Income Distribution Dynamics with Endogenous Fertility. By Michael Kremer and Daniel Chen

Similar documents
Sixty years later, is Kuznets still right? Evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa

Development Economics Unified Growth Theory: From Stagnation to Growth

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market

Inequality and Growth: Why Differential Fertility Matters Λ

Structural Change, Demographic Transition and Fertility Di erence

Poverty, Inequality and Growth: Empirical Issues

Rising Wage Inequality and the Effectiveness of Tuition Subsidy Policies:

Dynastic Altruism, Population Growth, and Economic Prosperity

1 Static (one period) model

Growth: Facts and Theories

Assumption 5. The technology is represented by a production function, F : R 3 + R +, F (K t, N t, A t )

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Fall 2015 P. Gourinchas/D. Romer MIDTERM EXAM

One-Sector Models of Endogenous Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

TECHNICAL APPENDIX. 7. Agents Decisions in the Cobb-Douglas Case

The Evolution of Population, Technology and Output

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Explaining Rising Wage Inequality: Explorations With a Dynamic General Equilibrium Model of Labor Earnings with Heterogeneous Agents

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Florian Hoffmann. September - December Vancouver School of Economics University of British Columbia

Lecture 1: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Econometrics. Week 8. Fall Institute of Economic Studies Faculty of Social Sciences Charles University in Prague

From Difference to Differential Equations I

Chapter 4 Population and Economic Growth

UNIVERSITY OF WARWICK. Summer Examinations 2015/16. Econometrics 1

Econometrics Homework 4 Solutions

Topic 2. Consumption/Saving and Productivity shocks

Part VII. Accounting for the Endogeneity of Schooling. Endogeneity of schooling Mean growth rate of earnings Mean growth rate Selection bias Summary

More on Roy Model of Self-Selection

General motivation behind the augmented Solow model

Income Inequality, Trade and Financial Openness

MSU Development Field Exam May 9, 2008

An overview of applied econometrics

Three Lectures on Economic Growth. and International Trade. Robert E. Lucas, Jr. Wuhan University. June 16-17, 2004

Lecture 2: The Human Capital Model

The Dynamic Effect of Openness on Income Distribution and Long-Run Equilibrium

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

A s i a n J o u r n a l o f M u l t i d i m e n s i o n a l R e s e a r c h KUZNETS CURVE: THE CASE OF THE INDIAN ECONOMY

Lecture 4: Linear panel models

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

Intermediate Macroeconomics, EC2201. L2: Economic growth II

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search

A Theory of Occupational Choice with Endogenous Fertility

Online Appendix The Growth of Low Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market. By David H. Autor and David Dorn

Panel data panel data set not

Econometrics (60 points) as the multivariate regression of Y on X 1 and X 2? [6 points]

Some Microfoundations for the Gatsby Curve. Steven N. Durlauf University of Wisconsin. Ananth Seshadri University of Wisconsin

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

RBC Model with Indivisible Labor. Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

What Accounts for the Growing Fluctuations in FamilyOECD Income March in the US? / 32

Fertility Policies and Social Security Reforms in China

EEE-05, Series 05. Time. 3 hours Maximum marks General Instructions: Please read the following instructions carefully

Endogenous information acquisition

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

1 Motivation for Instrumental Variable (IV) Regression

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

UNIVERSIDAD CARLOS III DE MADRID ECONOMETRICS FINAL EXAM (Type B) 2. This document is self contained. Your are not allowed to use any other material.

Globalization, Income Inequality and Deindustrialization: The Case of South Korea

Foundation of (virtually) all DSGE models (e.g., RBC model) is Solow growth model

Econometrics Problem Set 4

Kuznets Curveball: Missing the Regional Strike Zone

Child Maturation, Time-Invariant, and Time-Varying Inputs: their Relative Importance in Production of Child Human Capital

Estimating the Technology of Children s Skill Formation

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances

Motorization in Asia: 14 countries and three metropolitan areas. Metin Senbil COE Researcher COE Seminar

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

MIGRATION AND FDI: COMPLEMENTS OR SUBSTITUTES?

