Course Handouts: Pages 1-20 ASSET PRICE BUBBLES AND SPECULATION. Jan Werner

Similar documents
Kevin X.D. Huang and Jan Werner. Department of Economics, University of Minnesota

Notes on Recursive Utility. Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in

A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Sequential Economies

A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Sequential Economies

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Notes on Alvarez and Jermann, "Efficiency, Equilibrium, and Asset Pricing with Risk of Default," Econometrica 2000

A Simple No-Bubble Theorem for Deterministic Dynamic Economies

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Financial asset bubble with heterogeneous agents and endogenous borrowing constraints

SDT 283 FIAT MONEY AND THE VALUE OF BINDING PORTFOLIO CONSTRAINTS

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Essays in Financial Economics

Lecture 6: Competitive Equilibrium in the Growth Model (II)

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Self-enforcing Debt Limits and Costly Default in General Equilibrium

Housing with overlapping generations

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics

1 Overlapping Generations

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

SDT 314 LONG-LIVED COLLATERALIZED ASSETS AND BUBBLES

Arbitrage and Equilibrium with Portfolio Constraints

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Pseudo-Wealth and Consumption Fluctuations

1 Two elementary results on aggregation of technologies and preferences

Negishi s method for stochastic OLG models

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions

Dynamic Competitive Economies with Complete Markets and Collateral Constraints

Microeconomics, Block I Part 2

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

Core equivalence and welfare properties without divisible goods

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

Discussion Papers in Economics

Online Supplement to Coarse Competitive Equilibrium and Extreme Prices

January 2018 No: 1152

Consumption. Consider a consumer with utility. v(c τ )e ρ(τ t) dτ.

1 General Equilibrium

Open Market Operations and Money Supply. at Zero Nominal Interest Rates

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Slides to accompany 13. Markets and Efficient Risk-Bearing: Examples and Extensions

TA Sessions in Macroeconomic Theory I. Diogo Baerlocher

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

On optimality in intergenerational risk sharing

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

TWO-FUND SEPARATION IN DYNAMIC GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

Are Probabilities Used in Markets? 1

Macroeconomic Topics Homework 1

Regularity of competitive equilibria in a production economy with externalities

Documents de Travail du Centre d Economie de la Sorbonne

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth

Lecture 3: Limited Enforcement in Exchange Economies

Second Welfare Theorem

Question 1. (p p) (x(p, w ) x(p, w)) 0. with strict inequality if x(p, w) x(p, w ).

Elimination of Arbitrage States in Asymmetric Information Models

The Value of Information Under Unawareness

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2016

First Welfare Theorem

Foundations of Neoclassical Growth

FIN 550 Practice Exam Answers. A. Linear programs typically have interior solutions.

Microeconomics II. MOSEC, LUISS Guido Carli Problem Set n 3

Simple Consumption / Savings Problems (based on Ljungqvist & Sargent, Ch 16, 17) Jonathan Heathcote. updated, March The household s problem X

Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

Economics 201b Spring 2010 Solutions to Problem Set 1 John Zhu

Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Problem set Solutions

Boundary Behavior of Excess Demand Functions without the Strong Monotonicity Assumption

Output contingent securities and efficient investment by

Macroeconomics I. University of Tokyo. Lecture 12. The Neo-Classical Growth Model: Prelude to LS Chapter 11.

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Non-parametric counterfactual analysis in dynamic general equilibrium

Noncooperative Games, Couplings Constraints, and Partial Effi ciency

In the Ramsey model we maximized the utility U = u[c(t)]e nt e t dt. Now

Dynamic Problem Set 1 Solutions

On the survival and Irreductibility Assumptions for Financial Markets with Nominal Assets

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Macroeconomic Theory II Homework 2 - Solution

Mathematical models in economy. Short descriptions

MAGYAR NEMZETI BANK MINI-COURSE

Economics 201B Second Half. Lecture 10, 4/15/10. F (ˆp, ω) =ẑ(ˆp) when the endowment is ω. : F (ˆp, ω) =0}

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Competitive Equilibrium

(6, 4) Is there arbitrage in this market? If so, find all arbitrages. If not, find all pricing kernels.

