabilization Policy, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 2, 76-746. [6] Sargent, T. J., 973, Rational Expectations, the Real Rate of Interest, and the Natural Rate of Uneployent, Brookings Papers on Econoic Activity 2, 429 472. [7] Sargent, T. J. and N. Wallace, 975, Rational Expectations, the Optial Monetary Policy Instruent, and the Optial Money Supply Rule, Journal of Political Econoy 83, 24 254. [8] Walsh, C. E., 200, Monetary Theory and Policy. Third Edition, The MIT Press. [9] Woglo, G., 979, Rational Expectations and Monetary Policy in a Siple Macroeconoic Model, The Quarterly Journal of Econoics 93, 9 05. 4

Figures Figure : E ects of a positive supply shock, e > 0 5

Figure 2: E ects of a positive oney supply shock, s > 0. The case of = 0. 6

Figure 3: E ects of a positive oney supply shock, s > 0. The case of > 0. 7