KKM type theorems with boundary conditions

Similar documents
arxiv: v1 [math.mg] 28 Dec 2018

A Borsuk-Ulam Equivalent that Directly Implies Sperner's Lemma

ALGORITHMS FOR FINDING CONNECTED SEPARATORS BETWEEN ANTIPODAL POINTS

THE KNASTER KURATOWSKI MAZURKIEWICZ THEOREM AND ALMOST FIXED POINTS. Sehie Park. 1. Introduction

Combinatorial Consequences of Relatives of the Lusternik-Schnirelmann-Borsuk Theorem

REMARKS ON THE SCHAUDER TYCHONOFF FIXED POINT THEOREM

An elementary proof of the Knaster-Kuratowski- Mazurkiewicz-Shapley Theorem*

Brouwer Fixed Point Theorem: A Proof for Economics Students

Combinatorial Integer Labeling Theorems on Finite Sets with Applications

A Z q -Fan theorem. 1 Introduction. Frédéric Meunier December 11, 2006

arxiv: v1 [math.co] 25 Jun 2014

RESEARCH ARTICLE. An extension of the polytope of doubly stochastic matrices

DISCRETIZED CONFIGURATIONS AND PARTIAL PARTITIONS

COINCIDENCE AND THE COLOURING OF MAPS

Analogs of Steiner s porism and Soddy s hexlet in higher dimensions via spherical codes

A Discrete Approach to the Poincare-Miranda Theorem

SOME ELEMENTARY GENERAL PRINCIPLES OF CONVEX ANALYSIS. A. Granas M. Lassonde. 1. Introduction

4 CONNECTED PROJECTIVE-PLANAR GRAPHS ARE HAMILTONIAN. Robin Thomas* Xingxing Yu**

THE POINCARE-HOPF THEOREM

INTRODUCTION TO FINITE ELEMENT METHODS

The Borsuk-Ulam Theorem

SOME EXAMPLES FOR THE FIXED POINT PROPERTY

Fixed Point Theorems 1

KAKUTANI S FIXED POINT THEOREM AND THE MINIMAX THEOREM IN GAME THEORY

Mircea Balaj. Comment.Math.Univ.Carolinae 42,4 (2001)

32 Proof of the orientation theorem

An Algorithm For Super Envy-Free Cake Division

2 Definitions We begin by reviewing the construction and some basic properties of squeezed balls and spheres [5, 7]. For an integer n 1, let [n] denot

arxiv: v1 [math.oc] 21 Mar 2015

Math 530 Lecture Notes. Xi Chen

Cycles in 4-Connected Planar Graphs

Part II. Algebraic Topology. Year

arxiv: v2 [math.co] 15 Jan 2019

FINITE CONNECTED H-SPACES ARE CONTRACTIBLE

The splitting necklace problem

7.3 Singular Homology Groups

ON GENERAL BEST PROXIMITY PAIRS AND EQUILIBRIUM PAIRS IN FREE GENERALIZED GAMES 1. Won Kyu Kim* 1. Introduction

The existence of equilibrium in a simple exchange model

Lecture 1. Toric Varieties: Basics

arxiv: v1 [math.gt] 10 Mar 2009

RON AHARONI, NOGA ALON, AND ELI BERGER

ON INTERSECTION OF SIMPLY CONNECTED SETS IN THE PLANE

On the intersection of infinite matroids

Application of Fixed point Theorem in Game Theory

814 Sehie Park Hoonjoo Kim equilibrium points of n-person games with constraint preference correspondences on non-compact H-spaces. In 1967, motivated

THE JORDAN-BROUWER SEPARATION THEOREM

ON BASIC EMBEDDINGS OF COMPACTA INTO THE PLANE

Perron-Frobenius theorem

Covering the Convex Quadrilaterals of Point Sets

{2, 2}-Extendability of Planar Graphs

On the K-category of 3-manifolds for K a wedge of spheres or projective planes

WORKING PAPER MASSACHUSETTS ALFRED P. SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT CAMBRIDGE, MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY VARIABLE DIMENSION COMPLEXES,

Minimax Inequalities and Related Theorems for Arbitrary Topological Spaces: A Full Characterization

Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne UMR 8174

THE BORSUK-ULAM THEOREM FOR GENERAL SPACES

Some Applications of Fixed Point Theorem in Economics and Nonlinear Functional Analysis

Sharing a pizza: bisecting masses with two cuts

When are Sums Closed?

Math 147, Homework 6 Solutions Due: May 22, 2012

A NOTE ON SPACES OF ASYMPTOTIC DIMENSION ONE

Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences. Sums of sets, etc.