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0

Artificial Intelligence and Economic Growth

Negative Income Taxes, Inequality and Poverty

The Role of Sectoral Composition in the Evolution of the Skill Wage Premium. Sara Moreira. Northwestern University

Sources of Inequality: Additive Decomposition of the Gini Coefficient.

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

PhD/MA Econometrics Examination January 2012 PART A

Repeated observations on the same cross-section of individual units. Important advantages relative to pure cross-section data

We investigate the scientific validity of one aspect of the Chinese astrology: individuals

Welfare Comparisons, Economies of Scale and Indifference Scale in Time Use

Human Capital Investment, Signaling, and Wage Differentials

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

Habilitationsvortrag: Machine learning, shrinkage estimation, and economic theory

Imperfect Credit Markets, Household Wealth Distribution, and Development. (Prepared for Annual Review of Economics)

Instrumental Variables

Economic Development and the Spatial Allocation of Labor: Evidence From Indonesia. Gharad Bryan (LSE) Melanie Morten (Stanford) May 19, 2015

Econ 5110 Solutions to the Practice Questions for the Midterm Exam

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

Introduction to Linear Regression Analysis

Testing the Separation Hypothesis with Farmer Heterogeneity: A New Use of the Structural Break Test

Additional Material for Estimating the Technology of Cognitive and Noncognitive Skill Formation (Cuttings from the Web Appendix)

Economic Growth

Mid-term exam Practice problems

Transcription:

Income Distribution Dynamics with Endogenous Fertility By Michael Kremer and Daniel Chen I. Introduction II. III. IV. Theory Empirical Evidence A More General Utility Function V. Conclusions

Introduction 2 This is joint work with Daniel Chen. The most unequal developing countries, such as Brazil and South Africa, face an uphill battle in reducing inequality, since educated workers have birthrate lower than uneducated workers. For example, in Brazil:

Table 1 -- Total Fertility Rate by Woman's Years of Education: Brazil, 3 1986. Years of None 1-3 4-6 7-9 10+ Education Total Fertility 6.7 5.2 3.4 2.8 2.2 Source: United Nations, 1995.

If children of educated workers more likely to become educated, 4 demographic factors will increase proportion of unskilled workers from one generation to next. Relative wage of unskilled workers will decline. This reduces their opportunity cost of raising children. Increase in fertility among unskilled, creates a vicious cycle. This demographic force produces instability. On other hand as proportion of unskilled increase, return to skills increases. This strengthens incentives for investment in education. This force makes imbalances in supply of skilled workers selfcorrecting: Dynamics depend on which of these forces dominates. We combine these forces in model. Two-point distribution of cost of education. If initial proportion of skilled workers great enough, economy converges to steady state with low inequality. If initial proportion of skilled is too low, inequality is self-reinforcing.

Economy converges to steady state with high inequality. 5 Expanding access to education expands basin of attraction of lowinequality steady state and may eliminate high-inequality steady state. More generally, multiplier effects, even if steady state is unique. Dahan and Tsiddon [1998] focus on transition dynamics and model demographic transition. Kuznets curve. In Dahan and Tsiddon, single steady state because all poor identical, whereas in this model, heterogeneous. Creates possibility of multiple stable steady states. Empirical evidence Data is broadly consistent with model fertility differentials between educated and uneducated women are greater in countries with more income inequality. Not definitive proof of model But cannot reject an implication of model

Organization of talk: 6

II. Theory 7 A. Model B. Potential Steady States C. Admissibility D. Comparative Statics

A. Model 8 Suppose Wages will be Utility is V = ln (n - ε) + X, Raising each child requires time φ Time endowment is 1 Budget constraint is X = w (1 - nφ) Utility can be re-written as V = ln (n - ε) + w (1 - nφ) FOC for optimal fertility implies n = ε + 1 / (wφ) Asymptotes to ε If w < 1 / (1 - εφ), corner solution with no consumption For now, consider case where A large enough that away from corner and ε = 0 for tractability

9 Number of children of unskilled and skilled workers equals birthrate times population: Under quasi-linear utility function, higher wages lead people to have fewer children. Substitution effect > Income effect

10 Matches evidence: fertility declines with education across countries, within countries Alternative explanation: quality-quantity tradeoff Both may play role Several papers give support for hypothesis that substitution effect important Schultz (1981), Schultz and Razzaz (1998) Female education reduces fertility while male education has no clear effect on fertility (United Nations, 1987 also has corroborating evidence).

