Multivariate GARCH models.

Similar documents
Financial Econometrics Lecture 6: Testing the CAPM model

Lecture 8: Multivariate GARCH and Conditional Correlation Models

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1

Intro VEC and BEKK Example Factor Models Cond Var and Cor Application Ref 4. MGARCH

R = µ + Bf Arbitrage Pricing Model, APM

GARCH Models. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. December Rossi GARCH Financial Econometrics / 50

Volatility. Gerald P. Dwyer. February Clemson University

Regression: Ordinary Least Squares

The Slow Convergence of OLS Estimators of α, β and Portfolio. β and Portfolio Weights under Long Memory Stochastic Volatility

The Size and Power of Four Tests for Detecting Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity in the Presence of Serial Correlation

Ross (1976) introduced the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) as an alternative to the CAPM.

Sample Exam Questions for Econometrics

Econ671 Factor Models: Principal Components

Financial Econometrics Return Predictability

ECONOMETRIC REVIEWS, 5(1), (1986) MODELING THE PERSISTENCE OF CONDITIONAL VARIANCES: A COMMENT

ECON3327: Financial Econometrics, Spring 2016

Lecture 6: Univariate Volatility Modelling: ARCH and GARCH Models

Multivariate Time Series Analysis and Its Applications [Tsay (2005), chapter 8]

MFE Financial Econometrics 2018 Final Exam Model Solutions

Financial Times Series. Lecture 12

Stochastic Processes

Network Connectivity and Systematic Risk

State-space Model. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. November Rossi State-space Model Fin. Econometrics / 53

New Introduction to Multiple Time Series Analysis

Generalized Autoregressive Score Models

ASSET PRICING MODELS

Vector Auto-Regressive Models

Multivariate GARCH Models. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia

VAR Models and Applications

MEASURING THE CORRELATION OF SHOCKS BETWEEN THE UK AND THE CORE OF EUROPE

Switching Regime Estimation

Lecture 9: Markov Switching Models

Estimation of Vector Error Correction Model with GARCH Errors. Koichi Maekawa Hiroshima University of Economics

GARCH Models Estimation and Inference

Empirical properties of large covariance matrices in finance

Structural VAR Models and Applications

Heteroskedasticity in Time Series

GARCH Models Estimation and Inference

A simple graphical method to explore tail-dependence in stock-return pairs

Econometric Forecasting

9. Multivariate Linear Time Series (II). MA6622, Ernesto Mordecki, CityU, HK, 2006.

Nonlinear Bivariate Comovements of Asset Prices: Theory and Tests

Errata for Campbell, Financial Decisions and Markets, 01/02/2019.

Smooth Transition Quantile Capital Asset Pricing Models with Heteroscedasticity

Factor Models for Asset Returns. Prof. Daniel P. Palomar

Optimal Investment Strategies: A Constrained Optimization Approach

Structural Analysis of Portfolio Risk Using. Beta Impulse Response Functions. April Abstract

Time Series Modeling of Financial Data. Prof. Daniel P. Palomar

Multivariate modelling of long memory processes with common components

Multivariate Volatility, Dependence and Copulas

JOURNAL OF MANAGEMENT SCIENCES IN CHINA. R t. t = 0 + R t - 1, R t - 2, ARCH. j 0, j = 1,2,, p

Time Series Models and Inference. James L. Powell Department of Economics University of California, Berkeley

ZHAW Zurich University of Applied Sciences. Bachelor s Thesis Estimating Multi-Beta Pricing Models With or Without an Intercept:

Financial Econometrics

Multivariate Tests of the CAPM under Normality

Symmetric btw positive & negative prior returns. where c is referred to as risk premium, which is expected to be positive.

