Inflation traps, and rules vs. discretion

Similar documents
14.05 Lecture Notes Crises and Multiple Equilibria

Lecture 9: Stabilization policy with rational expecations; Limits to stabilization policy; closed economy case.

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Monetary Economics. Lecture 15: unemployment in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

Two Models of Macroeconomic Equilibrium

Queen s University Department of Economics Instructor: Kevin Andrew

Stabilization policy with rational expectations. IAM ch 21.

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1 Solutions. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Lars Svensson 2/16/06. Y t = Y. (1) Assume exogenous constant government consumption (determined by government), G t = G<Y. (2)

The Neo Fisher Effect and Exiting a Liquidity Trap

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1. Problem I An AD-AS Model

004: Macroeconomic Theory

The Time Consistency Problem - Theory and Applications

Internation1al Trade

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory)

Forward Guidance without Common Knowledge

Topic 9. Monetary policy. Notes.

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Aspects of Stickiness in Understanding Inflation

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Y t = log (employment t )

INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT: THE PHILLIPS CURVE. Dongpeng Liu Department of Economics Nanjing University

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Endogenous Information Choice

A Dynamic Model of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Eco504, Part II Spring 2008 C. Sims POLICY GAMES

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics

POLICY GAMES. u t = θ 0 θ 1 π t + ε t. (1) β t (u 2 t + ωπ 2 t ). (3)

POLICY GAMES. u t = θ 0 θ 1 π t + ε t. (1) β t (u 2 t + ωπ 2 t ). (3) π t = g t 1 + ν t. (4) g t = θ 1θ 0 ω + θ 2 1. (5)

MA Macroeconomics 4. Analysing the IS-MP-PC Model

MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case.

Demand Shocks, Monetary Policy, and the Optimal Use of Dispersed Information

Macroeconomics Theory II

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Neoclassical Growth Model: I

The transmission mechanism How the monetary-policy instrument affects the economy and the target variables

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Macroeconomics Theory II

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

Monetary Policy in a Macro Model

Strategic Interactions between Fiscal and Monetary Policies in a Monetary Union

RBC Model with Indivisible Labor. Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

GCOE Discussion Paper Series

Lecture Notes Morris-Shin and Global Games

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I

Eco 200, part 3, Fall 2004 Lars Svensson 12/6/04. Liquidity traps, the zero lower bound for interest rates, and deflation

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory)

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

The Lucas Imperfect Information Model

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Socially Optimal Coordination: Characterization and Policy Implications

Problem 1 (30 points)

Lars Svensson 10/2/05. Liquidity traps, the zero lower bound for interest rates, and deflation

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

Discussion of Contagious Malady? Global Dimensions of Secular Stagnation

Economics II. Labor Market, Unemployment and the Phillips Curve, Part II

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

The Basic New Keynesian Model, the Labor Market and Sticky Wages

Adverse Effects of Monetary Policy Signalling

Fiscal Rules, Bailouts, and Reputation in Federal Governments

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Discussion Global Dynamics at the Zero Lower Bound

New Keynesian Macroeconomics

Recursive Methods Recursive Methods Nr. 1

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change

What Happened to the Phillips Curve in the 1990s in Canada?

LECTURE 3 The Effects of Monetary Changes: Statistical Identification. September 5, 2018

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Volatility in a Small Open Economy. Jordi Galí and Tommaso Monacelli. March 2005

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics

Supplementary Materials for. Forecast Dispersion in Finite-Player Forecasting Games. March 10, 2017

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

Equilibrium in Factors Market: Properties

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

THE CASE OF THE DISAPPEARING PHILLIPS CURVE

Recession Aversion, Output and the Kydland-Prescott Barro-Gordon Model

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SENTIMENTS AND AGGREGATE DEMAND FLUCTUATIONS. Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen

Comments on A Model of Secular Stagnation by Gauti Eggertsson and Neil Mehrotra

THE CASE OF THE DISAPPEARING PHILLIPS CURVE

Module 16: Signaling

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

International Trade Lecture 9: Factor Proportion Theory (II)

Forward Guidance without Common Knowledge

Lessons of the long quiet ELB

Wage and price setting. Slides for 26. August 2003 lecture

The Natural Rate of Interest and its Usefulness for Monetary Policy

SGZ Macro Week 3, Lecture 2: Suboptimal Equilibria. SGZ 2008 Macro Week 3, Day 1 Lecture 2

Expectations, Learning and Macroeconomic Policy

Transcription:

