Wages in a General Equilibrium Time Series Model of the US. Henry Thompson

Similar documents
Wages in a Factor Proportions Time Series Model of the US

Energy in a Physical Production Function: The US Economy from 1951 to 2008

Internation1al Trade

Dynamic Three-Factor Models of International Trade *

TERMS OF TRADE: THE AGRICULTURE-INDUSTRY INTERACTION IN THE CARIBBEAN

The Heckscher-Ohlin model: Mathematical treatment*

External Economies of Scale and International Trade: Further Analysis

Volume 30, Issue 1. Measuring the Intertemporal Elasticity of Substitution for Consumption: Some Evidence from Japan

Cointegration and Tests of Purchasing Parity Anthony Mac Guinness- Senior Sophister

Defence Spending and Economic Growth: Re-examining the Issue of Causality for Pakistan and India

Trade with differences in technologies

International Trade Lecture 9: Factor Proportion Theory (II)

ARDL Cointegration Tests for Beginner

Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Population Growth and Economic Development: Test for Causality

Department of Economics, UCSB UC Santa Barbara

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms

The General Neoclassical Trade Model

Testing for Unit Roots with Cointegrated Data

The Heckscher-Ohlin Model: Brief Review

9) Time series econometrics

An Econometric Modeling for India s Imports and exports during

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE COLLEGE OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CANTERBURY CHRISTCHURCH, NEW ZEALAND

Government expense, Consumer Price Index and Economic Growth in Cameroon

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

Knowledge licensing in a Model of R&D-driven Endogenous Growth

Human Development and Trade Openness: A Case Study on Developing Countries

The Convergence Analysis of the Output per Effective Worker and Effects of FDI Capital Intensity on OECD 10 Countries and China

Cointegration, Stationarity and Error Correction Models.

Lecture 2 Macroeconomic Model of China by Simultaneous Equations

Projektbereich B Discussion Paper No. B-393. Katrin Wesche * Aggregation Bias in Estimating. European Money Demand Functions.

7. Integrated Processes

Trends and Unit Roots in Greek Real Money Supply, Real GDP and Nominal Interest Rate

Oil price and macroeconomy in Russia. Abstract

THE IMPACT OF REAL EXCHANGE RATE CHANGES ON SOUTH AFRICAN AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS: AN ERROR CORRECTION MODEL APPROACH

Factor Price Equalization? The Cointegration Approach Revisited

7. Integrated Processes

Will it float? The New Keynesian Phillips curve tested on OECD panel data

Internationa1 l Trade

Lecture 2: Factor Proportions Theory of Trade

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Technology and the Labor Market

Culture Shocks and Consequences:

Inflation Revisited: New Evidence from Modified Unit Root Tests

Topics in Trade: Slides

Eksamen på Økonomistudiet 2006-II Econometrics 2 June 9, 2006

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

Testing for non-stationarity

THE INFLUENCE OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENTS ON MONTENEGRO PAYMENT BALANCE

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

DATABASE AND METHODOLOGY

The Drachma/Deutschemark Exchange Rate, : A Monetary Analysis

Macroeconomics Field Exam. August 2007

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory)

1 The Basic RBC Model

CHAPTER 21: TIME SERIES ECONOMETRICS: SOME BASIC CONCEPTS

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

Co-integration and Error-Correction Modeling of Agricultural Output. A Case of Groundnut

THE TOURIST DEMAND IN THE AREA OF EPIRUS THROUGH COINTEGRATION ANALYSIS

Notes on Heterogeneity, Aggregation, and Market Wage Functions: An Empirical Model of Self-Selection in the Labor Market

This is a repository copy of Estimating Quarterly GDP for the Interwar UK Economy: An Application to the Employment Function.