NOTES ON VECTOR-VALUED INTEGRATION MATH 581, SPRING 2017

ALGEBRAICALLY TRIVIAL, BUT TOPOLOGICALLY NON-TRIVIAL MAP. Contents 1. Introduction 1

38 CHAPTER 2. COMPUTATIONAL METHODS. f n. n 1. X n 1. g n. X n

On the Asphericity of One-Point Unions of Cones

The splitting necklace problem

Notes for Functional Analysis

1 Radon, Helly and Carathéodory theorems

Economics Noncooperative Game Theory Lectures 3. October 15, 1997 Lecture 3

Neighborly families of boxes and bipartite coverings

CS675: Convex and Combinatorial Optimization Fall 2014 Combinatorial Problems as Linear Programs. Instructor: Shaddin Dughmi

NOTES FOR MATH 5520, SPRING Outline

Generalized Ham-Sandwich Cuts

Hanna Furmańczyk EQUITABLE COLORING OF GRAPH PRODUCTS

4 Lecture Applications

arxiv: v1 [math.gt] 5 Jul 2012

CONSTRUCTING PIECEWISE LINEAR 2-KNOT COMPLEMENTS

Manifolds and Poincaré duality

ELEMENTS OF THE KKM THEORY ON ABSTRACT CONVEX SPACES

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 7: PPAD and Fixed-Point Theorems

a i,1 a i,j a i,m be vectors with positive entries. The linear programming problem associated to A, b and c is to find all vectors sa b

1 Structures 2. 2 Framework of Riemann surfaces Basic configuration Holomorphic functions... 3

CW-complexes. Stephen A. Mitchell. November 1997

Fixed Point Theorems in Hausdorff Topological Vector Spaces and Economic Equilibrium Theory

BI-LIPSCHITZ GEOMETRY OF WEIGHTED HOMOGENEOUS SURFACE SINGULARITIES

Spanning Paths in Infinite Planar Graphs

TORIC WEAK FANO VARIETIES ASSOCIATED TO BUILDING SETS

A Geometric Approach to Graph Isomorphism

SOME NEW EXAMPLES OF INFINITE IMAGE PARTITION REGULAR MATRICES

Smith theory. Andrew Putman. Abstract

Homotopy and homology groups of the n-dimensional Hawaiian earring

BORSUK-ULAM IMPLIES BROUWER: A DIRECT CONSTRUCTION

A well-quasi-order for tournaments

CO759: Algorithmic Game Theory Spring 2015

Simplicial Homology. Simplicial Homology. Sara Kališnik. January 10, Sara Kališnik January 10, / 34

On the Homological Dimension of Lattices

Notes on Fixed Point Theorems

INERTIA GROUPS AND SMOOTH STRUCTURES OF (n - 1)- CONNECTED 2n-MANIFOLDS. Osaka Journal of Mathematics. 53(2) P.309-P.319

Coxeter Groups and Artin Groups

A PROOF OF A CONVEX-VALUED SELECTION THEOREM WITH THE CODOMAIN OF A FRÉCHET SPACE. Myung-Hyun Cho and Jun-Hui Kim. 1. Introduction

Transcription:

KKM type theorems with boundary conditions Oleg R. Musin arxiv:151.0461v [math.at] 17 Oct 016 Abstract We consider generalizations of Gale s colored KKM lemma and Shapley s KKMS theorem. It is shown that spaces and covers can be much more general and the boundary KKM rules can be substituted by more weaker boundary assumptions. Keywords: Sperner lemma, KKM theorem, KKMS theorem, Gale lemma, rental harmony, degree of mapping, homotopy classes of mappings, partition of unity. 1 Introduction Sperner s lemma [] is a combinatorial analog of the Brouwer fixed point theorem, which is equivalent to it. This lemma and its extension for covers, the KKM (Knaster Kuratowski Mazurkiewicz) theorem [9], have many applications in combinatorics, algorithms, game theory and mathematical economics. There are many extensions of the KKM theorem. In this paper we consider two of them: Gale s lemma [6] and Shapley s KKMS theorem [17]. David Gale in [6] proved an existence theorem for an exchange equilibrium in an economy with indivisible goods and only one perfectly divisible good, which can be thought of as money. The main lemma for this theorem is [6, Lemma, p. 63]. Gale s lemma can be considered as a colored KKM theorem. In [6, p. 63], Gale wrote about his lemma: A colloquial statement of this result is the red, white and blue lemma which asserts that if each of three people paint a triangle red, white and blue according to the KKM rules, then there will be a point which is in the red set of one person, the white set of another, the blue of the third. Note that Bapat [3] found an analog of Gale s lemma for Sperner s lemma. In fact, Gale s lemma (or its discrete analogs) can be applied for fair division problems, namely for the envy free cake cutting and rental harmony problems. In the envy free cake cutting problem, a cake (a heterogeneous divisible resource) has to be divided among n partners with different preferences over parts of the cake [5, 19, 0, 1]. The cake has to be divided into n pieces such that: (a) each partner receives a single connected piece, and (b) This research is partially supported by NSF grant DMS - 1400876. 1