Modeling choice of education: 11 Want model in which (i) educational decisions are responsive to incentives provided by wage premia (ii) children of unskilled parents face higher costs of education than children of skilled parents, due to either differences in home environments or capital market imperfections.

Group Time to obtain skills 12 Children of skilled parents units Proportion θ of children of unskilled units Proportion 1 - θ of children of unskilled units Obtain education if raises lifetime income; for those with low cost, if w S (1 - ) > w U. Obtain education if L, H < D, where L 1 / (1 - ) and H 1 / (1 - ) D w S / w U, anticipated wage differential when children become adults.

SKIP: 13 Note that both and are bounded by total time endowment, 1, and by 0, so L and H are unbounded above and bounded below by 1. Note also that D is similarly unbounded above and bounded below by 1 (skilled workers should make more than unskilled workers).

B. Potential Steady States 14 Define steady state as triplet (R*, D*, γ*), such that if ratio of skilled to unskilled workers at time t is R*, then Wage differential = D* Proportion of children of unskilled who become skilled = γ* Ratio of skilled to unskilled in next generation = R*. To solve for steady states, find fixed points of R t+1 (R t ).

15 Ls,t Lu,t Cs,t Cu,t 1 γ 1-γ Ls,t+1 Lu,t+1

If C S and fraction γ of C S become skilled, then: 16 R t+1 = R t implies steady state must satisfy: Three possible types of solutions (i) If R* induces D* = L, then γ* θ (ii) If R* induces D* = H, then γ* θ (iii) If R* induces L < D* < H, then γ* = θ.

No other solutions are possible since wage differential can never 17 be expected to be above H or less than L. (Otherwise everyone or no one would become skilled, which would not be consistent with rational expectations.) Note that quadratic equation in (5) yields more than two solutions because while there is a maximum of two solutions for a given γ*, there may be more than one steady state γ*.

R t+1 45 18 R equal * R equal * R unequal * R unequal * R + * R equal *, R unequal *, and R + * correspond to (i), (ii), and (iii) respectively. R t Figure 2: Multiple steady states

PROPOSITION 1: R equal * is an admissible steady state where 19 if and only if PROOF: D t = α / [(1 - α) R t ] D* = L R* = α / [(1 - α) L] To maintain R equal *, γ must equal γ equal* in (6). Children with a low cost of education are indifferent to obtaining education, which gives inequality in (7).

For R equal * to be admissible, θ cannot be too small relative to fertility 20 differential between skilled and unskilled, or else too few C U become skilled.

PROPOSITION 2: R unequal * is an admissible steady state where 21 if and only if PROOF: proof is similar to that of Proposition 1 except H replaces L.

R unequal * is admissible if θ is low enough relative to fertility differential 22 between skilled and unskilled. In this case, even if all θ children become skilled, R* does not increase and D* does not fall below H.

COROLLARY 1: The Gini coefficient for the equal steady state is less than the Gini coefficient for the unequal steady state. 23 PROOF: Only difference between G unequal * and G equal * is that L replaced by H. Since derivative of G equal * with respect to L is positive, G unequal * > G equal *. Income distribution at unequal s.s. S.O.S.D. income distribution at equal ss. Normalize to the same mean by fixing output and population. Cobb-Douglas fixes income going to educated and uneducated. At unequal ss, fewer educated so more income. Must transfer

24 PROPOSITION 3: R + * is a steady state if and only if D + * is between L and H and R - * is a steady state if and only if D - * is between L and H, where and the wage differential at R - * is at least as high as the wage differential at R + *. PROOF: roots of quadratic equation.