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Lecture 8a: Spurious Regression

Volume 29, Issue 1. Price and Wage Setting in Japan: An Empirical Investigation

Housing and the Business Cycle

10) Time series econometrics

ENERGY CONSUMPTION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN SWEDEN: A LEVERAGED BOOTSTRAP APPROACH, ( ) HATEMI-J, Abdulnasser * IRANDOUST, Manuchehr

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

Rybczynski Redux. E. Fisher. 17 June Department of Economics California Polytechnic State University Visiting CES

BCT Lecture 3. Lukas Vacha.

Stationarity and Cointegration analysis. Tinashe Bvirindi

International Journal of Applied Econometrics and Quantitative Studies Vol. 3-2 (2006)

Darmstadt Discussion Papers in Economics

Output correlation and EMU: evidence from European countries

Advanced Macroeconomics

11/18/2008. So run regression in first differences to examine association. 18 November November November 2008

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

STRUCTURE Of ECONOMICS A MATHEMATICAL ANALYSIS

A Guide to Modern Econometric:

Problem 1 (30 points)

Lecture 8a: Spurious Regression

MEXICO S INDUSTRIAL ENGINE OF GROWTH: COINTEGRATION AND CAUSALITY

LM threshold unit root tests

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Introductory Workshop on Time Series Analysis. Sara McLaughlin Mitchell Department of Political Science University of Iowa

Lecture 4: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model With Many Goods and Factors

The Harris-Todaro model

CO INTEGRATION: APPLICATION TO THE ROLE OF INFRASTRUCTURES ON ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT IN NIGERIA

An Empirical Analysis of RMB Exchange Rate changes impact on PPI of China

Government Expenditure and Economic Growth in Iran

growth in a time of debt evidence from the uk

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 3

Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 3d ed. Chapter 16: Simultaneous equations models. An obvious reason for the endogeneity of explanatory

A General Model of Fair Wages in an Open Economy

Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1

Cointegration: A First Look

Transcription:

Wages in a General Equilibrium Time Series Model of the US Henry Thompson Auburn University April 2008 Theoretical wage effects of changing product prices and inputs have been examined under various assumptions in general equilibrium models of production. The present paper is the first to estimate wage adjustments in the context of this theory. The data cover the real wage, labor force, fixed capital assets, energy input, and prices of manufactures and services in the US from 1949 to 2006. Labor is revealed in the middle of the factor intensity ranking. The rising price of services has raised the wage, as has the falling price of manufactures. Energy input has had a larger wage impact than investment. Contact information: Economics, 202 Comer Hall, Auburn University AL 36849, 334-844-2910, fax 5999, thomph1@auburn.edu 1

Wages in a General Equilibrium Time Series Model of the US Wages endogenously adjust as markets clear in response to changing product prices and factors endowments in general equilibrium models of production. Theoretical wage effects have been analyzed under various assumptions but actual adjustments have not been examined in the context of the general equilibrium model. The present paper estimates wage adjustment to exogenous changes in prices of manufactures and services, and inputs of labor, capital, and energy in the US from 1949 to 2006. The estimated difference equation is derived from the general equilibrium model with three factors and two goods, and estimated coefficients relate to factor intensity and substitution. The general equilibrium model based on full employment and competitive pricing is a logical extension of Walras (1874), Heckscher (1919), and Ohlin (1924) as formalized by Samuelson (1953), Jones (1956), Chipman (1966), Jones and Scheinkman (1976), Takayama (1982), and Ethier (1984) and reviewed by Jones and Neary (1984). The present paper applies the model with three factors and two goods of Ruffin (1981), Suzuki (1983), and Thompson (1985, 1993). The model provides the foundation for applied general equilibrium models based on observed factor intensity and estimated substitution. Thompson (2005) reviews some simple direct specifications. The implied wage relationship, however, has not been estimated. The present variables are cointegrated and error correction models separate adjustment relative to the dynamic equilibrium. Estimated coefficients relate directly to parameters of the comparative static general equilibrium model, including factor shares, industry share, and substitution elasticities. Coefficients also provide a gauge of fundamental exogenous forces on the labor market. Practical issues 2