each partner believes that his/her piece is (weakly) better than all other pieces. An algorithm for solving this problem was developed by Forest Simmons in 1980, in a correspondence with Michael Starbird. It was first publicized by Francis Su in 1999 [1]. Suppose a group of friends consider renting a house but they shall first agree on how to allocate its rooms and share the rent. They will rent the house only if they can find a room assignment-rent division which appeals to each of them. Following Su [1], we call such a situation rental harmony. In [1] consideration is given to different aspects of this model. In 1967 Scarf [16] proved that any non-transferable utility game whose characteristic function is balanced, has a non empty core. His proof is based on an algorithm which approximates fixed points. Lloyd Shapley [17] replaced the Scarf algorithm by a covering theorem (the KKMS theorem) being a generalization of the KKM theorem. Now Shapley s KKMS theorem [7, 8, 17, 18] is an important tool in the general equilibrium theory of economic analysis. The main goal of this paper to considere generalizations of Gale s and Shapley s KKMS theorems with general boundary conditions. In our paper [15] with any cover of a space T we associate certain homotopy classes of maps from T to n spheres. These homotopy invariants can then be considered as obstructions for extending covers of a subspace A X to a cover of all of X. We are using these obstructions to obtain generalizations of the KKM and Sperner lemmas. In particular, we show that in the case when A is a k sphere and X is a (k +1) disk there exist KKM type lemmas for covers by n + sets if and only if the homotopy group π k (S n ) 0. In Section is given a review of main results of [15]. In Section 3 we generalize Gale s lemma. In particular, see Corollary 3.1, we pove that if each of n people paint a k simplex with n colors such that the union of these covers is not null-homotopic on the boundary, then there will be a point which is in the first color set of one person, the second color set of another, and so on. In Section 4 we consider KKMS type theorems. Actually, these theorems are analogs for covers of a polytopal type Sperner s lemmas, see [4, 13, 15]. Let V be a set of m points in R n. Then, see Corollary 4.1, if F = {F 1,..., F m } is a cover of a k simplex that is not null homotopic on the boundary, then there is a balanced with respect to V subset B in {1,..., m} such that all the F i, for i B, have a common point. If V is the set of vertices of a k simplex k, then this corollary implies the KKM theorem and if V is the set of all centers of k it yields the KKMS theorem. As an example, we consider a generalization of Tucker s lemma (Corollary 4.3). (Note that David Gale, Lloyd Shapley as well as John F. Nash were Ph.D. students of Albert W. Tucker in Princeton.) Notations. Throughout this paper we consider only normal topological spaces, all simplicial complexes be finite, all manifolds be compact and piecewise linear, I n denotes the set {1,..., n}, n denotes the n dimensional simplex, S n denotes the n dimensional unit sphere, B n denotes the n dimensional unit disk and K denotes the underlying space of a simplicial complex K. We shall denote the set of homotopy classes of continuous maps from X to Y as [X, Y ].

Sperner KKM lemma with boundary conditions The (n 1) dimensional unit simplex n 1 is defined by n 1 := {x R n x i 0, x 1 +... + x n = 1}. Let v i := (x 1,..., x n ) with x i = 1 and x j = 0 for j i. Then v 1,..., v n is the set of vertices of n 1 in R n. Let K be a simplicial complex. Denote by Vert(K) the vertex set of K. An n labeling L is a map L : Vert(K) {1,,..., n}. Setting f L (u) := v k, where u Vert(K) and k = L(u), we have a map f L : Vert(K) R n. Every point p K belongs to the interior of exactly one simplex in K. Letting σ = conv{u 0, u 1,..., u k } be the simplex, we have p = k 0 λ i(p)u i with k 0 λ i(p) = 1 and all λ i > 0. (Actually, λ i (p) are the barycentric coordinates of p.) Then f L can be extended to a continuous (piecewise linear) map f L : K n 1 R n defined by k f L (p) = λ i (p)f L (u i ). i=0 We say that a simplex s in K is fully labeled if s is labeled with a complete set of labels {1,,..., n}. Suppose there are no fully labeled simplices in K. Then f L (p) lies in the boundary of n 1. Since the boundary n 1 is homeomorphic to the sphere S n, we have a continuous map f L : K S n. Denote the homotopy class [f L ] [ K, S n ] by µ(l) = µ(l, K). Example.1. Let L : Vert(K) {1,, 3} be a labelling of a closed planar polygonal line K with vertices p 1 p... p k. Then f L is map from K = S 1 to S 1. Not that µ(l) [S 1, S 1 ] = Z is the degree of the map f L. Moreover, µ(l) = deg(f L ) := p n, where p (respectively, n ) is the number of (ordering) pairs (p i, p i+1 ) such that L(p i ) = 1 and L(p i+1 ) = (respectively, L(p i ) = and L(p i+1 ) = 1). It is clear, that instead of [1, ] we can take [, 3] or [3, 1]. For instance, let L = (11313113131). Then p = 5 and n =. Thus, µ(l) = 5 = 3. Example.. Let K be a triangulation of the boundary of a simplex k+1. In other words, K is a triangulation of of S k ). Let L : Vert(K) {1,..., n} be a labeling such that K has no simplices with n distinct labels. Then f L π k (S n ). 3

