Maximin share and minimax envy in fair-division problems

Similar documents
The Mathematical Appendix

Rademacher Complexity. Examples

Chapter 5 Properties of a Random Sample

Strong Convergence of Weighted Averaged Approximants of Asymptotically Nonexpansive Mappings in Banach Spaces without Uniform Convexity

Chapter 9 Jordan Block Matrices

CIS 800/002 The Algorithmic Foundations of Data Privacy October 13, Lecture 9. Database Update Algorithms: Multiplicative Weights

Non-uniform Turán-type problems

{ }{ ( )} (, ) = ( ) ( ) ( ) Chapter 14 Exercises in Sampling Theory. Exercise 1 (Simple random sampling): Solution:

18.413: Error Correcting Codes Lab March 2, Lecture 8

TESTS BASED ON MAXIMUM LIKELIHOOD

CHAPTER VI Statistical Analysis of Experimental Data

MATH 247/Winter Notes on the adjoint and on normal operators.

Special Instructions / Useful Data

Chapter 4 (Part 1): Non-Parametric Classification (Sections ) Pattern Classification 4.3) Announcements

PROJECTION PROBLEM FOR REGULAR POLYGONS

Lecture 3 Probability review (cont d)

Complete Convergence and Some Maximal Inequalities for Weighted Sums of Random Variables

Q-analogue of a Linear Transformation Preserving Log-concavity

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Assignment 5/MATH 247/Winter Due: Friday, February 19 in class (!) (answers will be posted right after class)

Econometric Methods. Review of Estimation

9 U-STATISTICS. Eh =(m!) 1 Eh(X (1),..., X (m ) ) i.i.d

X ε ) = 0, or equivalently, lim

Part 4b Asymptotic Results for MRR2 using PRESS. Recall that the PRESS statistic is a special type of cross validation procedure (see Allen (1971))

A Remark on the Uniform Convergence of Some Sequences of Functions

arxiv:math/ v1 [math.gm] 8 Dec 2005

ρ < 1 be five real numbers. The

Discrete Mathematics and Probability Theory Fall 2016 Seshia and Walrand DIS 10b

Ordinary Least Squares Regression. Simple Regression. Algebra and Assumptions.

Lecture 3. Sampling, sampling distributions, and parameter estimation

Lecture 9: Tolerant Testing

Lebesgue Measure of Generalized Cantor Set

Feature Selection: Part 2. 1 Greedy Algorithms (continued from the last lecture)

Summary of the lecture in Biostatistics

Point Estimation: definition of estimators

1 Lyapunov Stability Theory

Lecture 7. Confidence Intervals and Hypothesis Tests in the Simple CLR Model

Chapter 14 Logistic Regression Models

Functions of Random Variables

Investigation of Partially Conditional RP Model with Response Error. Ed Stanek

L5 Polynomial / Spline Curves

Arithmetic Mean and Geometric Mean

Introduction to Probability

Mu Sequences/Series Solutions National Convention 2014

Chapter 4 Multiple Random Variables

Research Article A New Iterative Method for Common Fixed Points of a Finite Family of Nonexpansive Mappings

1 Mixed Quantum State. 2 Density Matrix. CS Density Matrices, von Neumann Entropy 3/7/07 Spring 2007 Lecture 13. ψ = α x x. ρ = p i ψ i ψ i.

Lecture 4 Sep 9, 2015

STA302/1001-Fall 2008 Midterm Test October 21, 2008

α1 α2 Simplex and Rectangle Elements Multi-index Notation of polynomials of degree Definition: The set P k will be the set of all functions:

Maps on Triangular Matrix Algebras

Chapter 3 Sampling For Proportions and Percentages

A tighter lower bound on the circuit size of the hardest Boolean functions

Bounds for the Connective Eccentric Index

CHAPTER 4 RADICAL EXPRESSIONS

. The set of these sums. be a partition of [ ab, ]. Consider the sum f( x) f( x 1)

MA 524 Homework 6 Solutions

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Extreme Value Theory: An Introduction

AN UPPER BOUND FOR THE PERMANENT VERSUS DETERMINANT PROBLEM BRUNO GRENET

CS286.2 Lecture 4: Dinur s Proof of the PCP Theorem

Complete Convergence for Weighted Sums of Arrays of Rowwise Asymptotically Almost Negative Associated Random Variables

ENGI 4421 Joint Probability Distributions Page Joint Probability Distributions [Navidi sections 2.5 and 2.6; Devore sections

Bounds on the expected entropy and KL-divergence of sampled multinomial distributions. Brandon C. Roy

X X X E[ ] E X E X. is the ()m n where the ( i,)th. j element is the mean of the ( i,)th., then

8.1 Hashing Algorithms

Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications

SUBCLASS OF HARMONIC UNIVALENT FUNCTIONS ASSOCIATED WITH SALAGEAN DERIVATIVE. Sayali S. Joshi

Entropy ISSN by MDPI

( ) = ( ) ( ) Chapter 13 Asymptotic Theory and Stochastic Regressors. Stochastic regressors model

Unsupervised Learning and Other Neural Networks

v 1 -periodic 2-exponents of SU(2 e ) and SU(2 e + 1)

Solving Constrained Flow-Shop Scheduling. Problems with Three Machines

Lecture Notes Types of economic variables

Qualifying Exam Statistical Theory Problem Solutions August 2005

PTAS for Bin-Packing

6.867 Machine Learning

Packing of graphs with small product of sizes

LINEAR RECURRENT SEQUENCES AND POWERS OF A SQUARE MATRIX

STK4011 and STK9011 Autumn 2016

Lecture 1. (Part II) The number of ways of partitioning n distinct objects into k distinct groups containing n 1,

Ideal multigrades with trigonometric coefficients

2.28 The Wall Street Journal is probably referring to the average number of cubes used per glass measured for some population that they have chosen.