Modern Portfolio Theory with Homogeneous Risk Measures

Notes on Time Series Modeling

1 Linear Difference Equations

Multivariate Time Series: VAR(p) Processes and Models

GARCH Models Estimation and Inference. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia

New meeting times for Econ 210D Mondays 8:00-9:20 a.m. in Econ 300 Wednesdays 11:00-12:20 in Econ 300

Final Exam Financial Data Analysis at the University of Freiburg (Winter Semester 2008/2009) Friday, November 14, 2008,

Introduction to ARMA and GARCH processes

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 3

Simultaneous Equations and Weak Instruments under Conditionally Heteroscedastic Disturbances

(I AL BL 2 )z t = (I CL)ζ t, where

Empirical Methods in Finance Section 2 - The CAPM Model

B y t = γ 0 + Γ 1 y t + ε t B(L) y t = γ 0 + ε t ε t iid (0, D) D is diagonal

Web Appendix to Multivariate High-Frequency-Based Volatility (HEAVY) Models

Multivariate Distributions

Multivariate ARCH Models: Finite Sample Properties of QML Estimators and an Application to an LM-Type Test

VAR Model. (k-variate) VAR(p) model (in the Reduced Form): Y t-2. Y t-1 = A + B 1. Y t + B 2. Y t-p. + ε t. + + B p. where:

X t = a t + r t, (7.1)

Financial Econometrics

Empirical Market Microstructure Analysis (EMMA)

International Monetary Policy Spillovers

Identifying Aggregate Liquidity Shocks with Monetary Policy Shocks: An Application using UK Data

1 Teaching notes on structural VARs.

Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics & Econometrics

A Non-Parametric Approach of Heteroskedasticity Robust Estimation of Vector-Autoregressive (VAR) Models

CHICAGO: A Fast and Accurate Method for Portfolio Risk Calculation

6. The econometrics of Financial Markets: Empirical Analysis of Financial Time Series. MA6622, Ernesto Mordecki, CityU, HK, 2006.

Lecture 2: Univariate Time Series

ECON4515 Finance theory 1 Diderik Lund, 5 May Perold: The CAPM

STAT Financial Time Series

Time-Varying Vector Autoregressive Models with Structural Dynamic Factors

9) Time series econometrics

State-space Model. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. November Rossi State-space Model Financial Econometrics / 49

Estimating Global Bank Network Connectedness

11. Further Issues in Using OLS with TS Data

This note introduces some key concepts in time series econometrics. First, we

Chapter 5. Analysis of Multiple Time Series. 5.1 Vector Autoregressions

Specification Test Based on the Hansen-Jagannathan Distance with Good Small Sample Properties

A Guide to Modern Econometric:

Financial Econometrics Short Course Lecture 3 Multifactor Pricing Model

TESTING FOR CO-INTEGRATION

GMM and SMM. 1. Hansen, L Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators, Econometrica, 50, p

Estimating Covariance Using Factorial Hidden Markov Models

Transcription:

Multivariate GARCH models. Financial market volatility moves together over time across assets and markets. Recognizing this commonality through a multivariate modeling framework leads to obvious gains in efficiency. Following Bollerslev et al (1986) consider a multivariate extension of the GARCH(p,q) as follows: Consider a system of n regression equations, vech(h t )=C y t = μ u t px A i vech(u t i u 0 t i) i=1 qx B i vech(h t i ) where u t I t 1 ~N(0,H t ) In this formulation, H t = E(u t u 0 t I t 1) is the n n conditional variance matrix associated with the error vector u 0 t and vech(h t ) denotes the (n(n1))/2 1 vector of all the unique elements of H t obtained by stacking the lower triangle of H t 1. Also μ is n 1 C is (n(n 1))/2 1 i=1 A 1,A 2,...A p,b 1,...B q are (n(n 1))/2 (n(n 1))/2 Example: ABivariateGARCH(1,1) Since most empirical applications of the model have restricted attention to multivariate GARCH(1,1) systems. We first consider the easiest example is the simple bivariate process which depends on its conditional variance covariance matrix (H t ). 1 In general if a c A = b d Then a vech(a) = b c d For a symmetric matrix a c B = c d n n is standardto write the vector using either the lower or the upper triangular information vech(b) = a c d (n (n1)/2) 1 1