In the case k = n we have π k (S k ) = Z and [f L ] = deg(f L ) Z. (Here by deg(f) is denoted the degree of a continuous map f from S k to itself.) For instance, let L be a Sperner labeling of a triangulation K of n 1 = u 1... u n. The rules of this labeling are: (i) The vertices of n 1 are colored with different colors, i. e. L(u i ) = i for 1 i n. (ii) Vertices of K located on any m-dimensional subface of the large simplex u i0 u i1... u im are colored only with the colors i 0, i 1,..., i m. Then µ(l) = deg(f L ) = 1 in [S n, S n ] = Z. In [15] we proved the following theorem, see [15, Corollary 3.1]. Theorem.1. Let T be a triangulation of a simplex k+1. Let L : Vert(T ) {1,..., n} be a labeling such that T has no simplices on the boundary with n distinct labels. If µ(l, T ) 0, then T must contain a fully labeled simplex. (Here by µ(l, T ) we denote the invariant µ on the boundary of T.) Since for a Sperner labeling µ(l, T ) = 1 0, Theorem.1 implies: (Sperner s lemma []) Every Sperner labeling of a triangulation of n 1 contains a cell labeled with a complete set of labels: {1,,..., n}. Consider an oriented manifold M of dimension (n 1) with boundary. Then [ M, S n ] = Z and for any continuous f : M S n we have [f] = deg f. If T is a triangulation of M and L : Vert(T ) {1,..., n} is a labeling then we denote by deg(l, T ) the class µ(l, T ). Theorem.. [15, Theorem 3.4] Let T be a triangulation of an oriented manifold M of dimension (n 1) with boundary. Then for a labeling L : Vert(T ) {1,..., n} the triangulation must contain at least deg(l, T ) fully labelled simplices. In Fig.1 is shown an illustration of Theorem.. We have a labeling with deg(l, T ) = 3. Therefore, the theorem garantee that there are at least three fully labeled triangles. Actually, a labeling can be considered as a particular case of a covering. For any labeling L there is a natural open cover of K. The open star of a vertex u Vert(K) (denoted St(u)) is S \ B, where S is the set of all simplices in K that contain u, and B is the set of all simplices in S that contain no u. Let where U l (K) := U L (K) = {U 1 (K),..., U n (K)}, u W l St(u), W l := {u Vert(K) : L(u) = l}. It is clear, that K = U 1 (K)... U n (K), i. e. U L (K) is a cover of K. 4

1 3 3 1 3 1 3 3 Figure 1: deg(l, T ) = 3. There are three fully labeled triangles. Now we extend the definition of µ(l) for covers. Let U = {U 1,..., U n } be a collection of open sets whose union contains a space T. In other words, U is a cover of T. Let Φ = {ϕ 1,..., ϕ n } be a partition of unity subordinate to U, i. e. Φ is a collection of non negative functions on T such that supp(ϕ i ) U i, i = 1,..., n, and for all x T, n 1 ϕ i(x) = 1. Let f U,Φ (x) := n ϕ i (x)v i, where v 1,..., v n, as above, are vertices of n 1. Suppose the intersection of all U i is empty. Then f U,Φ is a continuous map from T to S n. In [15, Lemmas.1 and.] we proved that a homotopy class [f U,Φ ] in [T, S n ] does not depend on Φ. We denote it by µ(u). Note that for a labeling L : Vert(K) {1,,..., n} we have µ(l) = µ(u L (K)) [ K, S n ]. Example.3. (a) Let T = S k and U = {U 1,..., U n } be an open cover of T = S k such that the intersection of all U i is empty. Then µ(u) π k (S n ). In the case k = n we have µ(u) = deg(f U ) Z. (b) Let h : S k S n be any continuous map. Actually, S n can be considered as the boundary of the simplex n 1. Let Then µ(u) = [h] π k (S m 1 ). U i := h 1 (U i ( n 1 ), i = 1,..., n U = {U 1,..., U n }. 5