Median as a Weighted Arithmetic Mean of All Sample Observations

3. Basic Concepts: Consequences and Properties

= lim. (x 1 x 2... x n ) 1 n. = log. x i. = M, n

Simple Linear Regression

THE ROYAL STATISTICAL SOCIETY 2016 EXAMINATIONS SOLUTIONS HIGHER CERTIFICATE MODULE 5

Uniform asymptotical stability of almost periodic solution of a discrete multispecies Lotka-Volterra competition system

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. August 2011

Exercises for Square-Congruence Modulo n ver 11

C.11 Bang-bang Control

Third handout: On the Gini Index

Large and Moderate Deviation Principles for Kernel Distribution Estimator

F. Inequalities. HKAL Pure Mathematics. 進佳數學團隊 Dr. Herbert Lam 林康榮博士. [Solution] Example Basic properties

Some Notes on the Probability Space of Statistical Surveys

Algorithms Design & Analysis. Hash Tables

The Brunn Minkowski Inequality, Minkowski s First Inequality, and Their Duals 1

ANALYSIS ON THE NATURE OF THE BASIC EQUATIONS IN SYNERGETIC INTER-REPRESENTATION NETWORK

A Study on Generalized Generalized Quasi hyperbolic Kac Moody algebra QHGGH of rank 10

Transcription:

Maxm share ad mmax evy far-dvso problems Marco Dall Aglo a,1 ad Theodore P. Hll b,,2 a Dpartmeto d Sceze, Uverstá G. d Auzo, Vale Pdaro 42, 65127 Pescara, Italy b School of Mathematcs, Georga Isttute of Techology, Atlata, GA 30332-0160, USA Submtted by Wllam F. Ames Abstract For far-dvso or cake-cuttg problems wth value fuctos whch are ormalzed postve measures (.e., the values are probablty measures) maxm-share ad mmax-evy equaltes are derved for both cotuous ad dscrete measures. The tools used clude classcal ad recet basc covexty results, as well as ad hoc costructos. Examples are gve to show that the evymmzg crtero s ot Pareto optmal, eve f the values are mutually absolutely cotuous. I the dscrete measure case, suffcet codtos are obtaed to guaratee the exstece of evy-free parttos. Keywords Far-dvso; Cake-cuttg; Maxm share; Mmax evy; Evy-free; Optmal partto; Equtable partto 1. Itroducto The subject of ths paper s far-dvso or cake-cuttg equaltes (cf. [5,6,11]), ad partcular, the relatoshp amog varous otos of optmalty such as maxm share, mmax evy, ad Dubs Spaer optmalty. A cake Ω s to be dvded amog players * Correspodg author. E-mal address hll@math.gatech.edu (T.P. Hll). 1 Partally supported by MURST-COFIN 2000. 2 Partally supported by US Natoal Scece Foudato Grat DMS-9971146 ad Göttge Academy of Sceces (Gauss Professorshp Fall 2000).

whose relatve values v 1,...,v of the varous parts of the cake may dffer. A partto of the cake to peces P 1,...,P s sought so that the resultg values v (P j ) make the mmum perceved share as large as possble, or make the maxmum evy as small as possble. The formal framework s as follows. There are (coutably addtve) probablty measures v 1,...,v o the same measurable space (Ω, F),where Ω represets the cake ad F s the σ -algebra of subsets of Ω whch represets the collecto of feasble peces. For each P F ad each, v (P ) represets the value of pece P to player. (Hece, ths settg, the feasble peces always clude the whole cake, ad are closed uder complemets ad coutable uos; ad the value fuctos are addtve.) Throughout ths paper, Π wll deote the collecto of F-measurable parttos of Ω, that s, { } Π = (P 1,...,P ): P F for all, P P j = f j, ad P = Ω, ad a typcal elemet P Π s the partto P = (P 1,...,P ) represetg allocato of P to player for all = 1,...,. Ths paper s orgazed as follows: Secto 2 cotas deftos ad examples of the value matrx, maxm optmalty ad far parttos, as well as the ma compactess ad covexty theorem for value matrces due to Dubs ad Spaer [6]; Secto 3 cotas the aalogous covexty/compactess result for evy matrces, a proof that eve the mutually absolutely cotuous case, a Dubs Spaer optmal partto eed ot be evyfree, ad several results guarateeg the exstece of quatfably super-far evy-free ad super-evy-free parttos; ad Secto 4 cotas mmax-evy equaltes for geeral measures (cludg measures wth atoms) whose bouds are fuctos of the maxmum atom sze. =1 2. Far ad Dubs Spaer-optmal parttos Deote by M( ) the set of real-valued matrces. Defto 2.1. The value matrx M V (P) of a partto P s the matrx whose etres are the values of the peces of the partto to the respectve players, that s, M V : Π M( ) s gve by ( ) ( ) M V (P) = M V (P 1,...,P ) = v (P j ),j=1, ad the set of F-feasble value matrces M V s gve by { } M V = M V (P): P Π M( ).