where xt w t = μx μ w εt ν t V t 1 (x t ) COV t 1 (x t w t ) V t 1 (w t ) = c x c xw c w a 1 a 2 a 3 a 4 a 5 a 6 (ε t 1) 2 (ε t 1 ν t 1 ) a 7 a 8 a 9 (ν t 1 ) 2 V t 2 (x t 1 ) COV t 2 (x t 1 w t 1 ) V t 2 (w t 1 ) b 1 b 2 b 3 b 4 b 5 b 6 b 7 b 8 b 9 Estimation of this model may be obtained by ML using numerical procedures. Two main problems with the estimation of these type of models should be apparent: 1. As its stands this model is very general, requiring a large number of parameters to be estimated. The simplest general model has 23 parameters. 2. We should ensure H t to be positive definite. (see Bera and Higgins). Various simplifications have been suggested to account for (1) and (2). A Diagonal Vech Parameterization (Bollerslev, Engle and Wooldridge (1982)) A natural simplification is to assume that each covariance depends only on its own past values and innovations, i.e., that A i and B i are diagonal. Then Each element of H t follows an univariate GARCH model driven by the corresponding cross product u t u 0 t. The implied conditional covariance matrix is always positive definite if the matrices of parameters cx c xw, c xw c w a1 a 5, a 5 a 9 b1 b 5 b 5 b 9 are all positive definite. This can be ensured by doing simple Cholesky transformations to each of these matrices. A Quadratic Specification, (Engle and Kroner(1995)) An alternative to the diagonal vech parameterization is to achieve a positive definite covariance matrix is the quadratic parameterization 2

H t = C 0 C A0u t 1 u 0 t 1A B 0 H t 1 B. where C is a lower triangular with n(n 1)/2 parameters and A and B are square matrices with n 2 parameters each. Weak restrictions on A and B guarantee that the H t is always positive definite. A Constant-Correlation Specification, (Bollerslev(1990)) This specification is similar to the diagonal specification, but imposes the restriction that the correlation between the assets is constant. COV t 1 (x t w t )=ρ p V t 1 (x t )V t 1 (w t ) Where ρ is also estimated with the rest of the parameter set. The conditions to get a positive definite matrix are as in the diagonal case. Stationarity and Co-persistence Stationarity The conditions for stationarity and moment convergence for the multivariate case are similar to those discussed in the univariate case. Specially, for the multivariate vech GARCH(1,1) model defined above, the minimum square error forecast for vech(h t ) as of time s<ttakes the form t s 1 X E s (vech(h t )) = [ (A 1 B 1 ) k ]C (A 1 B 1 ) t s vech(h s ) k=0 where (A 1 B 1 ) 0 is equal to the identity matrix by definition. Let V ΛV 1 denote the Jordan decomposition of the matrix A 1 B 1,sothat (A 1 B 1 ) t s = V Λ t s V 1.Thus,E s (vech(h t )) converges to the unconditional covariance matrix (I A 1 B 1 ) 1 C,fort, if and only if the absolute value of the largest eigen value of A 1 B 1 is strictly less than one. Results for other multivariate formulations are scarce, a possible exception is the constant conditional correlations parameterization where the conditions for the model to be covariance stationary are simply determined by the conditions of each of the univariate conditional variances. Co-Persistence in Variance The empirical estimates for univariate and multivariate ARCH models often indicate a high degree of persistence in the forecast moments of the conditional variances, i.e. E s (H t ) ii, i =1, 2,...N, fort. At the same time, the 3

commonality in volatility movements suggest that this persistence may be common across different series. More formally Bollerslev and Engle (1993) define the multivariate ARCH process to be co-persistent in variance if at least one of the elements in E s (H t ) is non-convergent for increasing forecasts, t s, but there exists a linear combination γ 0 ε t, such that for every forecast origin s, the forecasts of the corresponding future conditional variances E s (γ 0 H t γ) converge to a finite limit, independent of time s information. The conditions for this to occur are presented in Bollerslev and Engle (1993) and are similar to the conditions for co-integration in the mean as developed by Engle and Granger (1987). Multivariate GARCH-M models. Engle and Bollerslev (1986) consider a multivariate extension of the garchm as follows: Consider a system of n regression equations, y t = BX t Dvech(H t )u t px qx vech(h t )=C A i vech(u t i u 0 t i) B i vech(h t i ) i=1 i=1 where u t I t 1 N(0,H t ) Where B is n k D is n (n(n 1))/2 C is (n(n 1))/2 1 A 1,A 2,...A p,b 1,...B q are (n(n 1))/2 (n(n 1))/2 A Bivariate GARCH-M(1,1) model The easiest example is the simple bivariate process which depends on its conditional variance covariance matrix (H t ) xt w t = μx μ w d1 d 2 d 3 d 4 d 5 d 6 V t 1 (x t ) COV t 1 (x t w t ) V t 1 (w t ) εt ν t where 4

