The Dynamic Correlation Between Growth and Unemployment. Abstract

Similar documents
Can the Kydland Prescott Model Pass the Cogley Nason Test?

A Critical Note on the Forecast Error Variance Decomposition

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Threshold effects in Okun s Law: a panel data analysis. Abstract

EXAMINATION OF RELATIONSHIPS BETWEEN TIME SERIES BY WAVELETS: ILLUSTRATION WITH CZECH STOCK AND INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION DATA

Lecture 2. Business Cycle Measurement. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD II Semestre 2017 Last updated: August 18, 2017

1 The Basic RBC Model

Macroeconomics Theory II

Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions

Shyh-Wei Chen Department of Finance, Dayeh University. Abstract

Discussion of Riccardo DiCecio \Comovement: It's not a Puzzle" Matteo Iacoviello Boston College

RBC Model with Indivisible Labor. Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 4. VARs With Long-Run Restrictions

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

Macroeconomics Field Exam. August 2007

Euro-indicators Working Group

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018

Lecture 1: Information and Structural VARs

1. Shocks. This version: February 15, Nr. 1

An Anatomy of the Business Cycle Data

This note introduces some key concepts in time series econometrics. First, we

Lars Svensson 2/16/06. Y t = Y. (1) Assume exogenous constant government consumption (determined by government), G t = G<Y. (2)

The Dark Corners of the Labor Market

Macroeconomics Theory II

Macroeconomics Theory II

1.2. Structural VARs

When Do Wold Orderings and Long-Run Recursive Identifying Restrictions Yield Identical Results?

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models

The Price Puzzle: Mixing the Temporary and Permanent Monetary Policy Shocks.

Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme?

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

Dynamic Factor Models Cointegration and Error Correction Mechanisms

Perceived productivity and the natural rate of interest

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

S TICKY I NFORMATION Fabio Verona Bank of Finland, Monetary Policy and Research Department, Research Unit

Identifying SVARs with Sign Restrictions and Heteroskedasticity

Introduction to Macroeconomics

News, Noise, and Fluctuations: An Empirical Exploration

ECON 4160: Econometrics-Modelling and Systems Estimation Lecture 9: Multiple equation models II

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Comments on News and Noise in the Post-Great Recession Recovery by Renato Faccini and Leonardo Melosi

Estimating and Accounting for the Output Gap with Large Bayesian Vector Autoregressions

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Looking for the stars

Formulating, Estimating, and Solving Dynamic Equilibrium Models: an Introduction. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Trend-Cycle Decompositions

Aggregate Supply. A Nonvertical AS Curve. implications for unemployment, rms pricing behavior, the real wage and the markup

Problem Set 2: Sketch of Answers

Oil price and macroeconomy in Russia. Abstract

Identifying Aggregate Liquidity Shocks with Monetary Policy Shocks: An Application using UK Data

Testing an Autoregressive Structure in Binary Time Series Models

Technology Shocks in the New Keynesian Model

Warwick Business School Forecasting System. Summary. Ana Galvao, Anthony Garratt and James Mitchell November, 2014

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme?

Stochastic Trends & Economic Fluctuations

Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo

Combining Macroeconomic Models for Prediction

Indeterminacy, Aggregate Demand, and the Real Business Cycle

A Comparison of Business Cycle Regime Nowcasting Performance between Real-time and Revised Data. By Arabinda Basistha (West Virginia University)

Mortenson Pissarides Model

Frequency Domain and Filtering

News-Shock Subroutine for Prof. Uhlig s Toolkit

1. Stochastic Processes and Stationarity

Do Long Run Restrictions Identify Supply and Demand Disturbances?

The Real Business Cycle Model

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Decomposing the Effects of Monetary Policy Using an External Instruments SVAR

Are Structural VARs Useful Guides for Developing Business Cycle Theories? by Larry Christiano

A Variant of Uzawa's Theorem. Abstract

Monetary Economics. Lecture 15: unemployment in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

Computational Macroeconomics. Prof. Dr. Maik Wolters Friedrich Schiller University Jena

The Neo Fisher Effect and Exiting a Liquidity Trap

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

Nowcasting Norwegian GDP

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

WORKING PAPER NO NON-STATIONARY HOURS IN A DSGE MODEL. Yongsung Chang Seoul National University. Taeyoung Doh University of Pennsylvania

Inflation Persistence Revisited

ESRI Research Note Nowcasting and the Need for Timely Estimates of Movements in Irish Output

NON-LINEARITIES AND HYSTERESIS IN OECD UNEMPLOYMENT *

Closed economy macro dynamics: AD-AS model and RBC model.