Example 2.2. Let (Ω, F) = ([0, 1], Borels), = 2, v 1 = uform dstrbuto o [0, 1], ad v 2 = probablty measure o [0, 1] wth dstrbuto fucto F 2 (x) = x 2,0 x 1. The for P 1 = ([0, 1/2), [1/2, 1]) ad P 2 = ([0,( 5 1)/2), [( 5 1)/2, 1]), ( 1 1 ) ( 5 1 3 5 ) M V (P 1 ) = ad M V (P 2 ) =, 2 1 4 2 3 4 2 3 5 2 2 5 1 2 ad a easy calculato shows that {( ) } x 1 x 2 M V = :0 x 1, (1 x) 2 y 1 x. 1 y y Example 2.3. Let (Ω, F) = ([0, 1], Borels), = 2, v 1 = v 2 = δ (1/2), the Drac pot mass at {1/2},ad let P 1, P 2 be as Example 2.2. The ( ) ( ) 0 1 1 0 M V (P 1 ) =, M V (P 2 ) =, 0 1 1 0 ad {( ) } x 1 x M V = : x = 0or x = 1. x 1 x The ext result, a cosequece of Lyapouov s covexty theorem due to Dubs ad Spaer, s oe of the ma tools measure-theoretc far-dvso problems, ad s recorded here for ease of referece. (Recall that a measure v s atomless f for every P F wth v(p) > 0, there exsts a set A F, A P wth 0 <v(a) < v(p ); for Borel measures o the real le, ths s equvalet to v({x}) = 0for every x R.) Proposto 2.4 [6]. Fx 1 ad v 1,..., v probablty measures o (Ω, F).The () M V s compact (as a subset of real matrces); ad () f each v s atomless, the M V s covex. Remarks. Note that the measures Example 2.2 are atomless, ad hece that the set of feasble value matrces M V s covex. I Example 2.3, o the other had, v 1 ad v 2 are purely atomc, ad M V s far from covex. It s also easy to check that M V may be covex eve f {v } are atomc; for example, by takg = 2ad v 1 = v 2 defed by v 1 ({x}) = x for x = 2, = 1, 2,..., ad v 1 (x) = 0 otherwse, whch case {( ) } x 1 x M V = :0 x 1. x 1 x Defto 2.5. A partto P = (P 1,..., P ) s far f v (P ) 1/ for all ;s equtable f v (P ) = v j (P j ) for all, j ;s maxm optmal f m 1 v (P ) m 1 v (Pˆ) for all Pˆ = (Pˆ1,..., Pˆ) Π ;ad s Dubs Spaer optmal (DS optmal) f (v 1 (P 1 ),..., v (P )) (v 1 (Pˆ 1 ),..., v (Pˆ )) for all Pˆ = (Pˆ1,..., Pˆ) Π,where v (P ) are the creasg order statstcs of the {v (P )} (.e., v 1 (P 1 ) v 2 (P 2 )

v (P )), ad s the real lexcographc order. I other words, P s DS optmal f the smallest share m 1 v (P ) s as large as possble amog all possble parttos, ad amog all parttos attag that maxm, the secod smallest share s as large as possble, ad so forth. Remarks. As show [6], t follows from Proposto 2.4() that maxm-optmal ad DS-optmal parttos always exst; ad from Proposto 2.4() that f the {v } are atomless, that far equtable parttos always exst, ad that every DS-optmal partto s far. Wthout the assumpto of atomless measures, DS-optmal parttos may ot be far, as s easly see Example 2.3. 3. Evy-mmzg parttos A recet alteratve to the objectve of maxmzg oe s ow share v (P ), s the objectve of mmzg oe s evy of other s shares v (P j ) v (P ) (cf. [3 5,14]). Clearly the two objectves are related, but as the ext example pots out, players tryg to mmze evy would sometmes reject a gve partto favor of oe whch gves every player a much smaller share. I ths example, the players would reject a equtable partto whch allocates each player very early 50% of hs ow value of the cake (but wth a accompayg mscule amout of evy) favor of a evy-free partto whch allots each player a pece he feels s worth exactly 1% of the total value. I partcular, the example shows that the evy-mmzg objectve s ot Pareto optmal. Example 3.1. Let (Ω, F) = ([0, 100], Borels), = 100, let v be uform o [ 1, + 1) for = 1,..., 99, ad let v 100 be uform o [99, 100] [0, 1). Let P = (P 1,P 2,...,P 100 ) be gve by P =[ + 0.0001, + 1.0001), = 1,..., 98, P 99 = [99.0001, 100] [0, 0.0001),ad P 100 =[0.0001, 1.0001);ad let Pˆ = (Pˆ1, Pˆ 2,..., Pˆ 100 ) be P ˆ 99 = k= 0 [k + ( 1)/100,k + /100), = 1,..., 100. It s easly checked that, for each, v (P ) = 0.49995 ad the evy of player (see Defto 3.2 below) s 0.00005 for each. O the other had, wth partto Pˆ, each player receves a pece worth exactly v (Pˆ) = 0.01, but o player values ay other pece more tha hs ow. Thus players seekg to mmze evy would choose P 2 over P 1 ad reduce ther shares uformly by early a factor of 50. I the above example, however, t s easy to see that there s a partto (amely P = [ 1,) for all ) whch s smultaeously evy-free, DS optmal, equtable ad far, ad whch assgs each player a share he values exactly 50% of the cake. It s the purpose of ths secto to record several basc propertes of evy, to vestgate the terrelatoshp amog these varous otos of optmalty, ad to derve several geeral equaltes for upper bouds o evy. Defto 3.2. The evy of a partto P to player, e (P),s e (P) = max 1 j v (P j ) = v (P );the maxmum evy of P, e max (P), s e max (P) = max 1 e (P); the evy matrx of P, M E (P) s the elemet M( ) wth (, j)th etry e,j = v (P j ) v (P );ad the

set of F-feasble evy matrces M E s the subset of M( ) gve by M E ={M E (P): P Π }. (Note that the defto of evy here s the egatve of that [14]; here postve evy reflects valug aother s pece more tha oe s ow, ad the objectve s to mmze evy.) Example 3.3. () For the problem Example 2.2, ( ) ( ) 0 0 0 2 5 M E (P 1 ) =, M E (P 2 ) =, 1 0 2 5 0 2 ad {( ) } 0 1 2x 2 M E = :0 x 1, (1 x) 2 y 1 x. 1 2y 0 () For the problem Example 2.3, ( ) ( ) 0 1 0 1 M E (P 1 ) =, M E (P 2 ) =, 1 0 1 0 ad {( ) } 0 1 2x M E = : x = 0or1. 2x 1 0 Lemma 3.4. () dm(m V ) = dm(m E ); () the fucto from M V M E defed by M V (P) M E (P) s oe-to-oe, oto, ad affe. Proof. Cocluso () s a drect cosequece of (). To see (), ote that {v (P j )},j=1 clearly determes {v (P j ) v (P )},j= 1 ; coversely, the sum of the evy etres the th row, so ( ) v (P j ) v (P ) = v (P j ) v (P ) = 1 v (P ), j=1 j=1 v (P j ) = v (P j ) v (P ) + v (P ) ( ) ( ) = v (P j ) v (P ) + 1 1 v (P j ) v (P ). j=1 The ext theorem s a drect aalog of the ma compactess covexty result for value matrces gve Proposto 2.4. Theorem 3.5. Fx 1, ad v 1,v 2,..., v probablty measures o (Ω, F).The () M E s compact; ad () f each v s atomless, the M E s covex.