C. Admissibility 25 LEMMA 1: R - * = R + * if and only if θ = θ critical, where If θ > θ critical, R + * and R - * do not exist. If θ < θ critical, R ± * exist and R - * does not equal R + *. LEMMA 2: (i) θ L and θ H are between 0 and 1. (ii) θ L and θ H attain their maximum, θ critical, when L and H = T, where T = 1 + [1 / (1 - α)] 0.5. θ L and θ H have no other local maxima. (iii) θ L < θ H implies L < T. θ H < θ L implies H > T.

26 θ L, θ H 1 θ critical 0 1 T L, H Figure 4: θ L (L) and θ H (H)

Figure 4 shows θ L (L) and is helpful to understand axes in Figure 3. 27 On two X-axes, θ varies from 0 to 1. On Y-axis, L and H vary from 1 to infinity. Intuition for Figure 3 Broadly confirms intuition that lower costs of education and higher proportion children of unskilled with low cost may reduce inequality. Clearest for lowest and highest values of θ (Columns A and D). If proportion θ of C U with low cost is very low, economy converges to R unequal * because R equal * is inadmissible For high θ, economy converges to R equal *. R unequal * is inadmissible Multiple steady states for intermediate values of θ Stability When R equal *, R unequal *, R - * are admissible, generically stable as well. When R + * is admissible, it is generically unstable.

E. Comparative Statics 28 When there are multiple steady states as in Figure 2, system converges to R unequal * if R 0 < R + *, and to R equal * if R 0 > R + *. Increases in θ reduce R + *, and expand basin of attraction of equal steady state. To see this, note that which is negative since θ and α are less than 1. Suggests that countries with R 0 just under R + * may face a brief window of opportunity in which small and temporary increases in θ can move them into basin of attraction for R equal *. As time passes, and R falls, larger or longer-lasting increases in θ would be necessary to move to more equal steady state. Temporary increase in opportunity > permanently move country to greater equality.

III. Empirical Evidence 29 Some evidence that fertility differential between educated and uneducated women is greater in countries with more inequality. However, since causality runs in both directions in feedback model, evidence is not conclusive If only one direction of causality exists, still a positive association between differential fertility and inequality. Cannot reject implication of model remainder of section is organized as follows

III. Empirical Evidence 30 A. Data B. Methodology C. Results

A. Data 31 Table 1 Total fertility rates (TFR) by women s educational attainment United Nations 1987, Jones 1982, United Nations 1995, and Mboup and Saha 1998 Interpret total fertility rate as expected number of children a woman would have if she lives until end of her reproductive years Income inequality Deininger and Squire (1996) Mincer coefficients Bils and Klenow (1998) GDP data Summers and Heston (1994) 1) 88 observations in a sample of 62 countries from 1974 to 1994 for which observations on total fertility rates (TFR) by women s educational attainment and Gini coefficients of inequality could be obtained 2) 30 observations of countries for which TFR by women s educational attainment and Mincer coefficients could be obtained.

Table 2 32 B. Methodology Regress TFR on years of education. (Use weights because sometimes very few women with extreme levels of educational attainment, which increases measurement noise of fertility at these levels

Empirical Model 33 Two econometric models Error components model with country random effects. Data comes from several surveys at three different points in time (1970s, 1980s, and 1990s), data set includes some countries up to three times Since fertility differentials and income inequality are likely to be correlated for observations of same country due to unobservable characteristics of environment, we need to include country random effects. Failing to account for these correlations leads to underestimates of standard errors of coefficients.

Model: 34 F ct = a + bg ct + cx ct + u c + ε ct where c indexes countries and t indexes time. F ct G ct X ct fertility differential Gini coefficient vector of country and time variables such as ln(gdp), a Latin America dummy, and year of survey

35 Second model takes into account fact that ε ct is actually heteroskedastic. Noise in approximation of F ct, fertility differential, varies across observations. Earlier regressions provide an estimate of their noise the standard errors Variance-weighted least squares In effect, this regression puts more weight on observations with low variance. Could not do both because of software limitations