DYNAMIC LECTURE 5: DISCRETE TIME INTERTEMPORAL OPTIMIZATION

Speculative Investor Behavior and Learning

The Debreu-Scarf Theorem: The Core Converges to the Walrasian Allocations

2 Lecture Span, Basis and Dimensions

Advanced Macroeconomics

Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework

1 The Basic RBC Model

Transcription:

Course Handouts: Pages 1-20 ASSET PRICE BUBBLES AND SPECULATION Jan Werner European University Institute May 2010 1

I. Price Bubbles: An Example Example I.1 Time is infinite; so dates are t = 0,1,2,...,. There is no uncertainty. There is one security that pays zero dividend at every date. Two agents (i = 1,2) with the same utility function u i (c) = β t ln(c t ), (1) t=0 where 0 < β < 1. Agents maximize utility u i (c) subject to budget constraints c 0 + p 0 h 0 = w i 0 + p 0 α i 0, (2) c t + p t h t = w i t + p t h t 1, for all t 1, (3) h t 1, for all t (4) Constraint (4) is a short-sales constraint. Clearly, there is a trivial equilibrium with zero prices, p t = 0 for all t, and no trade. Claim: There can be an equilibrium with p t > 0 for every t. If p t > 0, then the price exceeds the fundamental value and there is price bubble. The fundamental value of zero dividends must be zero. 2

Suppose that endowments are w 1 0 = B + η, w 2 0 = A η, w 1 t = B, w 2 t = A for t even, w 1 t = A, w 2 t = B for t odd, where βa > B > 0. Initial security holdings are α 1 0 = 1 and α 2 0 = 0. The total supply is 1. Let η = βa B 3(1 + β). (5) There is an equilibrium with strictly positive price p t = η, for all t 0, (6) consumption plans c 1 t = (B + 3η) for t even, c 1 t = (A 3η) for t odd c 2 t = (A 3η) for t even, c 2 t = (B + 3η) for t odd, and security holdings h 1 t = 1 for t even, h 1 t = 2 for t odd h 2 t = 2 for t even, h 2 t = 1 for t odd 3

Verifying the equilibrium: (i) markets clear at every date, (ii) budget and short-sales constraints are all satisfied. (iii) verifying that consumption plans and security holdings are optimal: At each odd t, agent s 1 first-order condition is It holds. At each even date t, the first-order condition is β t c 1 t β t c 1 t p t = βt+1 c 1 p t+1, (7) t+1 p t βt+1 c 1 p t+1, (8) t+1 since short-sales constraint is binding. It is satisfied. A suitable transversality condition (see Kocherlakota (1992), Proposition 2) can also be verified to hold. The same for agent 2. So there is equilibrium price bubble. This security is fiat money. 4

II. Equilibrium with Portfolio Constraints II.1 The Model. Time: t = 0,1,... Uncertainty: Infinite set of states S. Information about the state at date t is described by a finite partition F t of S. F t+1 is finer than F t (nondecreasing information). F 0 = {S}. This is an infinite event tree. ξ t F t denotes an event at date t; ξt F t 1 is the predecessor of ξ t at date t 1, that is, ξ t ξt. Securities are traded at each date - infinitely-lived securities. Security j pays dividend x j (ξ t ) at date-t event ξ t for every t 1. Price of security j at date t in event ξ t is p j (ξ t ). A portfolio in event ξ t is h(ξ t ); h = {h t } is a portfolio strategy. Assumption: Dividends are positive, i.e., x(ξ t ) 0 for every ξ t. 5