Proof. Cocluso () follows from Lemma 3.4 ad Proposto 2.4, sce M E s a cotuous mage of the compact set M V, ad () follows smlarly sce the atomless measure case, M E s the mage of the covex set M V uder a affe trasformato. Note that Example 3.3, M E s covex case (), ad ot covex (); both cases t s compact. Defto 3.6. A partto P Π s evy-free f e max (P ) 0; s mmax evy optmal f e max (P ) = m{e max (P): P Π };ad s DS mmax evy optmal f t attas the mmum, lexcographcally, of the set of feasble ordered evy vectors {(e 1 (P),...,e (P)): P Π } (cf. Defto 3.2). Example 3.7. The partto P 2 Example 2.2 s the uque (up to sets of measure zero) DS-mmax-evy-optmal partto ad s also evy-free (see Example 3.3()); every partto Example 2.3 s DS mmax evy optmal wth maxmum possble evy +1 for oe of the players, ad o partto s evy-free. Theorem 3.8. Fx 1, ad v 1,...,v probablty measures o (Ω, F).The () Mmax-evy-optmal ad DS-mmax-evy-optmal parttos always exst; () If a partto s evy-free, the t s far; () If {v } 1 are atomless, the evy-free parttos always exst; (v) If {v } 1 are atomless ad learly depedet, the super-evy-free parttos (e max < 0) always exst. Proof. Cocluso () follows easly from Theorem 3.5() sce the mappg M E [ 1, 1] gve by M E (P) e max (P) ( (e 1 (P),...,e (P)), respectvely) s cotuous, so ts mmum s attaed; () s trval sce v (P j ) v (P ) 0for all, j mples that v (P ) 1/ for all ; () follows by Theorem 3.5() by cosderg the parttos P 1 = (Ω,,..., ), P 2 = (,Ω,,..., ),..., P = (,...,,Ω), ad otg that j=1 M E(P j ) s the zero matrx; ad (v) s the ma result [3]. Cotrary to a clam [15], the ext example shows that eve for three mutually absolutely cotuous measures v 1,v 2,v 3, a DS-optmal partto eed ot be evy-free. (Recall that Example 3.1, P was strctly better value-wse for each player tha the evyfree partto Pˆ,but P was ot DS optmal.) Example 3.9. Let (Ω, F) = ([0, 3], Borels), = 3, ad (lettg I(a,b) deote the dcator fucto I (a, b)(x) = 1f a<x<b,ad = 0 otherwse) let v 1,v 2,v 3 be the cotuous dstrbutos wth desty fuctos f 1,f 2,f 3, respectvely, gve by f 1 = 0.4I(0, 1) + 0.1I(1, 2) + 0.5I(2, 3), f 2 = 0.3I(0, 1) + 0.4I(1, 2) + 0.3I(2, 3), f 3 = 0.3I(0, 1) + 0.3I(1, 2) + 0.4I(2, 3).

The, as wll be proved the ext theorem, the partto P = (P 1,P 2,P 3 ) = ([0, 1), [1, 2), [2, 3]) yelds the uquely maxm-optmal vector (v 1 (P 1 ), v 2 (P 2 ), v 3 (P 3 )) = (0.4, 0.4, 0.4), but P s ot evy-free. Thus every evy-free partto s strctly suboptmal the maxm crtero, ad hece also strctly suboptmal the DS crtero. Theorem 3.10. () If = 2 ad v 1,v 2 are atomless, the every maxm-optmal partto s evy-free; ad () for each 3, there exst mutually absolutely cotuous atomless measures v 1,..., v such that o maxm-optmal partto s evy-free. ( ) ( ) 10 01 Proof. To see (), ote that ad are M V (takg P 1 = (Ω, ), P 2 = (,Ω)), ( 10 ) 01 1/2 1/2 so by Proposto 2.4, 1/2 1/2 M V, ad thus every maxm-optmal partto P satsfes v 1 (P) 1/2, v 2 (P) 1/2. By addtvty, ths mples that v 1 (P 1 ) v 1 (P 2 ) ad v 2 (P 2 ) v 2 (P 1 ), ad hece that P s evy-free. To see (), ote that [6, last remark o p. 17] for ay, whe the measures are mutually absolutely cotuous the DS-optmal soluto s equtable. Therefore, all maxmoptmal solutos are DS optmal ad equtable. For = 3, cosder the measures v 1, v 2,ad v 3 of Example 3.9. The set of all possble parttos of [0, 3] ca be descrbed as follows: the terval [0, 1) s dvded to three parts wth player 1 (respectvely, player 2) recevg a pece of legth p 1 (respectvely, p 2 )ad player 3 gettg the rest,.e., 1 p 1 p 2. Smlarly, [1, 2) s splt to three parts of legth q 1, q 2,ad1 q 1 q 2, respectvely, ad [2, 3] s parttoed as r 1, r 2,ad1 r 1 r 2. Every equtable partto s obtaed as a soluto of the followg system of lear equatos ad equaltes: 0.4p1 + 0.1q 1 + 0.5r 1 = α, 0.3p 2 + 0.4q 2 + 0.3r 2 = α, 0.3(1 p 1 p 2 ) + 0.3(1 q 1 q 2 ) + 0.4(1 r 1 r 2 ) = α, p 1,p 2,q 1,q 2,r 1,r 2 0, p 1 + p 2 1, q 1 + q 2 1, r1 + r 2 1, ad the largest value of α s sought that keeps ths system admssble. The correspodg solutos for the p s, q s, ad r s descrbe all possble maxm-optmal solutos. Solvg the frst equato for p 1 terms of α, q 1,ad r 1, ad the secod for q 2 terms of α, p 2,ad r 2, ad substtutg these expressos the thrd equato yelds 0.3p 2 + 0.9q 1 + 0.1r 1 + 0.7r 2 = 4 10α. (3.1) If α> 0.4, Eq. (3.1) has o soluto wth oegatve varables. If, stead, α = 0.4, (3.1) admts oly the soluto p 2 = q 1 = r 1 = r 2 = 0. (3.2) (Thus, the segmet [2, 3] s gve ts etrety to player 3, who reaches hs quota of 0.4 ad has o terest the other parts of the cake.)

