Rice University. Fall Semester Final Examination ECON501 Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Writing Period: Three Hours

Similar documents
Rice University. Answer Key to Mid-Semester Examination Fall ECON 501: Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Part A

Economics th April 2011

Second Welfare Theorem

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Chapter 9. Natural Resources and Economic Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Advanced Microeconomics

Simon Fraser University, Department of Economics, Econ 201, Prof. Karaivanov FINAL EXAM Answer key

EconS 501 Final Exam - December 10th, 2018

Index. Cambridge University Press An Introduction to Mathematics for Economics Akihito Asano. Index.

Market Failure: Externalities

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 6: Partial and General Equilibrium

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

One Variable Calculus. Izmir University of Economics Econ 533: Quantitative Methods and Econometrics

Neoclassical Growth Model: I

Microeconomic Theory I Midterm October 2017

Introductory Microeconomics

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A

First Welfare Theorem

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

Answers to Spring 2014 Microeconomics Prelim

The Fundamental Welfare Theorems

Competitive Equilibrium

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Structural Properties of Utility Functions Walrasian Demand

1 General Equilibrium

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

Firms and returns to scale -1- John Riley

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

The Ohio State University Department of Economics. Homework Set Questions and Answers

Universidad Carlos III de Madrid May Microeconomics Grade

where u is the decision-maker s payoff function over her actions and S is the set of her feasible actions.

Chapter 9. Natural Resources and Economic Growth. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Last Revised: :19: (Fri, 12 Jan 2007)(Revision:

Equilibrium in Factors Market: Properties

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions

ECMB02F -- Problem Set 2

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them.

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 2

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016

Week 6: Consumer Theory Part 1 (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 1)

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

ECON 255 Introduction to Mathematical Economics

z = f (x; y) f (x ; y ) f (x; y) f (x; y )

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics

Aggregate Supply. Econ 208. April 3, Lecture 16. Econ 208 (Lecture 16) Aggregate Supply April 3, / 12

1 Objective. 2 Constrained optimization. 2.1 Utility maximization. Dieter Balkenborg Department of Economics

Market Equilibrium and the Core

ECON 582: Dynamic Programming (Chapter 6, Acemoglu) Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Preferences and Utility

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

BEEM103 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER. BUSINESS School. January 2009 Mock Exam, Part A. OPTIMIZATION TECHNIQUES FOR ECONOMISTS solutions

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Universidad Carlos III de Madrid June Microeconomics Grade

Duality. for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed. Lawrence E. Blume

TOBB-ETU - Econ 532 Practice Problems II (Solutions)

Welfare Analysis in Partial Equilibrium.

Assignment #5. 1 Keynesian Cross. Econ 302: Intermediate Macroeconomics. December 2, 2009

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION

Proper Welfare Weights for Social Optimization Problems

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Microeconomics, Block I Part 1

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Lecture 1: Ricardian Theory of Trade

Econ Review Set 2 - Answers

ECON501 - Vector Di erentiation Simon Grant

Properties of Walrasian Demand

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

( )! ±" and g( x)! ±" ], or ( )! 0 ] as x! c, x! c, x! c, or x! ±". If f!(x) g!(x) "!,

Applications I: consumer theory

ECON 582: The Neoclassical Growth Model (Chapter 8, Acemoglu)

Existence, Computation, and Applications of Equilibrium

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS STAFF PAPER SERIES

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 2

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Notes on Recursive Utility. Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in

= 2 = 1.5. Figure 4.1: WARP violated

Notes IV General Equilibrium and Welfare Properties

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3

Microeconomic Theory-I Washington State University Midterm Exam #1 - Answer key. Fall 2016

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Week 10: Theory of the Firm (Jehle and Reny, Chapter 3)

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Appendix (For Online Publication) Community Development by Public Wealth Accumulation

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Econ 201: Problem Set 3 Answers

The Real Business Cycle Model

Transcription:

Rice University Fall Semester Final Examination 007 ECON50 Advanced Microeconomic Theory Writing Period: Three Hours Permitted Materials: English/Foreign Language Dictionaries and non-programmable calculators There are ve pages (including this title page) and ve questions. You should attempt all parts of all ve questions. The total points for the exam is one hundred and eighty (80).