Agents. Consumption plans: c(ξ t ) in event ξ t at date t; c t event-contingent consumption plan at date t; c = (c 0,c 1,...,). Agent i s utility function u i : C i R, where C i R +. u i is assumed increasing. Endowment is w i, and initial portfolio is α i R J. Consumption-Portfolio Choice. maxu(c) (10) c,h subject to c(ξ 0 ) + p(ξ 0 )h(ξ 0 ) = w(ξ 0 ) + p(ξ 0 )α, c(ξ t ) = w(ξ t ) + (p(ξ t ) + x(ξ t ))h(ξ t ) p(ξ t )h(ξ t ), ξ t t 1, (11) c C, h H (12) H is the set of feasible portfolio strategies. The agent is restricted in her choices of portfolio strategies to those that are in H. Assumption: H is closed, convex, and 0 H. If H = R, then there is no restriction. This would make no sense. Observation: If u is strictly increasing and p(ξ t ) 0 for every ξ t, then there is no solution to the portfolio-consumption choice problem with H = R. 6

Portfolio Constraints. Examples of constraints that may be used to define feasible portfolio set H : short sales constraint h j (ξ t ) b j (ξ t ), ξ t, (13) borrowing constraint p(ξ t )h(ξ t ) B(ξ t ), ξ t, (14) for some sequence of positive bounds {B(ξ t )}. debt constraint [p(ξ t ) + x(ξ t )]h(ξ t ) D(ξ t ), ξ t,,t 1, (15) for some sequence of positive bounds {D(ξ t )}. There are other possible constraints such as transversality constraint, wealth constraint, solvency constraint, collateral constraint, etc. 7

First-Order Conditions. First-order conditions for a solution (c,h) such that (i) c(ξ t ) > 0, ξ t, and (ii) portfolio constraint H is not binding at h, are p j (ξ t ) = ξ t+1 ξ t [p j (ξ t+1 ) + x j (ξ t+1 )] ξt+1u ξt u, j, ξ t (16) The price of security j in event ξ t equals the sum over immediate successor events ξ t+1 of cum-dividend payoffs of security j multiplied by the marginal rate of substitution between consumption in event ξ t+1 and consumption in event ξ t. II.2 Equilibrium in Security Markets with Portfolio Constraints. An equilibrium is an allocation {(c i,h i )} and a price system p such that (i) portfolio strategy h i and consumption plan c i are a solution to agent i s choice problem (10) subject to constraints (11), (12), (ii) markets clear, that is h i (ξ t ) = ᾱ, ξ t (17a) i and c i (ξ t ) = w(ξ t ) + x(ξ t )ᾱ, ξ t. (17b) i 8

III.1 Definitions. III. Arbitrage and Ponzi Schemes. Let z(h,p) denote the (net) payoff of portfolio strategy h in event ξ t : z(h,p)(ξ t ) = (p(ξ t ) + x(ξ t ))h(ξ t ) p(ξ t )h(ξ t ). (18) An arbitrage is a portfolio strategy ĥ such that z(ĥ,p)(ξ t) 0, ξ t t 1, and p 0 ĥ 0 0, (19) with at least one strict inequality. A finite-time arbitrage is an arbitrage portfolio strategy ĥ such that ĥt = 0 for all t τ for some τ. An infinite-time arbitrage is an arbitrage that is not a finite-time arbitrage. A Ponzi scheme is an infinite-time arbitrage portfolio strategy ĥ such that z(ĥ,p)(ξ t) = 0, ξ t t 1, and p 0 ĥ 0 < 0. (20) This is a strategy of rolling over the debt forever. Arbitrage ĥ is unlimited arbitrage for portfolio constraint H if h + λĥ H, λ 0, h H. (21) Condition (21) says that adding strategy ĥ, or an arbitrary multiple thereof, to any portfolio position h does not violate constraint H. Formally, (21) requires 9

that ĥ lies in the asymptotic (or recession) cone of H. If H is a cone, then (21) holds if and only if ĥ H Theorem 1: If agents utility functions are strictly increasing, then, in equilibrium, there is no unlimited arbitrage for H. III.2 Arbitrage and Event Prices. Let H be defined by the borrowing constraint (14). Portfolio strategy ĥ is an unlimited arbitrage under borrowing constraint iff ĥ is an arbitrage and p(ξ t )ĥ(ξ t) 0, ξ t. (22) Clearly, there is no unlimited Ponzi scheme under borrowing constraint at any p. Theorem 2: Assume that p(ξ t ) > 0 for every ξ t. Then there is no unlimited arbitrage under borrowing constraint iff there exist strictly positive numbers q(ξ t ) for all ξ t such that q(ξ t )p j (ξ t ) = q(ξ t+1 )[p j (ξ t+1 ) + x j (ξ t+1 )] ξ t j. (23) ξ t+1 ξ t Strictly positive numbers q(ξ t ) satisfying (23) and normalized so that q(ξ 0 ) = 1 are called event prices. 10