Hece, sce α = 0.4, p 1 + p 2 = 1 ad q 1 + q 2 = 1. Ths fact ad (3.2) mply that p 1 = q 2 = 1, whch shows that P = ([0, 1), [1, 2), [2, 3]) s, up to sets of Lebesgue measure zero, the oly mmax-optmal (ad DS-optmal) soluto. But ( 0 0.3 0.1 ) M E (P) = 0.1 0 0.1, 0.1 0.1 0 whch shows that ths partto s ot evy-free. Ths completes the case = 3 (ad establshes the clam Example 3.9). For > 3, let (Ω, F) = ([0,], Borels) ad fx ε wth 0 < ε< 1. Cosder the cotuous dstrbutos v 1,...,v wth desty fuctos f 1,...,f, respectvely, that have costat values each terval [ 1,), = 1,...,, wth values show the followg table: ε ε ε ε ε ε ε f 1 0.4(1 ε) 0.1(1 ε) 0.5(1 ε ) /( 3) /( 3)... ε/( 3) [0, 1) [1, 2) [2, 3) [3, 4) [4, 5)... [ 1,] f 2 0.3(1 ε) 0.4(1 ε) 0.3(1 ε ) ε /( 3) ε /( 3)... ε/( 3) f 3 0.3(1 ε) 0.3(1 ε) 0.4(1 ε ) ε /( 3) ε /( 3)... ε/( 3) f 4 ε/( 1) /( 1) ε /( 1) 1 εε/( 1)... ε/( 1) f 5 ε/( 1) /( 1) ε /( 1) /( 1) 1 ε... ε/( 1).......... f ε/( 1) /( 1) ε /( 1) /( 1) ε /( 1)... 1 ε As the = 3 case, the dstrbutos are mutually absolutely cotuous ad all mmaxoptmal solutos are DS optmal ad equtable. Deote by p,j (, j = 1,...,) the legth of the part of [ 1,) assged to player j wth the usual costrats p,j 0ad j=1 p,j = 1for all. The partto, defed by p, = 1for all, has 0.4(1 ε) as ts lowest value, so the mmax-optmal value caot be smaller tha ths value. Cosder ow the frst three players oly. Sce the mmax value s at least 0.4(1 ε) ad sce 3 f dv = ε, = 1, 2, 3, each of the players 1, 2, 3 must receve somethg worth atleast0.4 1.4ε from the terval [0, 3), so the followg system of equaltes must be satsfed by ay mmax-optmal soluto: 0.4p 1,1 + 0.1p 2,1 + 0.5p 3,1 β + O(ε), 0.3p 1,2 + 0.4p 2,2 + 0.3p 3,2 β + O(ε), 0.3p 1,3 + 0.3p 2,3 + 0.4p 3,3 β + O(ε), β 0.4 + O(ε). A smple cosequece of the ormalzg costrats for the p,j s that (3.3a) (3.3b) (3.3c) (3.3d) p,3 1 p,1 p,2, = 1, 2, 3. (3.4) Ths, wth (3.3c), mples that 0.3(1 p 1,1 p 1,2 ) + 0.3(1 p 2,1 p 2,2 ) + 0.4(1 p 3,1 p 3,2 ) β + O(ε).

Rearragg (3.3a) (3.3c) yelds p 1,1 5 2 β 1 4 p 2,1 5 4 p 3,1 + O(ε), (3.5a) p 2,2 5 2 β 3 4 p 1,2 3 4 p 3,2 + O(ε), (3.5b) 0.3p 1,1 + 0.3p 1,2 + 0.3p 2,1 + 0.3p 2,2 + 0.4p 3,1 + 0.4p 3,2 1 β + O(ε), (3.5c) β 0.4 + O(ε). Substtutg (3.5a) ad (3.5b) to (3.5c) yelds (3.5d) 0.3p 1,2 + 0.9p 2,1 + 0.1p 3,1 + 0.7p 3,2 4 10β + O(ε), (3.6a) β 0.4 + O(ε). (3.6b) These mply that 0.3p 1,2 + 0.9p 2,1 + 0.1p 3,1 + 0.7p 3,2 4 10β + O(ε) = O(ε). (3.7) Sce all varables (3.7) are oegatve, they all satsfy p 1,2 = O(ε), p 2,1 = O(ε), p 3,1 = O(ε), p 3,2 = O(ε). (3.8) From (3.5a) ad (3.5d), ad the fact that p 2,1 ad p 3,1 are O(ε), t follows that p 1,1 = 1 + O(ε), ad hece that p 1,3 = O(ε). (3.9) Smlarly, (3.5b), (3.5d), ad (3.8) mply that p 2,2 = 1 + O(ε),so p 2,3 = O(ε). (3.10) Fally, (3.5c), (3.5d), (3.9), ad (3.10) mply that p 3,3 = 1 + O(ε). (3.11) Thus, player 1 s evaluato of hs ow share ay mmax-optmal soluto s v 1 (P 1 ) = 0.4p 1,1 + 0.1p 2,1 + 0.5p 3,1 + O(ε) = 0.4 + O(ε). Player 1 s evaluato of player 3 s share, o the other had, s v 1 (P 3 ) = 0.4p 1,3 + 0.1p 2,3 + 0.5p 3,3 + O(ε) = 0.5 + O(ε), where the last equalty follows from (3.11). Therefore, e 1,3 = v 1 (P 3 ) v 1 (P 1 ) 0.1as ε 0, so asymptotcally, every maxm-optmal partto, player 1 eves player 3 s share by a amout arbtrarly close to 0.1. The fal theorem ths secto gves sharp bouds for faress of evy-free parttos ad mmax evy, the case where the measures are atomless ad have kow upper ad lower bouds, respectvely.