. [60 Points] Consider a preference relation that can be represented by the utility fuction x s x3 x x u (x ; x ; x 3 ; x ) = +. (a) Derive the uncompensated demand function for the region of the parameter space in which the consumer is choosing positive amounts of all four commodities. Evaluate the income elasticities of demand for each of the four commodities. Short cut u (x ; x ; x 3 ; x ) = u A (x ; x ) + u B (x 3 ; x ), so if e A = p x + p x and e B = p 3 x 3 + p x, then problem can be reexpressed as max v A (p ; p ; e A ) + v B (p 3 ; p ; e B ) s.t. e A + e B w he A ;e B i where v A (p ; p ; e A ) = max u A (x ; x ) s.t. p x + p x e A hx ;x i and v B (p 3 ; p ; e B ) = max u B (x 3 ; x ) s.t. p 3 x 3 + p x e B hx 3 ;x i Since u A (x ; x ) and u B (x 3 ; x ) are monotonic transformations of Cobb-Douglas utilities, we have Hence x (p ; p ; e A ) = e A p, x (p ; p ; e A ) = ( ) e A p, x 3 (p 3 ; p ; e B ) = e B p 3, x (p 3 ; p ; e B ) = ( ) e B p. v A (p ; p ; e A ) = e A p ( ) p and v B (p ; p ; e A ) = So the expenditure between groups problem can be written as s w e B eb max + e B p ( ) p p ( ) s eb p ( ) FONC p ( ) p v u + t e B h p 3p ( ) i = 0, since e B > 0. Yielding e B = p p 3p ( ) p ( ) and e A = w p ( ) p p ( )

Substituting back yields the uncompensated demand x (p ; p ; p 3 ; p ; w) = p w p x (p ; p ; p 3 ; p ; w) = x 3 (p ; p ; p 3 ; p ; w) = p 3 p x (p ; p ; p 3 ; p ; w) = ( ) p p ( ) ( ) w p p p p 3p ( ) p ( ) p p ( )! p ( ) p p ( ) ( ) ( ) Computing the marginal propensities to consume out of wealth: @x p @w =, p @x @w = ( ), p @x 3 3 @w = 0, p @x @w = 0. (b) Using your answer from (a) derive the indirect utility function. From (a) we have s v (p ; p ; p 3 ; w) = = = e A p ( ) p w p ( ) p w p ( ) p (c) Derive the compensated demand function. From the fundamental identity we have and hence + e B p ( ) p ( ) p p 3p + p p p 3p ( ) ( ) ( ) v (p ; p ; p 3 ; e (p ; p ; p 3 ; p ; u)) = u e (p ; p ; p 3 ; p ; u) p ( ) p + p ( ) p p ( ) 3p! + p ( ) p p ( ) 3p e (p ; p ; p 3 ; p ; u) = up ( ) p p ( ) By dierentiating the expenditure function we obtain the compensated demands. = u p ( ) p 3

(Shepherd's lemma). h (p ; p ; p 3 ; p ; u) = p "e (p ; p ; p 3 ; p ; u) h (p ; p ; p 3 ; p ; u) = ( ) p h 3 (p ; p ; p 3 ; p ; u) = p 3 p h (p ; p ; p 3 ; p ; u) = ( ) p " e (p ; p ; p 3 ; p ; u) ( ) p p ( ) p ( ) p p ( ) p ( ) p p ( ) # p ( ) p p ( ) Recall in lectures that the equivalent variation of a change in prices and income from (p 0 ; w 0 ) to (p ; w ) was dened to be EV = e p 0 ; v p ; w w 0. Further recall that if wealth is unaltered and the change in prices is caused by the imposition of commodity taxes then the deadweight loss (DWL) or excess burden of the taxes is given by DWL = EV X L `= t`x` p ; w 0. (d) Briey explain why this measure may be viewed as a deadweight loss to (social) economic eciency. (e) Suppose the initial budget constraint has p 0 = (; ; ; ) and w 0 = 36. Suppose further that the consumer's preferences parameters are = = and = =3. Calculate the DWL of the imposition of a specic tax of 3 on good, that leads to the price of good rising to. DWL = w 0 e p 0 ; v p ; w X L`= t`x` p ; w 0 From answers above, we have p w p p v (; ; ; ; 36) = p + p p p =3 p =3 e (; ; ; ; 0) = u p p p p p x (; ; ; ; 36) = = p w p =3 p =3 = (36 ) = 8 p p p =3 p =3 = 36 + = 0, = 0 = 9! # Hence DWL = 36 9 3 = 5