Comparison of detrending methods

Assessing Structural VAR s

Using frequency domain techniques with US real GNP data: A Tour D Horizon

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING

SMOOTHIES: A Toolbox for the Exact Nonlinear and Non-Gaussian Kalman Smoother *

Nonperforming Loans and Rules of Monetary Policy

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1 Solutions. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Do financial variables help forecasting inflation and real activity in the EURO area?

Economics 701 Advanced Macroeconomics I Project 1 Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 2011

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Research Brief December 2018

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

B y t = γ 0 + Γ 1 y t + ε t B(L) y t = γ 0 + ε t ε t iid (0, D) D is diagonal

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case.

A Primer on Vector Autoregressions

LECTURE 3 The Effects of Monetary Changes: Statistical Identification. September 5, 2018

Purchasing power parity: A nonlinear multivariate perspective. Abstract

Transcription:

The Dynamic Correlation Between Growth and Unemployment Fabien Tripier MODEM Université Paris X Nanterre Abstract We apply the measure of dynamic correlation developed by Croux, Forni and Reichlin (2001) [A measure of comovement for economic variables: theory and empirics. Review of Economics and Statistics 83, 232 241] to the relation between the quarterly rates of unemployment and labor productivity growth for the post war United States economy. The application of the dynamic correlation reveals that these variables are strongly related, but in a different manner according to the frequencies considered: negatively at low frequencies and positively at business cycle frequencies. I would like to thank Julien Matheron and Tristan Pierre Maury for their helpful comments. Any remaining errors are mine. Citation: Tripier, Fabien, (2002) "The Dynamic Correlation Between Growth and Unemployment." Economics Bulletin, Vol. 5, No. 4 pp. 1 9 Submitted: December 11, 2001. Accepted: April 6, 2002. URL: http://www.economicsbulletin.com/2002/volume5/eb 01E30001A.pdf

1 Introduction In modern macroeconomics, distinct methodologies have been developed to study the relation between productivity growth and unemployment depending on whether we are interested in the short-run or the long-run (see the both theoretical and empirical contributions of Christiano and Eichenbaum, 1992, for the short-run and of Bean and Pissarides, 1993, for the long-run). In this paper, we follow an alternative approach and propose to deal with the overall comovements between these two variables in an uniþed setup by means of spectral analysis. To do so, we resort to the notion of dynamic correlation developed by Croux et al. (2001). The dynamic correlation is deþnedinsection2andappliedinsection3totherelation between the quarterly rates of unemployment and labor productivity growth for the postwar United-States economy. It permits us to describe the sign and the amplitude of their comovements according to different frequencies: from long-run relations to shortrun movements. If we look only at the contemporaneous comovements of the raw series, we would conclude that these two variables are weakly or not correlated. The application of the dynamic correlation reveals that these variables are strongly related, but in a different manner according to the frequencies considered. The dynamic correlation is negative at frequency zero, crosses the zero value at the frequency which corresponds to a cycle with a period of eight years, and reaches a peak at the frequency which corresponds to a cycle with a period of four years. We then conclude that the rates of labor productivity growth and unemployment are negatively related in the long-run and positively in the short-run. This conclusion is discussed in section 4. In particular, we highlight the contribution of our empirical results to the theoretical controversy on the sign of the structural relations between growth and unemployment. Section 5 concludes. 2 DeÞnition This section takes up the Croux et al. (2001) deþnition of dynamic correlation in the particular case of a bivariate analysis (for more than two series, the authors introduce the notion of cohesion). Spectral analysis consists in depicting the covariance matrices in the frequency domain instead of the time domain. This approach has become very popular for describing the dynamic properties of univariate series through their spectrum. The dynamic correlation permits us to extend this approach to the comovements between two series in a more convenient way than traditional indeces used in time series analysis. Consider two zero-mean real stochastic and stationary processes y and x. Let s (ω) be the spectral density matrix of the covariance matrices at frequency π ω π. The spectrum of x and y are denoted s x (ω) and s y (ω), and the cross spectrum between y and 1