addressed by the present results include the wage effects of the falling price of manufactures due to import competition and the rising price of increasingly exported services. Regarding issues of changing factor endowments, the wage effects of immigration, altered investment, and decreased energy input can also be analyzed. 1. An applied 3x2 general equilibrium model Inputs of capital K, labor L, and energy E produce outputs of manufactures x M and services x S in the present 3x2 general equilibrium model of production and trade. Full employment of labor is stated L = Σ j a Lj x j where L is the labor force and a Lj the cost minimizing input of labor per unit of good j. Differentiate and introduce factor cost shares θ Lj and substitution elasticities σ ik in the first equation of the general equilibrium comparative static system (1) with exogenous changes on the right hand side. The second and third equations in (1) reflect adjustment to exogenous changes in capital K and energy E inputs. Competitive pricing of product j is written p j = a Lj w + a Kj r + a Ej e where factor prices are the wage w, capital rent r, and energy price e. Differentiate and use the cost minimizing envelope theorem to derive the last two equations in (1) where industry shares λ ij are portions of factor i employed in sector j. The comparative static model stated in differences of natural logs is σ LL σ LK σ LE θ LM θ LS dlnw dlnl σ KL σ KK σ KE θ KM θ KS dlnr dlnk σ EL σ EK σ EE θ EM θ ES dlne = dlne (1) λ LM λ KM λ EM 0 0 dlnx M dlnp M λ LS λ KS λ ES 0 0 dlnx S dlnp S. The system matrix is the Hessian of a constrained neoclassical national income maximization and Chang (1979) shows its determinant is negative due to concavity. Cross price substitution 3

elasticities are symmetric σ ij = σ ji and homogeneity implies substitution elasticities sum to zero Σ i σ ji = 0. The focus is wage adjustments to exogenous changes in prices and factor endowments. Let one of these exogenous changes be nonzero and divide both sides of (1) by that change. Solve for partial derivatives of the wage with Cramer s rule to find ε wl δlnw/δlnl = θ KE λ KE / ε wk δlnw/δlnk = -θ LE λ KE / ε we δlnw/δlne = -θ LK λ KE / (2) ε wm δlnw/δlnp M = -(λ KS φ 1 + λ ES φ 2 )/ ε ws δlnw/δlnp S = (λ EM φ 2 λ KM φ 1 )/ where θ EK θ EM θ KS θ ES θ KM, θ EL θ EM θ LS θ ES θ LM, θ LK θ LM θ KS θ LS θ KM, λ EK λ EM λ KS λ ES λ KM, φ 1 (θ EK + θ LK )σ LE + (θ LK θ EL )σ KE, and φ 2 (θ LK θ EL )σ KE (θ EK + θ EL )σ LK given homogeneity. Factor intensities alone determine the signs of θ KE, θ LE, θ LK, λ KE, and by implication the first three terms in (2). If energy is intensive in manufacturing relative to labo, for instance, θ EL and λ EL are positive. The own wage effect ε wl is negative reflecting neoclassical concavity since θ KE and λ KE have the same sign and < 0. Signs of ε wk and ε we depend only on factor intensity but one must be positive, an increase in either capital or energy raising the wage. A negative effect might not be expected for either but output adjustments and substitution may not favor the wage. Signs of ε wm and ε ws depend on factor substitution as well, and the sizes of all wage effects depend on the factor substitution as well as intensity. Partial derivative wage effects can be summarized in a single equation as dlnw = (λ KE (θ KE dlnl θ LE dlnk θ LK dlne) φ M dlnp M + φ S dlnp S )/ (3) where φ M λ KS φ 1 + λ ES φ 2 and φ S λ EM φ 2 λ KM φ 1. Empirical specification of the wage difference equation in (3) is 4