(f) Again starting from the initial position corresponding to p 0 = (; ; ; ) and w 0 = 36 compute the DWL arising from the imposition of a specic tax of 3 on good, and specic taxes of on both goods 3 and resulting in the price of good rising to and the prices of goods 3 and both rising to. From answers above, we have Hence p p p w v (; ; ; ; 36) = p + p p p =3 3 p =3 e (; ; ; ; 9) = u p p p p p x (; ; ; ; 36) = = p = 8 x 3 (; ; ; ; 36) = =3 p p p 3 w p =3 3 p =3 p p p =3 3 p =3 = 36 + = 9, = 9 = 8;! 3 (36 ) = 8 = 7 p =3 3 p =3 x (9; ; 3; 3; 36) = =3 p p p DWL = 36 8 3 7 p =3 3 p =3 3 = 3 = 3 3 = 7. [5 Points] Consider the following four lotteries: L (x) = L 3 (x) = if x = $3; 000 0 otherwise 8 < : 0:5 if x = $3; 000 0:75 if x = $0 0 otherwise 8 <, L (x) = : Show that if for the preference relation < we have 8 < and L (x) = : L L and L L 3 0:8 if x = $; 000 0: if x = $0 0 otherwise 0: if x = $; 000 0:8 if x = $0 0 otherwise then < L does not admit an expected utility representation. Which of the axioms for subjective expected utility theory does this pattern of preferences violate? State this axiom and show how the this pattern of preference is inconsistent with the axiom. Wlog, set u (; 000) := and u (0) := 0. Let u (3000) = u. L L ) u > 0:8 + 0: 0 ) u > 0:8 L L 3 ) 0: + 0:8 0 > 0:5 u + 0:75 0 ) 0: > 0:5u ) 0:8 > u, a contradiction! 5

Notice, L 3 = 0:5 L + 0:75 0 and L = 0:5 L + 0:75 0 The independence axiom states, for any three lotteries L, L 0 and L 00 and any in (0; ] : L % L 0, L + ( ) L 00 % L 0 + ( ) L 00 One implication is that if L L 0 then L+( ) L 00 L 0 +( ) L 00. But taking, we have a violation of independence. L := L, L 0 := L, L 00 := 0 and = 0:5, L L but 0:5 L + 0:75 0 0:5 L + 0:75 0, 3. [5 Points] An individual is an expected utility maximizer described by the intertemporally additive preference-scaling function u (c 0 ) + u (c ) where u () is a strictly concave function with u 000 (c) > 0. The individual has current income I 0. The individual can buy bonds at unit price p = which pay out in the next period one unit of consumption per unit of bond held. Compare the individual's demand for bonds in the case where her future income is certain and equal to I 0, and the situation in which there is a fty percent chance future income is I 0 + " and a fty percent chance future income is I 0 ". Let q denote the quantity of bonds the individual buys in period 0. Let c be her consumption in period. Her maximization problem may be expressed as follows max u (c 0 ) + u (c ) q or FONCe s:t: c 0 = I 0 pq c = I 0 q max u (I 0 pq) + u (I 0 + q) q q : u 0 (I 0 pq ) p + u 0 (I 0 + q ) = 0 Since p =, and u is strictly concave, it follows unique solution is q = 0. Now let c be her consumption in period when her income is I 0 + " and let c be her consumption in period when her income is I 0 ". Her maximization problem may now be expressed as follows max u (c 0 ) + q u (c ) + u (c ) 6