x is denoted s xy (ω). Let us introduce the coherency between x and y, denoted h xy (ω), as a Þrst comovement index. It is deþned by s xy (ω) h xy (ω) = q (1) sx (ω) s y (ω) It measures the correlation between the complex representation of x t and y t at frequency ω. Unfortunately, since the cross spectrum has an imaginary part this index is not real. To obtain a more convenient measure of comovement, the squared coherency h 2 xy (ω) is then generally preferred in the literature. It is deþned by h 2 xy (ω) = s xy (ω) 2 (2) s x (ω) s y (ω) and can be interpreted as the contribution of the frequency ω to the squared correlation coefficient. Nevertheless, this index is invariant with respect to a shift in the time process: h 2 xy (ω) is equal to h 2 zy (ω) where z t = x t+k and k accounts for a shift in time process 1. To avoid this limitative feature, Croux et al. (2001) propose to take the real part of the coherency, and call it the dynamic correlation c xy (ω) ρ xy (ω) = q (3) sx (ω) s y (ω) for 0 ω π. c xy (ω) =real(s xy (ω)) is the cospectrum between x and y. Contrary to the coherency it measures the correlation between the real waves of x t and y t instead of the complex ones. As emphasized by Croux and al. (2001), the dynamic correlation has the advantage of being real, taking values between 1 and 1, and being dependant upon a shift in the time process 2. To illustrate the differences between the dynamic correlation and the squared coherency, an example is developed in the appendix. We can also deþne the dynamic correlation on a frequency band. Let Ω be a frequency band which satisþes the following deþnition: Ω = Ω + Ω,whereΩ + =[ω 1, ω 2 ) and Ω =[ ω 1, ω 2 ) and 0 ω 1 ω 2 π. The static correlation coefficient between x t and y t over the frequency band Ω is deþned by ρ xy (Ω + )= R Ω + c xy (ω) dω q R Ω + s x (ω) dω RΩ + s y (ω) dω = RΩ + ρ xy (ω) q s x (ω) s y (ω)dω q R Ω + s x (ω) dω R Ω + s y (ω) dω For the particular band ω 1 =0and ω 2 = π, ρ xy (Ω + ) is the static contemporaneous correlation coefficient. In other cases, the simple mean of the dynamic correlation values over a band is not a consistent measure of the static correlation coefficient. 1 More precisely, the information encompassed in the phase on the delay between the comovements is lost (see Brockwell and Davis, 1991, ch. 11). 2 In fact, it depends only on the value of such a shift and not on its sign: ρ z(k)y (ω) is equal to ρ z( k)y (ω) where z t (k) =x t k. (4) 2

3 Application Our data set comes from the Bureau of Labor Statistics and covers the period 1948:1-2000:4 at a quarterly periodicity for the United-States. The Þrst data is the Þrst differenced logged labor productivity and the second data is the unemployment rate (also taken in logarithm). They are denoted g and u, respectively. For both series a constant is removed. To discuss the results, we retain a standard decomposition of the frequency band. Long-run comovements belong to the low frequency band [0, π/16] (which corresponds to cycles with a period longer than 8 years). Business cycle comovements belong to the high frequency band [π/16, π/3] (which corresponds to cycles with a period between 1.5 and 8 years). As traditional in the literature, we neglect movements at shorter horizons, on the frequency band [π/3, π]. The computation of the dynamic correlation requires to estimate the empirical spectral density matrix of the process {g t,u t }. To do so, the empirical autocovariance function is estimated and smoothed with a Barlett window equal to T,whereT is the number of observations. The dynamic correlation deþned by (3) is depicted on Þgure 1 and the static correlation coefficient per frequency band deþned by (4) is reported in table 1. Over the frequency band Ω + =[0, π], ρ gu (Ω + ) is the static correlation coefficient between g t and u t. The corresponding value appears to be approximately zero, around 0.06. This result hides strong differences according to the frequency considered. The dynamic correlation takes its smallest value at frequency zero (around 0.375) and reaches a peak (around 0.663) near the frequency ω = π/7.5, which corresponds to movements about 15 quarters. Between these two frequencies, the dynamic correlation is monotonically increasing and crosses the zero line around the frequency π/16. Its values are always negative over the frequency band Ω + =[0, π/16] and always positive over the frequency band Ω + =[π/16, π/3]. Notice that for the last frequency band, there is no other peak or dip in the dynamic correlation. The consequences for the static correlation coefficient are straightforward. Whereas the static correlation coefficient is close to zero for the frequency bands [0, π] and [π/16, π], it exhibits high absolute values for the two others frequency bands considered: [0, π/16] and [π/16, π/3]. The static correlation coefficient is negative ( 0.26) for long-run movements and positive (0.33) for the business cycle movements. In conclusion, the rates of unemployment and labor productivity growth do not comove in the same manner on all the frequency bands. They comove negatively at low frequencies and positively at high frequencies. To assess the robustness of these results, we propose to retain alternative methods of estimation of the spectral density matrix (see Wei, 1990, for an exposition). Table 2 and Þgure 2 report the results obtained with alternative estimation methods 3