For measures v 1,..., v, the fucto = 1 v : F [0, 1], called the maxmum of {v 1,..., v }, s the smallest set fucto whch domates each of the {v }; = 1 v s the aalogous mmum. It s easy to check that both v ad v are also coutably addtve measures o (Ω, F), ad lettg v,v deote the total masses of v, v, respectvely, that v 1 v, wth equalty f ad oly f v 1 = v 2 = =v.(whe {v } are absolutely cotuous wth destes {f }, v s smply the total area uder the outer evelope max 1 f of {f },ad v s the area uder m 1 f.) I far-dvso problems, v represets the cooperatve value of Ω, that s the total value to the coalto of all players f each pece s gve to the player who values t most, ad these values are added together. Smlarly, v represets the worst-case allocato f the values are added (cf. [8,10]). Example 3.11. For the measures Example 2.2, v = 5/4ad v = 3/4; Example 2.3, v = 1 = v. Theorem 3.12. Fx 1 ad v 1,..., v atomless probablty measures o (Ω, F). The there exst parttos P (1), P (2), P (3), P (4) Π such that (1) () P (1) s evy-free ad v (P ) = ( v + 1) 1 for all ; (2) () P (2) s evy-free ad v (P ) = ( + v } 1) 1 for all ; { v 1 () e max (P (3) ) m 0, { v +1 ; ad +v 3} (v) e max (P (4) ) m 0,, +v 1 ad these bouds are best possble. Recall that v = 1 f ad oly f v = 1 f ad oly f v 1 = = v, so the bouds ( v + 1) 1 ad ( + v 1) 1 () ad () are strctly bgger tha 1/ wheever the {v } are ot detcal. Thus, that case, () ad () guaratee the exstece of evy-free super-far parttos, wth super-faress quatfably greater tha 1/. Smlarly, for v suffcetly large, or v suffcetly small (v > 1, v < 3 ), () ad (v) guaratee the exstece of super-evy-free parttos wth evy quatfably strctly egatve (cf. [6] ad [3] for oquatfable super-far ad for super-evy-free parttos, respectvely). Proof of Theorem 3.12. Let µ = = 1 v.every v s absolutely cotuous wth respect to µ, so, by the Rado Nkodym theorem, there exsts a fucto f, called the desty fucto of v, such that v (A) = A f dµ for all A F. To prove (), let P = (P 1,...,P ) be the partto of Ω whch assgs each elemet of Ω to the player whose desty s hghest that pot. I case of tes, the pot s allocated to the player detfed by the lowest umber. More formally, let { } P = x Ω: f 1 (x) = max f m (x) 1 m

ad { } k 1 P = x Ω: f k (x) = max (x) P, k = 2,...,. k f m m =1 Let M V (P ) = (v (P j )),j=1 be the value matrx assocated wth the partto P.The ad ( ) v P = f dµ = max dµ = max f m dµ = v (3.12) f m m =1 =1 P =1 P Ω ( ) ( ) v P = f dµ = max f m dµ f j dµ = v j P m P P P for all, j = 1,...,. (3.13) Now, for each k = 1,...,, cosder the partto P k = (P k 1,...,P k ) whch assgs the whole set Ω to player k,.e., { k Ω f j = k, P j = (3.14) otherwse. Clearly, the value matrx M V (P k ) satsfes { ( ) k 1 f j = k, v P j = for all = 1,...,. 0 otherwse, Sce the v are atomless, Proposto 2.4() mples that M V s covex. Therefore, for +1 ay choce of β 1,...,β,β +1 wth β 0for all = 1,...,+ 1ad =1 β = 1, there (1) (1) exsts a partto P (1) = (P,...,P ) such that 1 M V (P (1) ) = β k M V (P k ) + β +1 M V (P ). k=1 Defe the coeffcets {β } as follows (cf. [12,13]): 1 v k (P k ) 1 β k =, k = 1,...,, ad β +1 =. v + 1 v + 1 The {β } are all oegatve sce v, ad satsfy β = 1 by (3.12). The elemets of M V (P (1) ) satsfy ( ) (1) ( ) ( ) ( ) v P k P j = β k v j + β +1 v P j = β j + β +1 v Pj k=1 1 v j (P j ) + v (P j ) 1 ( (1)) = = v P. (3.15) v + 1 v + 1 The equalty (3.15) follows by (3.13), wth the roles of ad j reversed. Therefore, P (1) s evy-free ad allots the value ( v + 1) 1 to each player. m