dlnw = α 1 dlnl + α 2 dlnk + α 3 dlne + α 4 dlnp M + α 5 dlnp S + ε (4) where ε is a white noise residual and time subscripts are omitted. Estimated coefficients such as α 1 = ε wl = λ EK θ EK / reveal effective factor intensity and perhaps information on substitution. Theoretical expectations are a negative α 1 and at least one positive sign for α 2 and α 3. 2. Difference stationarity The data in Figure 1 are from the US National Economic Accounts of the Bureau of Economic Analysis (2007) except Btu energy input E from the US Department of Energy (2007). The wage w is derived from employee compensation averaged across the labor force L and deflated by the consumer price index. The capital stock K is the deflated net stock of fixed capital assets. * Figure 1 * Price of manufacturing p M and services p S are price indices relative to the consumer price index. Part of the 68% decrease in the price of manufactures is due to import competition. Quite the opposite, the price of services increased 59% over the period. The relative price of services p s /p m increased about five times and the output of services relative to manufactures almost 50% according to output indices in the same data. Difference stationarity is critical to estimating the difference equation (4). The log of the price of services lnp S in Figure 2 is difference stationary by the Dickey-Fuller DFc test as reported in Table 1. Energy input lne is difference stationary by the augmented Dickey-Fuller ADF test adding α 2 t and α 3 x -1. The wage lnw and capital input lnk are difference stationary in ADF(2) tests with the added lag α 4 x -2. * Figure 2 * Table 1 * The labor force lnl has autocorrelated residuals and significant coefficients in all DF tests, and the price of manufactures lnp M has positive own coefficients. These two series in Figure 3 are, however, difference stationary with a 1975 structural break by the Perron (1989) test in Table 1. * Figure 3 * 5

In the difference stationary tests there is no evidence of autocorrelation relative to the critical Durbin-Watson statistic DW = 1.43 and no heteroskedasticity in residuals according to ARCH(1) tests. The series are all I(1) processes with unit roots suggesting a reliable difference equation regression in (4). 3. Wage difference and error correction models The residual of the regression in levels can be utilized in an error correction model ECM if the series are cointegrated and Table 2 reports the spurious regression. The series are cointegrated according to the Engle-Granger EG (1987) test reported in the last column implying interdependent time paths and suggesting an ECM. * Table 2 * The first row in Table 3 reports the estimate of the structural equation (4) as the difference equation model lnw = α 1 lnl + α 2 lnk + α 3 lnp M + α 4 lnp S + α 5 D + α 6 D lnl + α 6 D lnp M + ε (5) where D represents the 1975 structural break. Coefficients of D and its interactions are insignificant. Coefficients are estimated comparative static arc elasticities with other exogenous changes held equal to zero. * Table 3 * The own labor lnl elasticity is negative and elastic. Both the capital lnk and energy lne elasticities are positive. The range of critical DW values for no autocorrelation is 1.43 to 2.57 and the difference model falls in the indecisive range, casting some doubt on parameter significance. Heteroskedasticity is revealed by the ARCH(1) test. The theoretical model has no constant in (4) but adding a constant gauges other potential influences on the wage. The constant also detrends the wage although that is not necessary for the difference stationary series. The second row in Table 3 reports the difference model with a 6

significant constant and coefficients very similar to the difference model with no constant except a much weaker labor force effect after the break. The third row in Table 3 reports the ECM and its significant cointegrating effect. Coefficients have values similar to the difference model. Coefficients of the structural break D and its interactions are insignificant. Adjustment to the dynamic equilibrium reflected by the error correction coefficient strengthens the net wage elasticity. Note, however, no explanatory power is added relative to the difference model. Further, ambiguity in autocorrelation remains in the DW statistic and ARCH(1) heteroskedasticity is stronger. The ECM with a constant is reported in the last row of Table 3. Coefficients are similar to the ECM with no constant although there is a much weaker labor force effect after the break. Statistical properties are reliable and this ECM is included in the model comparison in Table 6. The dynamic adjustment process is extended to lags of differences in the lagged error correction model ECM -1 in Table 4. Relative to the ECM explanatory power increases and both autocorrelation and heteroskedasticity disappear. Elasticities of labor, energy, and the price of services are stronger, and energy input has a lagged effect. The capital elasticity is insignificant for the first lag and weaker for the second lag relative to the ECM. The price of manufactures has no wage effect. The structural break is significant interacted with lnl implying a different labor force effect after 1975. The cointegrating coefficient is over twice as strong in its second lag compared to the ECM. Regressions with further lags reveal no significant effects, suggesting all wage adjustment is complete after two years. * Table 4 * Each exogenous effect is separated into a difference and an error correction effect. For instance, lnl has a wage effect of -1.83 and an error correction effect of -0.53 x 0.69 = -0.37, the two summing to -2.20. The ECM -1 model is included in the model comparison in Table 6. 7