V t 1 (x t ) COV t 1 (x t w t ) V t 1 (w t ) = c x c xw c w c 1 c 2 c 3 c 4 c 5 c 6 (ε t 1) 2 (ε t 1 ν t 1 ) c 4 c 5 c 6 (ν t 1 ) 2 V t 2 (x t 1 ) COV t 2 (x t 1 w t 1 ) V t 2 (w t 1 ) b 1 b 2 b 3 b 4 b 5 b 6 b 4 b 5 b 6 Estimation The estimation of all the models presented above is carried out using conditional maximum likelihood estimation. The conditional log likelihood function for a single observation can be written as L t (θ) = (n/2) log(2π) (1/2) log(h t (θ)) (1/2)u t (θ) 0 Ht 1 (θ)u t (θ) where θ represents a vector of parameters, n represents number of equations and t represents time. Then conditional on initial values for u 0 and H 0, the likelihood function for the sample 1,..,T can be written as L(θ) = TX L t (θ) t=1 The maximization is usually achieved through numerical methods Notice that the model is highly non-linear and very unstable. An application of the MGARCH-M model : Testing The CAPM General issues Three main difficulties associated with testing the CAPM 1. The CAPM is a statement about the relationships between ex ante risk premiums and betas, both of which there are not directly observable. This problem is usually dealt with by assuming that investors form rational expectations: the realized return on assets are drawings from the ex ante probability distribution of returns on those assets. 2. The Roll- critique; many assets are not measurable (human capital etc.) so tests of the CAPM have to be based on proxies for the market portfolio which only includes (a subset of) traded assets. 5

3. The CAPM is a single-period model. However, in order to test the model time series are frequently used. This is only a valid procedure if both risk premia and betas are stationary. The Unconditional CAPM a short review of the literature. Markowitz(1959) laid the ground work for the CAPM. He cast the investor s portfolio selection problem in terms of the expected return and variance of the return. He argued that investors would optimally hold a mean-variance efficient portfolio. Sharpe and Litener showed that if investors have homogeneous expectations and optimally hold mean-variance portfolios then, the market portfolio will also be mean-variance. They also assume the existence of lending and borrowing at a risk free rate of interest. For this version of the CAPM the expected return for asset j is 2 E(r j )=r f β jm (E(r m ) r f ) Where r j,r f and r m are the asset j, risk free and market rate of return respectively. Defining excess returns r, we can rewrite the above expressions as E( r j )=β jm (E r m ) where r j = r j r f, r m = r m r f Since the risk free rate is assumed to be non-stochastic the two equations above are equivalent. Nevertheless in empirical applications r f is typically stochastic and therefore the β 0 may differ. Empirical tests of the Sharpe-Litener CAPM have focused on three implications of the last expression. 1. The intercept is zero 2. The parameter beta completely captures the cross sectional variation of expected excess returns 3. the market risk premium, (E r m ) is positive. Statistical Framework for the Sharpe-Lintner Version. The CAPM is a single-period model and do not have time dimension. For econometric analysis of the model we need to add an assumption concerning the time series properties of returns over time. We assume that the returns are IID and jointly multivariate Normal. Imposing the restriction that r jt and r mt are multivariate normal, it follows that 2 In testing the CAPM we usually do some simplifying assumptions. One is that the risk free rate is often approximated by the treasury bill lending rate. 6

where β j = cov( r jt r mt )/var( r mt ) and α j = E( r jt ) β j E( r mt ) Therefore E( r jt r mt )=α β r mt r jt = α j β j r mt ε jt (1) Traditionally β has been estimated by OLS regression, meaning that the range of problems encountered with any linear regression model recur here as well. To test the CAPM is equivalent to test the restriction that α j =0and this canbedoneinthiscontextbyasimpleftest. Alternativelywemayconsider the test in a multivariate context were E(ε t )=0 E(ε t ε 0 t )=Σ r t = α β r mt ε t E(r mt )=μ m, E(r mt μ m ) 2 = σ 2 m, Cov(r mt,ε t )=0 Where β is a vector of N 1 and ε t are N 1 asset returns intercepts and disturbances. We can estimate this model by maximum likelihood and test the N zero intercept restriction by a likelihood ratio test which is asymptotically distributed χ 2 (N). The Black (1972) version. In the absence of a risk free asset Black (1972) derived a more general version of the CAPM. In this version the expected return of asset i en excess of the zerobeta return is linearly related to its beta. Then E(r j )=r om β jm (E(r m ) r om ) where r is the return of the zero beta portfolio associated with m. This portfolio is defined to be the portfolio that has minimum variance of all the portfolios associated with m. The econometric analysis of the Black version of the CAPM treats the zerobeta portfolio as an unobserved quantity. This version can be tested as a restriction on the real return market model 7