of the spectral q density matrix. We Þrst consider two alternative values for the Bartlett window ( T/2 and 2 T ), we then apply a Hanning window (with a size of T ), and Þnally we estimate a bivariate VAR and deduce the corresponding spectral density matrix. The pattern of the results does not change with the method of estimation. For these four estimation methods, the dynamic correlation is negative at frequency zero and reaches a peak at business cycle frequencies. Nevertheless, the previously described pattern is minored with the small Bartlett window and reinforced with the three other estimation methods. In particular, the VAR estimation delivers the highest static correlation coef- Þcient per frequency bands. We conclude that our basic results are robust to changes in the estimation of the spectral density matrix. 4 Discussion Our results on business cycle frequencies recover the puzzling Dunlop-Tarshis observation: contrary to the prediction of standard real business cycle models, the empirical correlation between the cyclical components of labor productivity and employment is not strongly positive, but rather close to zero or negative (see Hansen and Wright, 1992). Our results conþrm this Þnding by stating it the frequency domain. For long-run movements, it is more difficult to link our results to the literature due to the lack of studies on this dimension. A notable exception is Staiger et al. (2001) who confront the univariate trends of productivity growth and unemployment rate and conclude at a striking and intriguing negative correlation but make also caution about the relevance of the apparent correlation. Indeed, as already shown by Caballero (1993) such results depend crucially on the Þlter s choice to deþne the univariate trends. The results obtained in this paper conþrm the Þnding of Staiger et al. (2001), but since we use spectral analysis our conclusion is not contingent upon a particular decomposition between the cyclical and trend components. The theoretical implications of our results are straightforward for the short-run. A wide literature has been developed to account for the Dunlop-Tarshis observation (for example, Christiano and Eichenbaum, 1992, suggest to consider nontechnology shocks whereas Gali, 1999, puts forward the role of nominal rigidities). Our results conþrm the importance of this issue and could be fruitfully used to assess the relevance of the different theoretical explanations by studying their spectral predictions on the dynamic correlation. For long-run analysis, our results could contribute to the debate on the structural relation between growth and unemployment. Aghion and Howitt (1994) gave rise to a controversy about the sign of this relation by describing the steady state adverse effects of the long-run growth rate on the equilibrium rate of unemployment. Our results provide evidence against this view and suggest that these variables are more probably negatively related in the long-run. Nevertheless, Aghion and Howitt (1994) and the subsequent literature consider only the steady state properties of deterministic models. Further researches 4