The possible autocorrelation in the difference model suggests it can be utilized in an error correction model in double differences, and the differences are cointegrated as indicated by that Engle-Granger EG test. The Engle-Granger statistic is significant at-5.37* and there is no autocorrelation with DW = 1.79 or heterskedasticity with ARCH(1) = 0.98. With no a constant term, the coefficient of each double difference variable equals the difference coefficient in (4). The first row in Table 5 reports the double difference model. There is no autocorrelation or heterskedasticity, an advantage over the difference model. The labor endowment effect is weaker after the 1975 break. The effects of capital and the price of manufactures disappear. A constant in the second row of Table 5 does not affect results. * Table 5 * The third row of Table 5 reports the double difference error correction model ECM 2 with the residual of the difference model as the error correction variable. There is no autocorrelation or heterskedasticity and explanatory power is reasonable. Elasticities of the wage, energy input, and price of services are similar to other models but effects of the capital and price of manufactures effects disappear. The break in labor input implies a weaker effect after 1975. The model with a constant in the second row produces nearly identical coefficients. The error correction effect is sizeable and effects of all differences feed through the error correction process. As an example, the error correction effect of energy input is -0.72 x -0.74 = 0.53 making its total effect 0.65 + 0.53 = 1.18. Coefficients of this double difference ECM 2 model are included in Table 6. 4. Comparison of wage elasticities Labor is revealed as the middle factor in the intensity ranking by the input elasticities. Estimated signs (- + +) of wage elasticities (ε wl ε wk ε we ) imply the terms (θ KE θ LE θ LK ) in (2) have signs ( +). There are two factor intensity rankings consistent with these signs are θ EM /θ ES > θ LM /θ LS > θ KM /θ KS (6) 8

and its reverse. The high input of energy in manufacturing suggests (6). The larger size of ε we relative to ε wk implies θ LK > θ EL which means θ LM /θ LS is closer to θ KM /θ KS than θ EM /θ ES. In other words, energy is revealed as very intensive in manufacturing. One of the cross price elasticities (σ KE, σ LE, σ LK ) may be negative indicating technical complements but otherwise factors are substitutes. There is a literature on whether energy and capital are complements as they appear in some time series analysis and the present wage elasticities ε wm < 0 and ε ws > 0 are consistent with σ KE < 0 in (2). Wage elasticities are summarized in Table 6 for the error correction model ECM in Table 3, the ECM with a lag in Table 4, and the double differenced ECM 2 in Table 5. Models without constants are closer to theory and utilized in Table 6 and averages with constants are similar. Coefficients are generally similar and not far out of line with the spurious model in levels, point estimates of the same elasticities. For discussion, consider their average in the last row of Table 6. * Table 6 * Sizes of wage effects can be gauged by means and standard deviations of changes. For instance, the mean change 1.4% of the labor force lnl and its standard deviation 0.5% suggest the range of changes (1.9%, 0.9%). The average labor elasticity -2.28 before the 1975 break implies an average wage adjustment of -3.2% and the range (-4.3%, -2.1%). After 1975 the average wage elasticity of -0.66 implies an average wage reduction of 0.9% and the range (-1.3%, -0.6%). Steady increases in the labor force put continuous downward pressure on the wage, reflecting a competitive labor market. Immigration contributes to the increase in the labor endowment although the share is difficult to pin down due to a lack of data. Assuming half of the immigrants obtaining legal status and located aliens enter the labor force, immigration accounts for up to 1/2 of the yearly increase in the labor force. At the mean, that assumption would imply annual immigration lowered the wage ceteris paribus by -1.6% before 1975 and -0.5% since. 9