For instance, if h : S 3 S is the Hopf fibration, then µ(u) = 1 π 3 (S ) = Z. In fact, see [15, Lemma.4], the homotopy classes of covers are also well defined for closed sets. Definition.1. We call a family of sets S = {S 1,..., S n } as a cover of a space T if S is either an open or closed cover of T. Definition.. Let S = {S 1,..., S n } be a cover of a space T. We say that S is not null homotopic if the intersection of all S i is empty and µ(s) 0 in [T, S n ]. Note that covers in Examples.1,. and.3 are not null homotopic. Actually, these examples and [15, Theorems.1.3] imply the following theorem. Theorem.3. Let S = {S 1,..., S m } be a cover of a space T. Suppose the intersection of all S i is empty. 1. Let T be S k. Then S is not null homotopic if and only if π k (S n 1 ) is not trivial and µ(s) 0 in this group.. Let T be an oriented (n ) dimensional manifold. Then S is not null homotopic if and only if deg(f S ) 0. Now we consider a generalization of the KKM theorem for covers of spaces. Definition.3. Consider a pair (X, A), where A is a subspace of a space X. Let S = {S 1,..., S m } be a cover of X and C = {C 1,..., C m } be a cover of A. We say that S is an extension of C and write C = S A if C i = S i A for all i. Definition.4. We say that a pair of spaces (X, A), where A X, belongs to EP n and write (X, A) EP n if there is a continuous map f : A S n with [f] 0 in [A, S n ] that cannot be extended to a continuous map F : X S n with F A = f. We denoted this class of pairs by EP after S. Eilenberg and L. S. Pontryagin who initiated obstruction theory in the late 1930s. Note that [15, Theorem.3] yield that (i) if π k (S n ) 0, then (B k+1, S k ) EP n, (ii) if X is an oriented (n + 1) dimensional manifold and A = X, then (X, A) EP n. Theorem.4. Let A be a subspace of a space X. Let (X, A) EP n. Let S = {S 1,..., S n } be a cover of (X, A). Suppose the cover S is not null homotopic on A. Then all the S i have a common intersection point. Corollary.1. Let S = {S 1,..., S n } be a cover of B k. Suppose S is not null homotopic on the boundary of B k. Then all the S i have a common intersection point. Corollary.. Let S = {S 1,..., S n } be a cover of a manifold M of dimension (n 1) with boundary. Let C := S M. Suppose deg f C 0. Then all the S i have a common intersection point. 6

We say that a cover S := {S 1,..., S m } of a simplex m 1 is a KKM cover if for all J I m the face of m 1 that is spanned by vertices v i for i J is covered by S i for i J. Let C := S n 1. Note that if all the C i have no a common intersection point, then the KKM assumption implies that µ(c) = deg(f C ) = 1. Thus, Corollary. yields Corollary.3. (KKM theorem [9]) If S := {S 1,..., S n } is a KKM cover of n 1, then all the S i have a common intersection point. 3 Gale s lemma with boundary conditions David Gale [6, Lemma, p. 63] proved the following lemma: For i, j = 1,,..., n let Sj i be closed sets such that for each i, {S1, i..., Sn} i is a KKM covering of n 1. Then there exists a permutation π of 1,,..., n such that n Sπ(i) i. Now we generalize this lemma for pairs of spaces. Theorem 3.1. Let A be a subspace of a space X. Let (X, A) EP n. Let S i = {S1, i..., Sn}, i i = 1,..., n, be covers of (X, A). Let n F j := Sj, i F := {F 1,..., F n }, C := F A. Suppose C is not null homotopic. Then there exists a permutation π of 1,,..., n such that n Sπ(i) i. Proof. Here we use Gale s proof of his lemma. We consider the case where the sets S i j are open. As above the proof of the closed case then follows by a routine limiting argument. Now for each cover S i consider the corresponding partition of unity {ϕ i 1,..., ϕ i n}. Define Φ i : X n 1 and Φ : X n 1 by Φ i (p) := (ϕ i 1(p),..., ϕ i n(p)), Φ(p) := Φ1 (p) +... + Φ n (p), n where n 1 = {(x 1,..., x n ) R n x i 0, i = 1,..., n, x 1 +... + x n = 1}. Since C is not null homotopic, Φ is a map from A to n 1 S n and Φ(X) = n 1. Therefore, there is p X such that Φ(p) = (1/n,..., 1/n), so nφ(p) = (1,..., 1). Thus, the matrix M := nφ(p) = ( ϕ i j(p) ) is a doubly stochastic matrix, is a square matrix of nonnegative real numbers, each of whose rows and columns sums to 1. By Mirsky s lemma [11] for any doubly stochastic matrix M it is a possible to find a permutation π such that ϕ i π(i) (p) > 0 for all i, but this means precisely that p Sπ(i) i. 7