should then be devoted to study stochastic versions of these models in order to confront their spectral properties to the empirical relation described here. 5 Conclusion In this paper, we applied the dynamic correlation measure developed by Croux et al. (2001) to describe the relation between the quarterly rates of unemployment and productivity growth for the post-war U.S. economy. The approximately zero value of the static correlation coefficient between the raw series hides strong differences between low and high frequencies: the correlation is negative for long-run movements and positive at business cycle frequencies. We then discussed the usefulness of this approach for assessing the relevance of alternative theoretical explanations of the relation between growth and unemployment either in the short-run or in the long-run. References Aghion, P., and Howitt, P. (1994) Growth and unemployment, Review of Economic Studies 61, 477-494. Bean, C.R., and Pissarides, C.A. (1993) Unemployment, consumption and growth, European Economic Review 37, 837-859. Brockwell, P.J., and Davis, R.A. (1991), Time Series: Theory and Methods, Springer- Verlag: New-York. Caballero, R.J. (1993) Comments on Unemployment, consumption and growth, by C.R. Bean and C.A. Pissarides, European Economic Review 37, 855-860. Christian, L.J., and Eichenbaum, M. (1992) Current Real-Business-Cycle theories and aggregate labor-market ßuctuations, American Economic Review 82, 430-450. Croux, C., Forni, M., and Reichlin, L. (2001) A measure of comovement for economic indicators: theory and empirics, Review of Economics and Statistics 83, 232 241. Gali, J. (1999) Technology, employment, and the business cycle: do technology shocks explain aggregate ßuctuations?, American Economic Review 89, 249-271. Hansen, G.D., and Wrigth, W. (1992) The labor market in real business cycle theory, Federal Reserve Bank of Mineapolis Quarterly Review 16, 2-12. Staiger, J., Stock, J.H., and Watson, M.W. (2001) Prices, wages and the U.S. NAIRU in the 1990s, NBER Working Paper 8320. Wei, S.W. (1990) Times Series Analysis. Univariate and Multivariate Methods, Addison- Wesley. 5

Appendix To illustrate the properties of dynamic correlation, let us take an example developed by Brockwell and Davis (1991, ch. 11) x t = ε 1t y t = ε 2t + bx t λ where ε 1t and ε 2t aretwowhitenoisewithavarianceσ 2. The spectral density matrix is " s (ω) = σ2 2π 1 be iλω be iλω 1+b 2 and the squared coherency and dynamic correlation are h 2 xy (ω) = b 2 ρ xy (ω) = # 1+b 2 b cos (λω) 1+b 2 From this simple example, we can see how the dynamic correlation is a more informative index than the squared coherency. The squared coherency depends only on the absolute value of the parameter b, that is the strength of the comovements. The dynamic correlation provides two additional information. The Þrst one is the sign of b: the dynamic correlationgivesinformationbothonthestrengthandthesignofcomovement. The second one is the inßuence of the absolute value of λ: whereas the squared coherency is constant, the dynamic correlation varies with ω for ω [0, π]. To obtain a measure of comovements that gives information about the sign of λ, we would have to compute the phase between x and y. Finally, notice that over the frequency band Ω + =[0, π], wehave ρ xy (Ω + )=0which is natural since the static contemporaneous correlation coefficient between x t and y t is zero. 6

0.8 0.4 ρ gu (ω) 0-0.4-0.8 0 pi/16 pi/3 pi ω Figure 1: Dynamic correlation between g and u for the frequencies ω [0, π]. Table1:Staticcorrelationcoefficient between g and u over the frequency bands Ω +. Frequency bands Ω + [0, π] [0, π/16] [π/16, π/3] [π/3, π] Values of ρ gu (Ω + ) 0.060 0.255 0.328 0.020 7

0.8 Bartlett window 10 Bartlett window 20 Hanning window 10 VAR with 6 lags 0.4 ρ gu (ω) 0-0.4-0.8 0 pi/16 pi/3 pi ω Figure 2: Dynamic correlation between g and u for the frequencies ω [0, π] for alternative estimation methods of the spectral density matrix. Estimation methods: Bartlett window 10 (solid line), Bartlett window 20 (dotted line), Hanning window 15 (dashdot line), and VAR with six lags (dashed line). Table 2: Static correlation coefficient between g and u over the frequency bands Ω + for alternative estimation methods of the spectral density matrix. Frequency bands Ω + [0, π] [0, π/16] [π/16, π/3] [π/3, π] Values of ρ gu (Ω + ) using the method: Bartlett window 10 0.060 0.132 0.226 0.006 Bartlett window 20 0.060 0.328 0.405 0.025 Hanning window 15 0.060 0.274 0.357 0.101 VAR with six lags 0.035 0.460 0.514 0.139 8