Let H be defined by the debt constraint (15). Portfolio strategy ĥ is an unlimited arbitrage under debt constraint iff ĥ is an arbitrage and [p(ξ t ) + x(ξ t )]ĥ(ξ t ) 0, ξ t,,t 1 (24) Theorem 3: There is no unlimited arbitrage under debt constraint iff there exist strictly positive event prices. 11

IV. Price Bubbles. VI.1 Definitions. Assume that p is such that there exist event prices q >> 0 satisfying (23). The present value at date 0 of security j under q is defined by t=1 ξ t F t q(ξ t )x j (ξ t ). (25) Similarly, we can define present value of security j at any event. Price bubble is the difference between the price and the present value of a security. Price bubble at ξ t is σ j (ξ t ) p j (ξ t ) 1 q(ξ t ) τ>t ξ τ ξ t q(ξ τ )x j (ξ τ ) (26) Theorem 4: Suppose that there exist strictly positive event prices. Then (i) If p(ξ t ) 0 for all ξ t, then 0 σ j (ξ t ) p j (ξ t ), ξ t j. (ii) If security j is of finite maturity (that is, x jt = 0 for t τ for some τ, and that security is not traded after date τ), then σ j (ξ t ) = 0 for all ξ t. (iii) It holds q(ξ t )σ j (ξ t ) = ξ t+1 ξ t q(ξ t+1 )σ j (ξ t+1 ) ξ t j. 12

IV.2 Price Bubbles in Equilibrium. The question is whether price bubbles can be nonzero in equilibrium in security markets. We say that security markets are complete at prices p if the one-period payoff matrix [p j (ξ t+1 ) + x j (ξ t+1 )] j,ξt+1 has the rank equal to the number of events ξ t+1 that are successors of ξ t, for every ξ t. Let H be defined by the borrowing constraint (14). Theorem 5: Let p 0 be an equilibrium price system under the borrowing constraint. Suppose that security markets are complete at p and there exist strictly positive event prices q. If and t=1 q(ξ t ) w(ξ t ) <, ξ t F t ᾱ 0 >> 0, then price bubbles are zero. See Santos and Woodford (1997) (also for incomplete markets), Huang and Werner (2000). 13

Let H be defined by the debt constraint (15). Theorem 5-d: Let p 0 be an equilibrium price system under the debt constraint. Suppose that security markets are complete at p and there exist strictly positive event prices q. If and t=1 q(ξ t ) w(ξ t ) <, ξ t F t ᾱ 0 >> 0, then price bubbles are zero. [This is a conjecture. I am not sure whether the result holds for incomplete markets.] Remark: It is crucial in Theorem 5 that borrowing limits B(ξ t ) are positive, (so that they do not become minimum saving requirements). Similarly, D(ξ t ) are positive in Theorem 6. 14

IV.3 Pareto Optimal Equilibria in Security Markets. A special case of the borrowing constraint is the wealth constraint with B(ξ t ) = 1 q(ξ t ) τ>t where q is a sequence of event prices. ξ τ ξ t q(ξ τ )w(ξ τ ) ξ t, (27) Theorem 6: Let p and {c i,h i } be a security market equilibrium under the wealth constraint. If security markets are complete at p and price bubbles are zero, then {c i } and P given by P(c) ξ t E q(ξ t )c(ξ t ) (28) are an Arrow-Debreu equilibrium. Further, consumption allocation {c i } is Pareto optimal. 15