Remark.. This proof is constructive. If p Φ 1 (1/n,..., 1/n), then there is a permutation π with ϕ i π(i) (p) > 0, i.e. the intersection of all the Si π(i), i = 1,..., n, is not empty. Theorem 3.1 and [15, Theorem.3] imply the following corollaries. Corollary 3.1. Let S i = {S i 1,..., S i n}, i = 1,..., n, be covers of S k. Let F j is the union of S i j, i = 1,..., n, and F := {F 1,..., F n }. Suppose F is not null homotopic on the boundary of S k. Then there exists a permutation π of 1,,..., n such that n Sπ(i) i. Corollary 3.. Let S i = {S i 1,..., S i n}, i = 1,..., n, be covers of a manifold M of dimension (n 1) with boundary. Let F j is the union of S i j, i = 1,..., n, F := {F 1,..., F n }, and C := F M. Suppose deg C 0. Then there exists a permutation π of 1,,..., n such that n Sπ(i) i. Now consider the rental harmony problem. Following Su [1], suppose there are n housemates, and n rooms to assign, numbered 1,..., n. Let x i denote the price of the i th room, and suppose that the total rent is 1. Then x 1 +... + x n = 1 and x i 0. From this we see that the set of all pricing schemes forms a simplex n 1. Denote by S i j a set of price vectors p in n 1 such that housemate i likes room j at these prices. Consider the following conditions: (C1) In any partition of the rent, each person finds some room acceptable. In other words, S i = {S i 1,..., S i n}, i = 1,..., n, is a (closed or open) cover of n 1. (C) Each person always prefers a free room (one that costs no rent) to a non free room. In other words, for all i and j, S i j contains n 1 j := {(x 1,..., x n ) n 1 x j = 0}. In fact, (C) is the dual boundary KKM condition. Su [1, Sect. 7] using the dual simplex and dual Sperner lemma proves that there exists a permutation π of 1,,..., n, such that the intersection of the Sπ(i) i, i = 1,..., n, is not empty. It proves the rental harmony theorem. Also, this theorem can be derived from Corollary 3.. Rental Harmony Theorem [1]. Suppose n housemates in an n bedroom house seek to decide who gets which room and for what part of the total rent. Also, suppose that the conditions (C1) and (C) hold. Then there exists a partition of the rent so that each person prefers a different room. Let us consider an extension of this theorem. Suppose there are some constraints f i (p) 0, i = 1,..., n, for price vectors. Let M := {p n 1 f 1 (p) 0,..., f k (p) 0} be a manifold of dimension n 1. Let S i j be sets of price vectors p in M such that housemate i likes room j at these prices. Consider the following conditions: 8

(A1) S i = {S i 1,..., S i n}, i = 1,..., n, is a cover of M. (A) deg C 0, where C := F M, F := {F 1,..., F n }, and F j := n Si j. The following theorem is equivalent to Corollary 3.. Theorem 3.. Suppose n housemates in an n bedroom house seek to decide who gets which room and for what part of the total rent. Also, suppose that the conditions (A1) and (A) hold. Then there exists a partition of the rent so that each person prefers a different room. 4 KKMS type theorems with boundary conditions Let us extend definitions from Section for any set of points (vectors) V := {v 1,..., v m } in R n. Denote by c V the center of mass of V, c V := (v 1 +... + v m )/m. Let U = {U 1,..., U m } be an open cover of a space T and Φ = {ϕ 1,..., ϕ m } be a partition of unity subordinate to U. Let ρ U,Φ,V (x) := m ϕ i (x)v i. Suppose c V lies outside of the image ρ U,Φ,V (T ) in R n. Let for all x T f U,Φ,V (x) := ρ U,Φ,V (x) c V ρ U,Φ,V (x) c V. Then f U,Φ,V is a continuous map from T to S n 1. In [15, Lemmas.1 and.] we proved that the homotopy class [f U,Φ,V ] [T, S n 1 ] does not depend on Φ and then the homotopy class [f U,V ] in [T, S n 1 ] is well define. Notation 4.1: Denote the homotopy class [f U,V ] in [T, S n 1 ] by µ(u, V ). Note that for the case V = Vert( n ) we have µ(u, V ) = µ(u). In [15, Lemma.4] we show that this invariant is well defined also for closed covers. As above we call a family of sets S = {S 1,..., S m } as a cover of a space T if S is either an open or closed cover of T. Definition 4.1. Let I be a set of labels of cardinality m. Let V := {v i, i I}, be a set of points in R n. Then a nonempty subset B I is said to be balanced with respect to V if for all i B there exist non-negative λ i such that λ i v i = c V, where λ i = 1 and c V := 1 v i. m i B i B i I In other words, c V conv{v i, i B}, where conv(y ) denote the convex hull of Y in R n. 9