The mean capital change lnk of 3.5% and its standard deviation 2.2% imply an average wage increase of 1.0% and the range (1.6%, 0.4%) with the average 0.28 elasticity. The mean energy input change of lne 2.0% and its standard deviation 2.8% imply an average wage increase of 2.2% and the range (5.3%, -0.9%) with the 1.10 energy elasticity. Increases in the labor endowment are more than offset after 1975 by increased labor demand due to investment and increased energy input. Before 1975, however, competition in the labor market dominated on average depressing the wage holding output prices constant. The mean change in the price of manufactures lnp m -2.0% and standard deviation 1.7% imply the range (-0.3%, -3.7%). The elasticity of -0.36 implies an average wage adjustment of 0.7% and range (1.3%, 0.1%). While the positive wage effect of a falling price of manufactures may seem paradoxical, output of labor intensive services was increasing. The mean and standard deviation of the change in the price of services lnp s are both 0.8% implying the range (1.6%, 0%) and its 1.31 elasticity implies an average wage effect of 1.0% and range (2.1%, 0%). These annual manufacturing and services price effects are consistent with energy intensive manufactures and labor intensive services comparing these two inputs as in the intensity ranking (6). 5. Conclusion Empirical results reveal labor as the middle factor relative to capital and energy, and energy as very intensive in manufacturing. The ceteris paribus wage effect of the typical annual increase in the labor force is about -4% before 1975 but reduces to about -1% since. Immigration accounts for perhaps half that decrease in the wage. The rising price of services raises the wage about 1% annually and the falling price of manufactures raises the wage almost that amount. The underlying consistent expansion of the service sector has supported the wage as the relative price of services increased over five times. 10

The wage increases by an average of 1% annually due to investment and over twice that amount due to increased energy input. The expected continuing rising price of energy in the future does not bode well for labor. Subsequent models and empirical analysis can look closer at the relationship between the wage and energy input. Regression results are consistent with substitution between all inputs or with complementary capital and energy. Subsequent models or data may reveal more about effective substitution. Estimated substitution parameters vary across regions and time, and the present approach may contribute to the applied production literature. The present sort of empirical analysis has potential to refine general equilibrium models of production. The model can include other factors of production including labor skills, natural resources, and sector specific capital or other inputs. Outputs can be disaggregated. The various equations of the general equilibrium production model, including adjustments in all factor prices and outputs, can be estimated. Implications of the various theoretical assumptions in the literature can be compared. Adjustment processes can be compared across countries and time periods. 11