E(r j )=α j β jm E(r m ) and the implication of this version is α jm = E(r om )(1 β jm ) This restrictions can also be tested by a likelihood ratio test. Applied work Most tests of the CAPM have used a time-series of monthly rates of return on common stocks listed in the New York Stock Exchange as a proxy of the market portfolio. Suppose that the objective is to explain the (excess) return of the j th portfolio of assets r jt. If there is only one asset per portfolio this will simply be the (excess) return on that asset. Portfolios can be interpreted in diverse ways. For example Harvey(1989) has r jt as the (excess) return on equity in the j th country. In the market model r jt is related to the return on the market or aggregate portfolio, r mt. The latter may be a simple average of the returns to all stocks in the economy or perhaps is a weighted average, with weights depending on the value of the portfolio accounted for each stock. b) The second approach interprets the tests conditional on the investors information set which is assumed to be jointly stationary and with multivariate normally distributed asset returns. E( r jt I t 1 )=β jt E( r mt I t 1 ) (2) The Conditional CAPM In (1) β j was a constant equal to the ratio cov(r jt r mt )/var(r mt ). However, in line with the distinction between conditional and unconditional moments, one might wish to consider models for r jt in which the conditional density rather than the unconditional density returns is used. Let I t 1 be a set of conditioning variables including the past history of r jt and r mt. Then the conditional asset pricing model has E( r jt I t 1 )=β jt E( r mt I t 1 ) (2) where β jt = cov( r jt r mt I t 1 )/var( r mt I t 1 ). Because the coefficients of the conditional market model are functions of the conditional moments for r jt and r mt it is necessary to model this in some way. A natural way to proceed is to allow the conditional mean for r jt to depend on its conditional variance, as in GARCH-M models, and to subsequently model cov(r t I t 1 ) by a multivariate GARCH. Multivariate GARCH-M models:a CAPM with time-varying covariances 8

As discussed above the conditional CAPM can be written as E(r jt I t 1 ) r ft 1 = β jt [E(r mt I t 1 ) r ft 1 ] where β jt = cov(r jt r mt I t 1 )/var(r mt I t 1 ). where, because we now allow the covariance matrix of returns var(r H = jt I t 1 ) cov(r jt r mt I t 1 ) cov(r jt r mt I t 1 ) var(r mt I t 1 ) to vary over time, both the expected returns and the betas will, in general, be time varying. This formulation of the CAPM is, however, non-operational because of the lack of an observed series for the expected market returns. If we assume that the market price of risk, λ is constant, where λ =(E(r mt I t 1 ) r ft 1 )/var(r mt I t 1 ). So that [E(r jt I t 1 ) r ft 1 ]=λcov(r jt,r mt I t 1 ) then we can write Also nothing that r jt = r ft 1 λcov(r jt,r mt I t 1 )u jt E(r mt I t 1 ) r ft 1 = λvar(r mt I t 1 ) (since λ =(E(r mt I t 1 ) r ft 1 )/var(r mt I t 1 ) ) r mt = r ft 1 λvar(r mt I t 1 )u mt Where u jt and u mt are the innovations. This time varying CAPM can be put into multivariate GARCH-M form as y t = b dvech(h t )u t where y t =(r jt r ft 1,r mt r ft 1 ) 0,vech(H t )=(var(r jt I t 1 ),cov(r jt r mt I t 1 ), var(r mt I t 1 )) 0,u t =(u jt,u mt ) 0 and 0 1 0 d = λ. 0 0 1 The zero restrictions implied by the theory may be tested (against a general model) by a likelihood ratio test which is asymptotically distributed χ 2 (5). A by-product of this methodology is that plot of conditional time varying betas can easily been obtained. This plot is very informative since it may provide as with time varying beta ranking and also show how different stocks react to shocks to the economy. 9