The Utility Frontier

Similar documents
Notes IV General Equilibrium and Welfare Properties

Pareto Efficiency (also called Pareto Optimality)

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Notes I Classical Demand Theory: Review of Important Concepts

Economics 101 Lecture 5 - Firms and Production

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions

Adding Production to the Theory

Week 7: The Consumer (Malinvaud, Chapter 2 and 4) / Consumer November Theory 1, 2015 (Jehle and 1 / Reny, 32

Second Welfare Theorem

Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3

u(x, y) = x 1 3 y v(p, q, I) = u(x(p, q, I), y(p, q, I))

Microeconomic Theory-I Washington State University Midterm Exam #1 - Answer key. Fall 2016

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

An Application to Growth Theory

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

Lecture Notes for January 8, 2009; part 2

Midterm Exam, Econ 210A, Fall 2008

The Envelope Theorem

Vector Spaces. Addition : R n R n R n Scalar multiplication : R R n R n.

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis Solutions to Midterm Exam

The Debreu-Scarf Theorem: The Core Converges to the Walrasian Allocations

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Recitation #2 (August 31st, 2018)


Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Problem Set 1 Welfare Economics

Market Failure: Externalities

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

ECONOMICS 001 Microeconomic Theory Summer Mid-semester Exam 2. There are two questions. Answer both. Marks are given in parentheses.

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

On the (Non-)Differentiability of the Optimal Value Function When the Optimal Solution Is Unique

Maximum Value Functions and the Envelope Theorem

Lakehead University ECON 4117/5111 Mathematical Economics Fall 2002

Lecture 1. History of general equilibrium theory

Math Review ECON 300: Spring 2014 Benjamin A. Jones MATH/CALCULUS REVIEW

Solving Dual Problems

Existence, Computation, and Applications of Equilibrium

PS4-Solution. Mehrdad Esfahani. Fall Arizona State University. Question 1 Question 2 Question 3 Question 4 Question 5

Alp Simsek (MIT) Recitation Notes: 1. Gorman s Aggregation Th eorem2. Normative Representative November 9, Household Theorem / 16

Chapter 6: Rational Expr., Eq., and Functions Lecture notes Math 1010

E 600 Chapter 4: Optimization

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

i) This is simply an application of Berge s Maximum Theorem, but it is actually not too difficult to prove the result directly.

Additional questions for Chapter 1 - solutions: 1. See Varian, p.20. Notice that Varian set a1=a2. 2. See Varian, p.20.

Solutions. F x = 2x 3λ = 0 F y = 2y 5λ = 0. λ = 2x 3 = 2y 5 = x = 3y 5. 2y 1/3 z 1/6 x 1/2 = 5x1/2 z 1/6. 3y 2/3 = 10x1/2 y 1/3

Lecture Notes October 18, Reading assignment for this lecture: Syllabus, section I.

Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais

1 + x 1/2. b) For what values of k is g a quasi-concave function? For what values of k is g a concave function? Explain your answers.

Constrained optimization.

Comparative Statics. Autumn 2018

Generalized Convexity in Economics

; p. p y p y p y. Production Set: We have 2 constraints on production - demand for each factor of production must be less than its endowment

Economics 200A part 2 UCSD Fall quarter 2011 Prof. R. Starr Mr. Troy Kravitz1 FINAL EXAMINATION SUGGESTED ANSWERS

Consumer theory Topics in consumer theory. Microeconomics. Joana Pais. Fall Joana Pais

Public Economics Ben Heijdra Chapter 9: Introduction to Normative Public Economics

Economics 101. Lecture 7 - Monopoly and Oligopoly

Multi Variable Calculus

Separation of variables

Competitive Equilibrium

Tvestlanka Karagyozova University of Connecticut

PhD Qualifier Examination

Solutions. ams 11b Study Guide 9 econ 11b

Lecture 4: Optimization. Maximizing a function of a single variable

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

First Welfare Theorem

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Slides to accompany 13. Markets and Efficient Risk-Bearing: Examples and Extensions

Chapter 4. Maximum Theorem, Implicit Function Theorem and Envelope Theorem

Utility Maximization Problem

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016

Last Revised: :19: (Fri, 12 Jan 2007)(Revision:

Final Exam - Math Camp August 27, 2014

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2

The Walrasian Model and Walrasian Equilibrium

Introduction to General Equilibrium

Problem Set #06- Answer key First CompStat Problem Set

Optimization, constrained optimization and applications of integrals.

ANSWER KEY. University of California, Davis Date: June 22, 2015

Economics 401 Sample questions 2

Self-test for applicants M.Sc. Economics

Fixed Point Theorems

General Equilibrium with Production

Market Equilibrium and the Core

Advanced Microeconomics

MS&E 246: Lecture 18 Network routing. Ramesh Johari

5.1 - Polynomials. Ex: Let k(x) = x 2 +2x+1. Find (and completely simplify) the following: (a) k(1) (b) k( 2) (c) k(a)

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Answers Econ 805

1 Theory of the Firm: Topics and Exercises

Equilibrium in Factors Market: Properties

Dynamic stochastic game and macroeconomic equilibrium

Advanced Microeconomics

a = (a 1; :::a i )

Question 1. (p p) (x(p, w ) x(p, w)) 0. with strict inequality if x(p, w) x(p, w ).