References Bureau of Economic Analysis (2007) National Economic Accounts, Department of Commerce webpage, www.bea.gov/national/nipaweb/selecttable.asp?selected=n Chang, Winston (1979) Some Theorems of Trade and General Equilibrium with Many Goods and Factors, Econometrica 47, 709-26. Chipman, John (1966) A Survey of the Theory of International Trade: Part 3, The Modern Theory, Econometrica 34, 18-76. Department of Energy (2007) Energy Overview, Energy Information Agency webpage, www.eia.doe.gov/emeu/aer/overview.html Dickey, David and Wayne Fuller (1979) Distribution of the Estimates for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root, Journal of the American Statistical Association 74, 427-31. Engel, Robert and Clive Granger (1987) Cointegration and Error-Correction: Representation, Estimation, and Testing, Econometrica 55, 251-76. Ethier, Wilfred (1984) Higher Dimensional Issues in Trade Theory, in Ron Jones and Peter Kenen (eds) Handbook of International Economics, vol. 1, Amsterdam: North Holland, 131-84 Heckscher, Eli (1919) The Effect of Foreign Trade on the Distribution of Income, Ekonomisk Tidskrift. Jones, Ron (1965) The Structure of Simple General Equilibrium Models, Journal of Political Economy 73, 57-72. Jones, Ron and Neary, Peter (1984) The Positive Theory of International Trade, in Handbook of International Trade, vol. 1, Ron Jones and Peter Kenen (eds.), Amsterdam: North Holland. Jones, Ron and José Scheinkman (1977) The Relevance of the Two-Sector Production Model in Trade Theory, Journal of Political Economy 85, 909-35. Ohlin, Bertil (1924) The Theory of Trade, translated in Harry Flam and June Flanders, Heckscher- Ohlin Trade Theory, MIT Press, 1991, 73-214. Perron, Pierre (1989) The Great Crash, the Oil Shock, and the Unit Root Hypothesis, Econometrica 57, 1361-1401. Rassekh, Fahad (1992) The Role of International Trade in the Convergence of Per Capita GDP in the OECD, 1950-1985, International Economic Journal 6, 1-15. Ruffin Roy (1981) "Trade and Factor Movements with Three Factors and Two Goods," Economics Letters 7, 177-82. 12

Samuelson, Paul (1953) Prices of Factors and Products in General Equilibrium, Review of Economic Studies 21, 1-20. Stolper, Wolfgang and Paul Samuelson (1941) Protection and Real Wages, Review of Economic Studies 9, 58-73. Suzuki Katsuhiko (1983) A Synthesis of the Heckscher-Ohlin and Neoclassical Models of International Trade: A Comment, Journal of International Economics 14, 141-44. Takayama, Akira (1982) On Theorems of General Competitive Equilibrium of Production and Trade: A Survey of Recent Developments in the Theory of International Trade, Keio Economic Studies 19, 1-38. Thompson Henry (1985) Complementarity in a Simple General Equilibrium Production Model, Canadian Journal of Economics 16, 616-21. Thompson, Henry (1993) The Magnification Effect with Three Factors, Keio Economic Studies 20, 57-64. Thompson, Henry (2003) Robustness of the Stolper-Samuelson Factor Intensity Price Link, in Handbook of International Trade, edited by Kwan Choi, Blackwell. Thompson, Henry (2005) Income Redistribution, Trade Prices, and International Capital in Simulated Trade Models, in WTO and World Trade: Challenges in a New Era, edited by Geunter Heiduk and Kar-yiu Wong, Springer-Verlag. Thompson, Henry (2007) An Empirical Measure of Factor Intensity when there are Many Factors and Many Products, The International Trade Journal 21, 109-19. Walras, Léon (1874) Elements of Pure Economics, 1954 translation of 1926 edition, Richard Irwin. 13

Figure 1. Data series Figure 2. Difference Stationary Figure 3. Difference Stationary with 1975 Structural Break 14