First we consider an extension of Theorems.4. Theorem 4.1. Let V := {v 1,..., v m } be a set of points in R n. Let A be a subspace of a space X. Let (X, A) EP n 1. Let F = {F 1,..., F m } be a cover of (X, A). Suppose S := F A is not null homotopic. Then there is a balanced subset B in I m with respect to V such that F i. i B Proof. Assume the converse. Then there are no balanced subsets B in I m such that {F i, i B} have a common point. It implies that c V / ρ F,V (X) and therefore, f F,V : X S n 1 is well defined. On the other side, it is an extension of the map f S,V : A S n 1 with [f S,V ] 0, a contradiction. Remark. The assumption: c V ρ S,V (A) in R n is equivalent to the assumption: there is a balanced B in I m with respect to V such that the intersection of all S i, i B, is not empty. Thus, if c V ρ S,V (A) or c V / ρ S,V (A) and µ(s, V ) 0, then the intersection of the F i, i B, is not empty. Theorem 4.1 and [15, Theorem.3] imply the following extension of Corollary.1. Corollary 4.1. Let V := {v 1,..., v m } be a set of points in R n. Let F = {F 1,..., F m } be a cover of B k that is not null homotopic on the boundary. Then there is a balanced with respect to V subset B in I m := {1,..., m} such that the intersection of all F i, i B, is not empty. If V = Vert( n ), then this corollary implies the KKM theorem. It is also implies the KKMS theorem. Corollary 4.. (KKMS theorem [17]) Let K be the collection of all non-empty subsets of I k+1. Consider a simplex S in R k with vertices x 1,..., x k+1. Let V := {v σ, σ K} R k, where v σ denotes the center of mass of S σ := {x i, i σ}. Let C := {C σ, σ K} be a cover of k such that for every J I k+1 the simplex J that is spanned by vertices from J is covered by {C σ, σ J}. Then there exists a balanced collection B in K with respect to V such that C σ. σ B Proof. The assumptions of the corollary imply that µ(c, V ) = deg(f C,V ) = 1. Thus, Corollary 4.1 yields the corollary. There are many extensions of the Sperner and KKM lemmas, in particular, that are Tucker s and Ky Fan s lemmas [, 4, 1, 13, 14, 15]. Actually, these lemmas can be derived from Theorem 4.1 using certain sets V. Let us consider as an example a generalization of Tucker s lemma. 10

Corollary 4.3. Let V := {±e 1,..., ±e n }, where e 1,..., e n is a basis in R n. Let F = {F 1, F 1..., F n, F n } be a cover of B k that is not null homotopic on the boundary. Then there is i such that the intersection of F i and F i is not empty. In particular, if F is antipodally symmetric on the boundary of B k, i. e. for all i we have S i = S i, where S j := F j S k 1, then there is i such that F i F i. Proof. Note that any balanced subset with respect to V consists of pairs (i, i), i = 1,..., n. It yields the first part of the theorem. By assumption, S is antipodally symmetric on S k 1. Then ρ S,V : S k 1 R n is an odd (antipodal) map. If k > n, then the Borsuk Ulam theorem implies there x S k 1 such that ρ S,V (x) = 0. Therefore, there is i such that S i S i. If for all i we have S i S i =, then k n. Then the odd mapping theorem (see [14]) implies that k = n and deg(f S,V ) is odd. Thus, µ(s, V ) 0 and from Theorem 4.1 follows the second part of the corollary. Definition 4.. Let V := {v 1,..., v m } be a set of points in R n. Let T be a triangulation of an n-dimensional manifold M. Let L : Vert(T ) I m be a labeling. We say that a simplex s T is BL (Balanced Labelled) if the set of labels L(s) := {L(v), v Vert(s)} is balanced with respect to V [15, Theorems 3.3 and 3.5] yield the following theorem. Theorem 4.. Let V := {v 1,..., v m } be a set of points in R n. Let T be a triangulation of an oriented manifold M of dimension n with boundary. Let L : Vert(T ) {1,,..., m} be a labeling such that T has no BL simplices on the boundary. Then T must contain at least deg(l, T ) distinct (internal) BL simplices. Corollary 4.4. Let T be a triangulation of a compact oriented PL manifold M of dimension (m 1) with boundary. Then for any labeling L : Vert(T ) {1,,..., m} the triangulation T must contain at least deg(l, T ) fully colored (m 1) simplices. Proof. Let V := {v 1,..., v m } be the set of vertices of an (m 1) simplex in R m 1. Then I m is the only balanced subset in I m with respect to V. Thus, Theorem 4. yields the corollary. Corollary 4.5. Let T be a triangulation of B n that antipodally symmetric on the boundary. Let L : Vert(T ) {+1, 1,..., +n, n} be a labelling that is antipodal on the boundary. Suppose there are no complementary edges on the boundary. Then deg(l, T ) is an odd integer and there are at least deg(l, T ) internal complementary edges. (An edge in T is called complementary if its two vertices are labelled by opposite numbers.) Proof. Let V := {±e 1,..., ±e n }, where e 1,..., e n is an orthonormal basis in R n. Then any balanced subset with respect to V consists of pairs (i, i), i = 1,..., n. The fact that deg(l, T ) is odd follows from the odd mapping theorem, see [1]. Thus, Theorem 4. completes the proof. In Fig. is shown a labeling with deg(l, T ) = 3. Then Corollary 4.5 yield that there are at least three complimentary edges. 11