Transcription:

The Utility Frontier Any allocation (x i ) n 1 to a set N = {1,..., n} of individuals with utility functions u 1 ( ),..., u n ( ) yields a profile (u 1,..., u n ) of resulting utility levels, as depicted in Figure 1 for the case n = 2. (Throughout this set of notes, in order to distinguish between utility functions and utility levels, I ll use superscripts for the functions and subscripts for the resulting levels, as I ve done in the preceding sentence and in Figure 1.) Let s formally define the function that accomplishes this: U : R nl + R n is defined by U ( (x i ) N ) = ( u 1 (x 1 ),..., u n (x n ) ) ( ) Figure 1 Let F denote the set of feasible allocations i.e., those that satisfy n 1 xi x. The set of feasible utility profiles is the image under U of the set of all feasible allocations, i.e., U(F): Figure 2

The Pareto efficient allocations are clearly the ones that get mapped by U to the northeast part of the boundary of the set of feasible utility profiles. (More accurately, to those points u on the boundary of U(F) for which there are no other points in U(F) lying to the northeast). This northeast part of the set U(F) is called the utility frontier, which we ll denote by UF. It consists of the utility profiles u = (u 1,..., u n ) that are maximal in U(F) with respect to the preorder on R n : u = (u 1,..., u n ) UF if and only if u U(F) and there is no u U(F) that satisfies i : u i u i & i : u i > u i. Equivalently, UF is the image under U of the set of Pareto allocations: UF = U(P), where P is the set of Pareto allocations in R nl +. Figure 3 Note that the alternatives over which the individuals have utility functions needn t be allocations: we could replace the set R nl + of allocations with an arbitrary set X of alternatives x, and ( ) would become U : X R n is defined by U(x) = ( u 1 (x),..., u n (x) ) Figure 2 would still look the same: it would be U(X), or U(F), the image under U of either X or F; and Figure 3 would be the same, the image under U of the set of Pareto efficient alternatives. The utility frontier is a surface in R n, and it could be expressed as the set of profiles (u 1,..., u n ) that satisfy the equation h(u 1,..., u n ) = 0 for some function h, or u 1 = g(u 2,..., u n ) ( ) for some function g. In the equation ( ), the function g tells us, for given utility levels u 2,..., u n for n 1 individuals, what is the maximum utility level u 1 that s feasible for the remaining individual. In other words, g is the value function for the problem (P-Max), in which the utility 2

levels u 2,..., u n are parameters and we solve for the allocation (x i ) n 1 in which x 1 maximizes u 1 ( ) subject to all other individuals i = 2,..., n receiving at least the utility level u i (recall that we re using u i to denote utility functions and u i to denote utility levels!): max (x i k ) Rnl + u 1 (x 1 ) subject to x i k 0, i = 1,..., n, k = 1,..., l n x i k x k, k = 1,..., l i=1 u i (x i ) u i, i = 2,..., n. (P-Max) The Solution Function and the Value Function for a Maximization Problem Consider the maximization problem max f(x; α) subject to G(x; α) 0. x (P) Note that we re maximizing over x and not over α x is a variable in the problem (typically a vector or n-tuple of variables) and α is a parameter (typically a vector or m-tuple of parameters). The parameters may appear in the objective function and/or the constraints, if there are any constraints. We associate the following two functions with the maximization problem (P): the solution function: x = x(α), and the value function: v(α) := f(x(α)). The solution function gives the solution x as a function of the parameters; the value function gives the value of the objective function as a function of the parameters. Example 1: The consumer maximization problem (CMP) in demand theory, max u(x) subject to p x w. x R l + Here α is the (l + 1)-tuple (p; w) consisting of the price-list p and the consumer s wealth w. The solution function is the consumer s demand function x(p; w). The value function is the consumer s indirect utility function v(p; w) = u(x(p; w)). 3

Example 2: The firm s cost-minimization (i.e., expenditure-minimization) problem, min E(x; w) = w x subject to F (x) y. x R l + Here F is the firm s production function; x is the l-tuple of input levels that will be employed; E(x; w) is the resulting expenditure the firm will incur; and α is the (l + 1)-tuple (y; w) consisting of the proposed level of output, y, and the l-tuple w of input prices. The solution function is the firm s input demand function x(y; w). The value function is the firm s cost function C(y; w) = E(x(y; w); w). Example 3: The Pareto problem (P-Max), max x F u1 (x 1 ) subject to u 2 (x 2 ) u 2,..., u n (x n ) u n, where F is the feasible set {x R nl + n 1 xi x}. Here α is the (n 1)-tuple of utility levels u 2,..., u n. The solution function is x(u 2,..., u n ), which gives the Pareto allocation as a function of the utility levels u 2,..., u n. The value function is u 1 (x(u 2,..., u n )), which gives the maximum attainable utility level u 1 as a function of the utility levels u 2,..., u n. The value function therefore describes the utility frontier for the economy ((u i ) n 1, x), as depicted in Figure 2. 4