The proof of () also requres the followg verso prcple (cf. [10, Proposto 2.3]): M V M V (1 M V )/( 1) M V, (3.16) where 1 s the matrx whose elemets are all 1 s. Ths tme, the partto P, whch assgs each pot to the player wth the lowest desty, s { } P 1 = x Ω: f 1 (x) = m f m (x) m ad { } k 1 P k = x Ω: f k (x) = m f m (x) P, k It s easy to see that ad v (P ) = v =1 1 M V (P ) M V (P (2) ) = βˆkm V (P k ) + βˆ+1, 1 k=1 m = 2,...,. v k (P k ) 1 βˆk =, k = 1,...,, ad βˆ+1 =. + v 1 + v 1 +1 It s easy to check that βˆ 0, ad, by (3.17a), =1 βˆ = 1. From (3.17b) t follows that =1 v (P ) v j (P ) for all, j = 1,...,. (3.17a) (3.17b) By (3.16), (1 M V (P ))/( 1) M V ad, therefore, by Proposto 2.4(), there exsts (2) (2) a partto P (2) = (P,...,P ) whose value matrx satsfes 1 where coeffcets βˆ are gve by ( (2) ) ( ) 1 v (P j ) 1 v (P j ) v P j = βˆkv Pj k + βˆ+1 = βˆj + βˆ+1 1 1 k=1 v j (P j ) + 1 v (P j ) 1 ( (2) = = v ) P, (3.18) + v 1 + v 1 so P (2) s evy-free ad allots the value ( + v 1) 1 to each player. Statemets () ad (v) are a drect cosequece of () ad (), respectvely. I partcular, to prove (), aga cosder the partto P (1). It was show () that ths partto s evy-free, so e max (P (1) ) 0. Also, by (3.15), v (P (1) ) = ( v + 1) 1 ad ( (1)) ( (1)) v v P j 1 v P = for all j. v + 1

Therefore ( (1)) ( (1)) v 1 v P j v P for all j =, v + 1 whch completes the proof of (). Smlarly, to obta (v), ote that e max (P (2) ) 0 ad, by (3.18), so ( (2)) ( (2)) + v 2 v P j 1 v P = for all j, + v 1 ( (2)) ( (2)) + v 3 v Pj v P for all j. + v 1 Example 3.13. For the measures Example 2.2, Theorem 3.12() guaratees the exstece of a evy-free partto wth equtable share (2 v + 1) 1 = 4/7 = 0.57 for each player, whereas for these partcular measures eve more s possble (amely ( 5 1)/2 = 0.61, see Example 2.2). Smlarly, Theorem 3.12() guaratees the exstece of a super-evyfree partto wth maxmum evy (2 v 1)/(2 v + 1) = 1/7, whereas eve smaller maxmum evy 2 5 s possble (cf. Example 3.3). 4. Mmax-evy equaltes for measures wth atoms For atomless measures, far ad evy-free parttos always exst (cf. Theorem 3.12), as a cosequece of the covexty of the value ad evy matrx rages, respectvely (Proposto 2.4, Theorem 3.5). For measures wth atoms, however, geeral the sets of F-feasble value matrces ad evy matrces are ot covex, ad ether far or evy-free parttos exst (cf. Examples 2.3 ad 3.3()). It s the purpose of ths secto to establsh bouds o the ocovexty, ad upper bouds o evy based o the mass of the largest atom, aalogous to the bouds foud [7] for value matrces. The uderlyg tuto s smply that f the atoms are all very small, the the evy-matrx rage must be early covex, ad hece early evy-free parttos must exst. For α (0, 1), let P(α) deote the set of value fuctos wth o atom mass greater tha α. That s, { P(α) = v: v s a probablty measure o (Ω, F ) } wth v(a) α for all v-atoms A F. The ext theorem gves a upper boud o how far from covex the set of feasble evy matrces ca be as a fucto of the maxmum atom sze ad the umber of measures. Here co(s) deotes the covex hull of the set S. Theorem 4.1. Fx 1 ad α (0, 1), ad let v P(α), = 1,...,. The for every C = (c j ),j= 1 co(m E) there exsts P Π wth 3/2 e,j (P) c,j α(2) for all, j = 1,...,.

Proof. Fx C = (c,j ),j=1 co(m E). By Lemma 3.4, there exsts D = (d,j ),j =1 co(m V ) such that c,j = d,j d, for all, j = 1,...,. (4.1) Sce v 1,..., v P(α), by a theorem of Allaart [2, Theorem 2.11()], the Hausdorff eucldea dstace betwee M V ad ts covex hull s o more tha 2α 3/2,sothere exsts M = (m,j ),j=1 M V wth [ ] 1/2 2 3/2 (m,j d,j ) 2α. (4.2),j=1 Sce M M V, there exsts a partto P = (P 1,..., P ) Π wth v (P j ) = m,j for all, j = 1,...,. (4.3) m Sce max{ a 2 1,..., a m } ( k=1 a k ) 1/2, (4.2) ad (4.3) mply that 3/2 v (P j ) d,j 2α for, j = 1,...,. (4.4) By defto of evy, e,j (P) = v (P j ) v (P ), so (4.1) mples that e,j (P) c,j = v (P j ) v (P ) (d,j d, ) 3/2 3/2 v (P j ) d,j + v (P ) d, 2 2α = α(2), where the last equalty follows by (4.4). Allaart has also foud the sharp boud for the Hausdorff dstace betwee the partto rage ad ts covex hull [1, Theorem 2.5] terms of α, whch has drect applcato to maxm-share but ot to mmax-evy equaltes. The ext result s a example of a applcato of Theorem 4.1 to establsh the exstece of evy-free parttos some fardvso problems wth atoms. Recall that v ad v are the total masses of the smallest measure domatg, ad the largest measure domated by, respectvely, all the measures v 1,..., v (cf. Example 3.11). Theorem 4.2. Fx 1 ad α (0, 1), ad let v P(α) for all = 1,...,.Thef ether ( +v +1 () α< ) ( v +1 (2) 3/2 or v +3 ) () α< (2) 3/2, +v 1 the there exsts a super-evy-free partto P Π. Proof. To see (), assume wthout loss of geeralty, that ( + v + 1)> 0, for otherwse the cocluso s trval. Elargg Ω f ecessary (e.g., replacg A by A [0, 1] for every v-atom A F), t may be assumed wthout loss of geeralty that there exsts a σ -algebra Fˆ F, ad atomless measures u 1,..., u o (Ω, Fˆ ) such that