C. Results 36 Table 3 -- Fertility Differential Regressed on Gini Coefficient, 1974-1995 Table 3 and Chart 1 refer to sample of countries for which observations on TFR by women s educational attainment and Gini coefficients of inequality could be obtained. Positive and significant at 1% level for most specifications. 0.101*** indicates that going from a relatively equal country like Indonesia with a Gini coefficient of 0.320 in 1987 to a relatively unequal country like Brazil with a Gini coefficient of 0.545 in 1986 increases fertility differential by 0.023. 0.023 suggests that the ratio of the expected number of children between a woman with no schooling and a woman with 10 years of education is 1.26 children greater in a country like Brazil than it is in a country like Indonesia.

ln(gdp) and ln(gdp)^2 as additional covariates. No difference. 37 Latin America dummy Decrease in magnitude and significance: some of increase in fertility differential could be due to other factors related to Latin America. Sub-saharan africa dummy asia dummy, ECE support discussion in section about more general utility function

Table 4 -- Fertility Differential Regressed on Returns to Education Table 4 refer to sample of countries for which TFR by women s educational attainment and Mincer coefficients of returns to education could be obtained. 38 Variance-weighted least squares: one Mincer coefficient per country 0.288 implies that increase in two standard deviations of returns to education > increase fertility differential by 0.026. Income effects: no difference Mincer coefficient*latin America dummy: suggests Latin American countries have large, significant negative relationship while non-latin American countries have almost no relationship Potentially problematic since wage differentials appear more directly related to differential fertility than income inequality, as measured by Gini coefficient, in model But: very few observations, data quite mismatched by year for many

countries, Mincer coefficients themselves have many problems. 39 (Ability differentials and mis-measurement of returns to education because of varying quality of education across countries.) (13 observations for the United States from 1925 to 1989 (See Table 5). positive though somewhat weaker than the relationship in the other two data sets. small size of the US time-series sample. hard to pick up in general for a high-income country

IV. A More General Utility Function 40 We use quasilinear utility function Implies number of kids inversely proportional to wage This approximation may be okay at some wage levels but not others Malthus: if wages low enough, wage -> number of surviving children In Africa, at low education, n increases with education Very high wages: wage > reduce fertility only modestly.

41 Fertility B A C D Wages Figure 5: Fertility vs. Wages

Inverse relationship between fertility and wages: characteristic of 42 middle-income countries: less strong for very low or very high income countries. Can model positive asymptote with ε > 0. Suppose actual reduced form like Figure 5 If wages are sufficiently low around A, then high wage have more kids than low wage, strengthens this B - ambiguous C - model applies D - Wages are sufficiently high so that fertility of both skilled and unskilled labor is small > differential fertility low > Low variance > Measurement noise. Table 5 - relationship is in middle-y countries Cut-off between middle-income and low-income developing countries is

43 $950 GDP per capita while cut-off between middle-income and highincome countries is $9500 GDP per capita Searched

V. Conclusion and Possible Extensions 44 We assume a two-point form for distribution of cost Implies that supply of skilled labor is infinitely elastic when D = L or H > stabilizing force dominates completely inelastic for L < D < H. > demographic force dominates With a more general, continuous distribution of cost of education, either force could locally dominate in different areas. R t+1 (R t ) curve could cross 45 line an arbitrary number of times, generating an arbitrary number of stable steady states. Response of fertility differentials to wages should make R t+1 increase more steeply in R t than if fertility were exogenous. Suppose a program educates an additional 1,000,000 children > unskilled wages will rise > reducing fertility of unskilled > further increase wages among unskilled. creating a multiplier effect on inequality.

45 Rt+1 45 45 Rt+1 Rt Rt Figure 6: Multiplier effect in a local neighborhood of a stable steady state with and without endogenous fertility

46 Note that this does not apply in simple model with two-point distribution of cost Limitation: relative wages depend on population ratio rather than market labor time ratio, Market labor time depends on proportion of time each group spends on education and raising children. Choice of whether to obtain education depends on people s expectations of fertility of skilled and unskilled when they become adults. R t would depend not only on R t-1 but also on R t+1. Conjecture: robust as long as (i) skilled and unskilled workers are complements in production; (ii) children of unskilled are more likely to be unskilled, and (iii) higher wages reduce fertility because substitution effects outweigh income effects.