Table 2. Spurious Regression constant lnl lnk lne lnp M lnp S EG τ -3.18 3.95** (2.35) -0.69*** (-4.63) 0.25*** (3.36) 0.61*** (10.7) -0.01 (-0.10) 1.29*** (6.91) adjr 2.996 DW 0.62 (+) ARCH 2.64*** -3.32* DW 1.46 ARCH 1.15 Table 3. Difference Model and ECM in lnw lnl lnk lne lnp M lnp S D D lnl D lnp M Res -1 Difference no constant -1.24*** (-3.10) 0.31*** (2.81) 0.74*** (8.14) -0.37* (-1.86) 0.49* (1.81) -0.01 (-0.50) 1.05 (1.20) 0.23 (0.81) adjr 2.763 DW 1.39(?) ARCH 1.87* 0.30*** (3.30) -2.46*** (-4.74) 0.23** (3.20) 0.65*** (7.53) -0.21 (-1.09) 0.45* (1.85) -0.03** (-2.30) 2.29** (2.59) 0.09 (0.34) adjr 2.738 DW 1.49 ARCH 0.93 ECM no constant 0.03*** (3.11) -1.22*** (-3.18) -2.34*** (-4.64) 0.26** (2.45) 0.19* (1.93) 0.72*** (8.20) 0.64*** (7.62) -0.45** (-2.31) -0.28 (-1.53) 0.69** (2.44) 0.71* (2.64) -0.01 (-0.71) -0.03** (-2.36) 1.09 (1.29) 2.22** (2.59) 0.29 (1.06) 0.15 (0.58) -0.25** (-2.28) -0.21** (-2.04) adjr 2.780 DW 1.37(?) ARCH 2.43** adjr 2.738 DW 1.49 ARCH 0.93 Table 4. Lagged ECM -1 in lnw no constant lnl lnk lne lnp M lnp S D D lnl D lnp M -1.83*** (-3.56) 0.04 (0.26) 0.78*** (10.6) 0.13 (-0.75) 1.06*** (3.75) -0.02* (-1.69) 1.55** (2.05) 0.01 (0.04) 0.01 (0.91) -2.04*** (-3.62) 0.07 (0.53) 0.75*** (9.40) -0.11 (-0.59) 0.97*** (3.20) -0.03* (-1.92) 1.82** (2.24) -0.02 (-0.07) lnl -1 lnk -1 lne -1 lnp M-1 lnp S-1 Res -1 Res -2 0.34 (0.70) 0.20 (0.38) 0.18* (1.79) 0.14 (1.20) 0.14* (1.69) 0.12 (1.38) -0.14 (-0.86) -0.12 (-0.72) 0.33 (1.34) 0.26 (0.26) 0.11 (0.83) 0.11 (0.74) -0.53*** (-3.87) -0.50*** (-3.48) adjr 2.846 DW 2.02 ARCH 0.79 adjr 2.782 DW 2.11 ARCH 0.52 15

Table 5. Double Difference Model and ECM 2 in 2 lnw constant 2 lnl 2 lnk 2 lne 2 lnp M 2 lnp S D D 2 lnl D 2 lnp M Res 0.00 (0.38) ECM 2 no constant 0.00 (1.21) -3.16*** (-3.51) -3.23*** (-3.49) -2.35*** (-3.09) -2.48*** (-3.25) 0.13 (1.09) 0.13 (1.07) 0.05 (0.50) 0.04 (0.44) 0.67*** (8.39) 0.67*** (8.33) 0.65*** (10.1) 0.66*** (10.2) 0.00 (0.00) 0.00 (0.00) -0.23 (-1.61) -0.24* (-1.67) 0.64** (2.32) 0.65** (2.33) 0.83*** (3.63) 0.89*** (3.81) 0.00 (0.27) -0.00 (-0.12) 0.00 (0.27) -0.00 (-0.76) 3.35** (2.57) 3.42** (2.57) 2.64** (2.44) 2.79** (2.58) -0.11 (-0.41) -0.11 (-0.41) 0.31 (1.29) 0.32 (1.35) -0.72*** (-4.91) -0.75*** (-5.05) adjr 2.667 DW 2.24 ARCH 0.80 adjr 2.682 DW 2.25 ARCH 1.01 adjr 2.768 DW 1.83 ARCH 0.82 adjr 2.791 DW 1.83 ARCH 1.12 Table 6. Comparison of ECM Wage Elasticities ECM -1.39*** (6.78) L / break K E p M p S 0.32*** 0.87*** -0.45** (3.52) (17.8) (2.32) 1.01*** (7.83) ECM -1-2.20*** / -0.65 (4.14) / (0.70) 0.32*** (2.76) 1.25*** (8.93) 0 1.74*** (5.01) ECM 2-3.24*** / 0.59* (-5.41) / (1.59) 0.22* (1.33) 1.18*** (168) -0.27*** (-4.43) 1.18*** (6.98) average -2.28 / -0.88 0.28 1.10-0.36 1.31 16