u = v ad u (P ) = v (P ) for all P F. (4.5) Lettg {( ) } Mˆ E = u (Pˆj ) : Pˆ1,..., Pˆ Fˆ, Pˆ = Ω, Pˆ Pˆj = f = j,,j=1 t follows by the defto of {u } ad Fˆ that ˆM E = co(m E ). (4.6) By (4.5) ad Theorem 3.12(), there exsts a partto Pˆ = (Pˆ1,..., Pˆ) wth Pˆ Fˆ for all, ad satsfyg u 1 u (Pˆj ) u (Pˆ) for all = 1,...,, j. (4.7) u + 1 By (4.6), (u (Pˆj )),j= 1 co(m E), so by Theorem 4.1 there exsts a partto P Π wth ( ) ( ) 3/2 + v + 1 3/2 3/2 e,j (P) u (Pˆj ) u (Pˆ) α(2) < (2) (2) v + 1 + v + 1 =, = j, v + 1 so by (4.7) ad the fact that u = v, + v + 1 e,j (P)< + u (Pˆj ) u (Pˆ) 0, v + 1 so e max (P)< 0ad P s super-evy-free, whch proves (). The argumet for () s smlar, usg Theorem 3.12(v). Example 4.3. Suppose that v 1 ad ( v 2 are probablty measures wth v = 5/4. If o atom v +1 v ) 1 or v 2 has mass greater tha 2+ 2 v (4) 3/2 +1 = 1/56, the there s a super-evy-free partto. (Compare wth Example 3.13, where v 1 ad v 2 are atomless wth the same outer measure v = 5/4.) The ext proposto, whch s recorded here for ease of referece, gves the sharp guarateed maxm share as a fucto of maxmum atom sze ad umber of measures; t wll be used here to establsh upper bouds o maxmum evy also as a fucto of atom sze ad umber of measures. Defto 4.4. V : [0, 1] [0, 1] s the uque ocreasg fucto satsfyg V (x) = 1 k( 1)x for all x [(k + 1)k 1 ((k + 1) 1) 1,(k 1) 1 ], k = 1, 2,... Proposto 4.5 [9]. Fx 1 ad let v 1,..., v P(α). The there exsts a partto P = (P 1,..., P ) Π satsfyg v (P ) V (α) for all = 1,...,, ad ths boud s attaed.

Theorem 4.6. Fx 1 ad α (0, 1) ad let v 1,..., v P(α). The there exst parttos P (1), P (2) Π satsfyg () e max (P (1) ) α(2) 3/2 ; ad () e max (P (2) ) 1 2V (α). Proof. Let u 1,..., u, F,ad ˆ Mˆ E be as the proof of Theorem 4.2. Theorem 3.8() mples the exstece of a evy-free partto Pˆ for u 1,..., u, ad va correspodece (4.6), ths mples that there s a elemet C = (c,j ),j=1 co(m E) wth c,j 0for all, j = 1,...,. Cocluso () the follows mmedately from Theorem 4.1. To see (), let P = (P 1,..., P ) Π be as Proposto 4.5. By addtvty of the measures {v }, v (P j ) 1 v (P ) for all j, so v (P j ) v (P ) 1 2v (P ) 1 2V (α). Example 4.7. Let α = 0.01, that s, o partcpat values ay crumb more tha oe hudredth of the total value of the cake. If there are two players, the boud Theorem 4.6() s 0.08 ad checkg that V 2 (0.01) = 50/101, the boud () s 1/101, whch s sharper. If there are three players, the the boud () s (0.01)6 3/2 = 0.1470, ad that () (checkg that V 3 (0.01) = 33/101) s 35/101, whch ths case s substatally weaker tha the boud gve by (). Refereces [1] P. Allaart, A sharp ocovexty boud for partto rages of vector measures wth atoms, J. Math. Aal. Appl. 235 (1999) 326 348. [2] P. Allaart, Bouds o the o-covexty of rages of vector measures wth atoms, Cotemp. Math. 234 (1999) 1 11. [3] J. Barbael, Super evy-free cake dvso ad depedece of measures, J. Math. Aal. Appl. 197 (1996) 54 60. [4] S. Brams, A. Taylor, A evy-free cake dvso protocol, Amer. Math. Mothly 102 (1996) 9 18. [5] S. Brams, A. Taylor, Far Dvso: From Cake-Cuttg to Dspute Resoluto, Cambrdge Uv. Press, Cambrdge, UK, 1996. [6] L. Dubs, E. Spaer, How to cut a cake farly, Amer. Math. Mothly 68 (1961) 1 17. [7] J. Elto, T. Hll, A geeralzato of Lyapouov s covexty theorem to measures wth atoms, Proc. Amer. Math. Soc. 296 (1987) 297 304. [8] J. Elto, T. Hll, R. Kertz, Optmal parttog equaltes for oatomc probablty measures, Tras. Amer. Math. Soc. 296 (1986) 703 725. [9] T. Hll, Parttog geeral probablty measures, A. Probab. 15 (1987) 804 813. [10] T. Hll, A sharp parttog-equalty for o-atomc probablty measures based o the mass of the fmum of the measures, Prob. Theory Related Felds 75 (1987) 143 147. [11] T. Hll, Parttog equaltes probablty ad statstcs, IMS Lecture Notes 22 (1993) 116 132. [12] J. Legut, Iequaltes for α-optmal parttog of a measurable space, Proc. Amer. Math. Soc. 104 (1988) 1249 1251. [13] J. Legut, M. Wlczysk, Optmal parttog of a measurable space, Proc. Amer. Math. Soc. 104 (1988) 262 264. [14] J. Robertso, W. Webb, Cake-Cuttg Algorthms, A.K. Peters, Natck, MA, 1998. [15] D. Weller, Far dvso of a measurable space, J. Math. Ecoom. 14 (1985) 5 17.