s:t: c 0 = I 0 pq c = I 0 + " + q c = I 0 " + q or FONC max u (I 0 q pq) + q : u 0 (I 0 pq ) p + u (I 0 + " + q) + u (I 0 " + q) u0 (I 0 + " + q ) + u0 (I 0 " + q ) = 0 CLAIM q > q = 0. To see this, notice that LHS of FOC setting q = 0 yields u 0 (I 0 ) + u0 (I 0 + ") + u0 (I 0 ") > u 0 (I 0 ) + u 0 (I 0 + ") + (I 0 ") = 0 The inequality follows from Jensen's inequality applied to a convex function ( u 0 is a convex function since u 000 > 0). Thus we the individual's demand for bonds (i.e. for `saving' ) is greater when she faces uncertain future income than when she faces certain future income. This comparative static eect (which obtains since u 0 is convex) is an illustration of the `precautionary motive for saving'.. [30 Points] A price-taking rm produces output q from inputs z and z according to a dierentiable concave production function f (z ; z ). The price of its output is p > 0 and the price of its inputs are (w ; w ) 0. However, there are two unusual things about this rm. First, rather than maximizing prot, the rm maximizes revenue (the manager wants his rm to have bigger dollar sales than any other). Second, the rm is cash constrained. In particular, it has only C dollars on hand before production and, as a result, its total expenditures on inputs cannot exceed C. Suppose one of your econometrician colleagues tells you that she has used repeated observations of the rm's revenue under various output prices, and levels of the nancial constraint and has determined that the log of the rm's revenue level R can be expressed as the following function of the variables (p; w ; w ; C) : ln R (p; w ; w ; C) = ln p + [ + ln C ln w ( ) ln w ] (a) What is the rm's use of inputs z and z and its output q when prices are (p ; w ; w ) and it has C dollars of cash on hand? (5 points). (b) Using your answer to (a) show the rm's production function is Cobb-Douglas. (5 points). 7

5. [5 Points] A real-valued function f : R n! R, is called superadditive if f (x + x ) f (x )+f (x ). Show that every cost function is superadditive in input prices. Use this to prove the cost function is non-decreasing in input prices without requiring it to be dierentiable. Fix output target q > 0. Let z R L + (respectively, z, z 3 ) be the cost-minimizing input vector for the production of q units of the output when the rm faces input prices w R L + (respectively, w, w + w ) Since these input bundles are cost-minimizing for their respective input price vectors we have Adding these two inequalities, yields as required. c w ; q = w z w z 3 c w ; q = w z w z 3 c w ; q + c w ; q w + w z 3 = c w + w ; q, To see that the cost function is non-decreasing in prices, take any two input price vectors, w 0 and w 00. If w 00 w 0 = d 0, then by taking w := w 0, w := d (and hence w + w = w 00, we have, by superadditivity of the cost function, c (w 00 ) c (w 0 ) + c (d) Hence c (w 00 ) c (w 0 ) = c (d) 0, as required. 6. [5 Points] Throughout this question, assume all functions mentioned are twice continuously dierentiable. In Ruritania, the electricity industry is perfectly competitive both in the input and output markets. Let B e (q) represent a schedule of benets generated by the consumption of electricity, with B e (0) = 0, Be 0 (q) > 0 and Be 00 (q) < 0. Production opportunities in this industry is summarized by the aggregate production function: q = f (K e ; L; z), where q is the (maximum) amount of electricity that can be generated when K e units of capital are employed in electricity generation, in conjunction with L units of labor and z units of coal. Suppose f is strictly increasing in all its arguments and strictly concave and that capital and labor are elastically supplied at prices r and w, respectively. Suppose further that coal is competitively supplied according to a technology embodied in the cost function C (z) (that is, the cost of supplying z units of coal to the market is C (z), where C (0) = 0, C 0 > 0 and C 00 > 0.) Using coal to produce electricity generates as sulphur as a by-product. Left untreated sulphur is a pollutant but it can be made valuable if delivered in a pure state. Suppose 8