1 1 1 1 1 1 References Figure : Since deg(l, T ) = 3, there are three complementary edges. [1] Y. Azrieli and E. Shmaya, Rental harmony with roommates, Journal of Mathematical Economics, 46 (014), 303 310. [] P. Bacon, Equivalent formulations of the Borsuk-Ulam theorem, Canad. J. Math., 18 (1966), 49 50. [3] R. B. Bapat, A constructive proof of a permutation based generalization of Sperner s lemma, Mathematical Programming, 44 (1989), 113 10. [4] J. A. De Loera, E. Peterson, and F. E. Su, A Polytopal Generalization of Sperner s Lemma, J. of Combin. Theory Ser. A, 100 (00), 1 6. [5] L. E. Dubins and E. H. Spanier, How to cut a cake fairly, Amer. Math. Monthly, 68 (1961), 1 17. [6] D. Gale, Equilibrium in a discrete exchange economy with money, International Journal of Game Theory, 13 (1984), 61 64. [7] P. J. J. Herings, An extremely simple proof of the K K M S theorem, Economic Theory, 10 (1997), 361 367. [8] H. Komiya, A simple proof of the K K M S theorem, Economic Theory, 4 (1994), 463 466. [9] B. Knaster, C. Kuratowski, S. Mazurkiewicz, Ein Beweis des Fixpunktsatzes für n dimensionale Simplexe, Fundamenta Mathematicae 14 (199): 13 137. [10] K. Fan, A generalization of Tucker s combinatorial lemma with topological applications. Ann. of Math., 56 (195), 431 437. 1

[11] L. Mirsky, Proofs of two theorems on doubly stochastic matrices, Proc. Amer. Math. Soc., 9 (1958), 371 374. [1] O. R. Musin, Borsuk-Ulam type theorems for manifolds, Proc. Amer. Math. Soc. 140 (01), 551 560. [13] O. R. Musin, Extensions of Sperner and Tucker s lemma for manifolds, J. of Combin. Theory Ser. A, 13 (015), 17 187. [14] O. R. Musin, Generalizations of Tucker Fan Shashkin lemmas, Arnold Math. J., :3 (016), 99 308. [15] O. R. Musin, Homotopy invariants of covers and KKM type lemmas, Algebr. Geom. Topol., 16 (016), 1799 181. [16] H. Scarf. The core of an n-person game, Econometria, 35 (1967), 50 69. [17] L. S. Shapley On balanced games without side payments, in Mathematical Programming, Hu, T.C. and S.M. Robinson (eds), Academic Press, New York, 61 90, 1973. [18] L. S. Shapley and R. Vohra, On Kakutani s fixed point theorem, the KKMS theorem and the core of a balanced game, Economic Theory, 1 (1991), 108 116. [19] H. Steinhaus, Sur las division pragmatique, Econometrica 17 (1949), 315 319. [0] W. Stromquist, How to cut a cake fairly, Amer. Math. Monthly, 87 (1980), 640 644. [1] F. E. Su, Rental harmony: Sperner s lemma in fair division, Amer. Math. Monthly, 106 (1999), 930 94. [] E. Sperner, Neuer Beweis für die Invarianz der Dimensionszahl und des Gebietes, Abh. Math. Sem. Univ. Hamburg 6 (198), 65 7. O. R. Musin University of Texas Rio Grande Valley, One West University Boulevard, Brownsville, TX, 7850 E-mail address: oleg.musin@utrgv.edu 13