14.05 Lecture Notes Inflation traps, and rules vs. discretion A large number of private agents play against a government. Government objective. The government objective is given by the following loss function: L gov = { (y y ) 2 + βπ 2} where y is the equilibrium level of output, y is the socially optimal (first-best) level, and π is the inflation rate. Welfare is thus assumed to decrease with the distance between actual and first-best output, as well as with the rate of change in prices. Philips curve. Let us denote the expected inflation by π e. Nominal wages are set so that the nominal wage w moves one to one with π e. The realized real wage is thus a decreasing function of the inflation surprise, namely difference between realized inflation π and expected inflation π e. Since lower labor costs stimulate output, we conclude that equilibrium output can be express as a decreasing function of the inflation surprise: y = y + α(π π e ) This positive relation between output and inflation (or the associated negative relation between 1

George-Marios Angeletos unemployment and inflation) is commonly referred to as the Philips curve. The variable y represents the natural level of output namely the level of output that obtains in equilibrium when monetary policy targets price stability or, more generally, when π e = π. We assume y < y, which means that the natural level of output is inefficiently low. Private agents. The agents set prices/wages so as to minimize the losses from any subsequent inflation surprises. Since these losses are increasing in the gap between actual and expected inflation, we can represent that objective of the private agents with the following loss function: Lmarket = (π e π) 2 Private agents then set π e so as to minimize the expectation of the above loss. Information and timing. The agents move first, setting π e (or, equivalently, setting wages). The government moves second, choosing π after agents have formed their inflation expectations and have fixed wages. 2

14.05 Lecture Notes Best responses: government. The government choose π so as to minimize L gov = { (y y ) 2 + βπ 2} subject to y = y + α(π π e ), taking π e as given. Taking the FOC of this problem, and rearranging, we infer that the optimal choice of π is given by α (y y) + α 2 π e π = g(π e ) =. α 2 + β You can think of this as the best response of the government against any given π e chosen by the private sector. Note that g(0) > 0 and g 2 (π) = α α 2 +β (0, 1). Best responses: private sector. The private agents choose π e so as to minimize E[L market ] = E [ (π e π) 2], where E is the rational expectations operator. The best response for the private sector is thus given by π e = E[π] 3

George-Marios Angeletos Equilibrium. Since private agents are rational, they can not be fooled": they can not make systematic mistakes when predicting inflation. Along with the simplifying assumption that there is no uncertainty, this implies that E[π] = π. That is, private agents can perfectly forecast inflation. We infer that the equilibrium values of π e and π must solve π = g(π e ) and π e = π Combining, we get the following fixed-point relation for π: α (y y) + α 2 π π = g(π). α 2 + β Recall that g(0) > 0 (because we have assumed y < y ) and g (.) (0, 1). Hence, there is a unique solution to π = g(π) and this is given by α (y y) π = π. β It follows that equilibrium equilibrium output is y = y. 4

14.05 Lecture Notes Rules vs discretion. When the government is free to optimize over the choice of inflation, the equilibrium is given by π = π > 0 and y = ȳ Now suppose that, before the agents move and set their expectations, the government ties its hands and commits on perfect price stability (π = 0) no matter what. E.g., say the government hands its monetary policy to an external authority (as it roughly happened when Greece and other Southern European countries abandoned their currencies and let Germany, in effect, set π 0 under all circumstances). Then, the private agents will now set π e = 0 = π, implying that the equilibrium is now given by π = 0 and y = ȳ Clearly, this equilibrium is much better: it delivers exactly the same aggregate output with less inflation! 5

George-Marios Angeletos What is going on? Ex ante, the government would like to promise low inflation. Ex post, the government has a desire to cheat and raise inflation, so as to reduce the output gap, that is, the gap between the equilibrium and the efficient level of output. But if the market expects the government to deviate, then they will adjust their expectations of inflation up to the point that the costs of extra inflation will be so high that the government will find it suboptimal to deviate. Hence, if the government has full discretion (freedom to choose π) and little internal commitment, then the economy ends up in a high-inflation trap. When this is the case, there is value for rules over discretion, for constitutional constraints on the conduct of monetary (and fiscal) policies, or for other ways to tie the government s hands. Importantly, this is true even if the government is entirely benevolent! This illustrates the value of commitment... of tying one s hands... of central-bank independence... and some of the benefits of joining a currency union with a "strong" central bank. 6

MIT OpenCourseWare http://ocw.mit.edu 14.05 Intermediate Macroeconomics Spring 2013 For information about citing these materials or our Terms of Use, visit: http://ocw.mit.edu/terms.