V. Examples. Example V.1: Binomial event-tree with Prob(up ξ t ) = Prob(down ξ t ) = 1 2. Two consumers with 0 < β < 1. u i (c) = β t E[ln(c t )] t=0 Two securities with dividends x 1 t 1, t, for security 1, and x 2 (ξ t ) = u, or = d depending on whether ξ t = (ξ t 1,up) or ξ t = (ξ t 1,down) for security 2. Assume u > d. Initial portfolio holdings are α 1 = (0,1) and α 2 = (0,0). Endowments are w 1 (ξ t ) = A u, w 2 (ξ t ) = B, whenever ξ t = (ξ t 1,up), and w 1 (ξ t ) = B d, w 2 (ξ t ) = A, whenever ξ t = (ξ t 1,down) for all t 1, and w 1 0 = w 2 0 = A+B 2. Note that w 1 t + w 2 t + (α 1 + α 2 )x t = A + B. 16

This is a no-aggregate risk environment. Portfolio constraint is the wealth constraint (27). Security market equilibrium under the wealth constraint has security prices p 1 (ξ t ) = β τ = β 1 β τ=1 p 2 (ξ t ) = u + d β τ = u + d β 2 2 1 β, and consumption allocation τ=1 c 1 (ξ t ) = c 2 (ξ t ) = A + B, ξ t. 2 and some portfolio strategies h 1,h 2. Security markets are complete at p and price bubbles are zero. Event prices are q(ξ t ) = 1 2 t β t. Equilibrium with bubble has security prices p 1 (ξ t ) = β τ + σ(ξ t ) = τ=1 p 2 (ξ t ) = u + d 2 τ=1 β 1 β + σ(ξ t), β τ = u + d 2 β 1 β, where σ(ξ t ) is chosen arbitrarily subject to (iii) of Theorem 4, that is, σ(ξ t ) = β[ 1 2 σ(ξ t,up) + 1 2 σ(ξ t,down)], (30) and σ(ξ t ) 0, ξ t. Equilibrium consumption allocation {c 1,c 2 } is as before. Portfolio strategies are different. At these security prices markets are complete and there is price bubble on security 1 equal to σ. There is no price bubble on security 2. 17

Example V.2: Suppose that initial asset holdings are α 1 = (1,1) and α 2 = ( 1,0). Portfolio constraint is the wealth constraint (27). There is an equilibrium security prices and p 1 (ξ t ) = β τ + σ(ξ t ) = τ=1 p 2 (ξ t ) = u + d 2 τ=1 β 1 β + σ(ξ t), β τ = u + d 2 β 1 β, where σ(ξ t ) 0 is chosen arbitrarily subject to (30). At these prices markets are complete and there is price bubble on security 1 equal to σ. There is no price bubble on security 2. Equilibrium allocation is and c 1 (ξ t ) = A + B 2 c 2 (ξ t ) = A + B 2 + σ 0 (1 β), ξ t, σ 0 (1 β), ξ t. This is an Arrow-Debreu equilibrium allocation with transfers: consumer 1 receives date-0 transfer σ 0 from consumer 2. Note that σ 0 has to be small so that agent 2 s consumption be positive. Event prices are q(ξ t ) = 1 2 β t. t 18

Example V.3: Kocherlakota (2008) There is one infinitely lived security with risk-free dividend d, the same at every date, and a full set of one-period Arrow securities at every date-event. One (representative) agent with utility function u i (c) = β t E[v(c t )], (31) t=0 where 0 < β < 1. Consumption endowment is constant ω(ξ t ) = ω. Initial security holding is α 0 = 1. Portfolio constraint is the debt constraint (15) with D(ξ t ) = ω (1 β) The no-trade equilibrium is c t = ω + d, h t = 1, with p(ξ t ) = βd (1 β) Event prices are q(ξ t ) = β t Prob(ξ t ). No bubble in this equilibrium. 19

Consider perturebed debt constraint with adjusted limits ˆD given by where σ satisfies (30). ˆD(ξ t ) = ω (1 β) σ(ξ t) (31) There is an equilibrium with c t = ω + d, h t = 1, and p(ξ t ) = βd (1 β) + σ(ξ t). There is a bubble! Event prices are q(ξ t ) = β t Prob(ξ t ). Note that if the bubble is non-zero, then it must grow without bound for some state and debt limit ˆD given by (31) will become negative (!?) in that state. 20