the by-production of sulphur from burning coal is a linear activity, so that without loss of generality we can choose units for sulphur to be such that using z units of coal generates z units of sulphur as by-product. Let y = g (K s ; z) represent the production of pure sulphur from this joint product with K s being the units of capital involved in the \purication" process (also available at [constant] unit price of r). The function g is strictly increasing in all arguments, strictly concave, and lim g (K s; z) z for all z. K s! The benet for puried sulphur is given by the schedule B s (y), with Bs 0 (y) > 0, Bs 00 (y) < 0 and B (0) = 0. Unpuried sulphur will be emitted as a pollutant into the environment. The amount of pollutant d will be d = z g (K s ; z). The social harm it will cause is given by the schedule H (d), with H 0 > 0, H 00 > 0 and H (0) = 0. (a) Characterize the economic ecient outcome for this conguration. (0 points). To characterize the economically ecient (Pareto optimal) outcome, consider maximizing max hk e;k s;l;zi B e (q) + B s (y) rk e rk e wl C (z) H (d) subject to q = f (K e ; L; z) () y = g (K s ; z) () d = z g (K s ; z) (3) Hence maximization can be re-expressed as: max B e (f (K e ; L; z))+b (g (K s ; z)) rk z rk y wl C (z) H (z g (K s ; z)) hk e;k s;l;zi FONC: K e : B 0 e (q ) f K (K e ; L ; z ) r = 0 () K s : [B 0 s (y ) + H 0 (d )] g K (K s ; z) r = 0 (5) L : B 0 e (q ) f L (K e ; L ; z ) r = 0 (6) z : Be 0 (q ) f z (Ke ; L ; z ) + Bs 0 (y ) g z (K s ; z) C 0 (z) H 0 (d ) ( g z (K s ; z)) = (7) 0 Each has obvious interpretation with the possible exception of the last. There, however, the equality of the marginal benet generated by employing the input is required to equal its full marginal social cost. 9

(b) Show that eciency can be achieved even if H (d) were ignored by producers in a competitive market if the government imposed an appropriate emission charge on d. (5 points). It is perhaps a miracle of modern economic theory that a single euent charge can be shown to guarantee that the social optimum just characterized in (a) will be produced by a competitive economy. To see how, let t be the emission charge on d, so that maximzing B e (q) + B s (y) rk e rk e wl C (z) td with respect to K e, K s, L and z given the conditions recorded in equations () through (3) models the competitive economy's equilibrium behavior (by the rst fundamental welfare theorem for partial equlibrium). The outcome, indicated by that notation is then the solution to a new set of rst-order conditions: K e : Be 0 (^q) f K ^Ke ; ^L; ^z r = 0 (8) K s : [Bs 0 (^y) + t] g K ^Ks ; ^z r = 0 (9) L : Be 0 (^q) f L ^Ke ; ^L; ^z r = 0 (0) z : Be 0 (^q) f z ^Ke ; ^L; ^z + Bs 0 (^y) g z ^Ks ; ^z C 0 (^z) t g z ^Ks ; ^z = () 0.Setting t = H 0 (d ), however, means equations () through (7) duplicate equations (8) through (). As a result, ^K e = K e, ^Ks = K e, ^L = L, ^z = z, ^q = q, ^y = y and ^d = d. (c) Show that a system that charged a tax t on the use of coal and paid a subsidy s for the production of puried sulphur could also achieve optimality. (5 points). Giving a subsidy s for the sale of puried sulphur and a tax t charged on the use of coal as an input, the competitive solution maximizes B e (q) + B s (y) rk e rk e wl C (z) tz + sy with respect to K e, K s, L and z, equations () through (3) still hold, and the rst-order conditions characterize a third vector of solutions: K e : Be 0 (eq) f eke K ; L; e ez r = 0 () K s : [Bs 0 (ey) + s] g eks K ; ez r = 0 (3) L : Be 0 (eq) f eke L ; L; e ez r = 0 () z : Be 0 (eq) f eke z ; L; e ez + Bs 0 (^y) g eks z ; ez C 0 (^z) + sg eks z ; ez t = (5) 0 Setting s = t = H 0 (d ), these equations duplicate equations (8) through () leading again to the ecient outcome. 0

(d) Contrast the informational requirements of these alternative systems (i.e., the regulative structures embodied in parts (b) and (c). (5 points). Comparing the information required to enact the policies envisioned in parts (b) and (c), notice both require some notion of the optimal, total level of emissions so that H 0 (d ) can be evaluated. For an euent tax to work, moreover, individual emission levels must be observed so that the required individual pollution fees can be collected. Therein lies a signicant informational problem, because euent is a dicult commodity to monitor eectively. On the other hand, the subsidy/input charge mechanism requires information about the quantity of material inputs being employed (more easily measured than euent, perhaps at point of supply) and the quantity of useable, cleansed pollutant being sold (again an easier measurement).