Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise

Similar documents
Existence and Comparisons for BSDEs in general spaces

Markov Chain BSDEs and risk averse networks

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 Nov 2011

Uniformly Uniformly-ergodic Markov chains and BSDEs

Backward Stochastic Differential Equations with Infinite Time Horizon

Stochastic Calculus for Finance II - some Solutions to Chapter VII

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Thomas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover

Time-Consistent Mean-Variance Portfolio Selection in Discrete and Continuous Time

The main purpose of this chapter is to prove the rst and second fundamental theorem of asset pricing in a so called nite market model.

Random G -Expectations

Minimal Supersolutions of Backward Stochastic Differential Equations and Robust Hedging

Lecture 3 Partial Differential Equations

An Introduction to Malliavin calculus and its applications

On the dual problem of utility maximization

Birgit Rudloff Operations Research and Financial Engineering, Princeton University

A new approach for investment performance measurement. 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009

Robust Mean-Variance Hedging via G-Expectation

Question 1. The correct answers are: (a) (2) (b) (1) (c) (2) (d) (3) (e) (2) (f) (1) (g) (2) (h) (1)

Risk Measures in non-dominated Models

Risk-Minimality and Orthogonality of Martingales

Variance Reduction Techniques for Monte Carlo Simulations with Stochastic Volatility Models

Time consistency in Risk measures

of space-time diffusions

Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options

Introduction to Stochastic Optimization Part 4: Multi-stage decision

A Barrier Version of the Russian Option

Uncertainty in Kalman Bucy Filtering

Portfolio Optimization in discrete time

On continuous time contract theory

Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework

Optimal portfolio strategies under partial information with expert opinions

Economics 2010c: Lectures 9-10 Bellman Equation in Continuous Time

Aggregate Risk. MFM Practitioner Module: Quantitative Risk Management. John Dodson. February 6, Aggregate Risk. John Dodson.

Financial Econometrics

Using Economic Contexts to Advance in Mathematics

A class of globally solvable systems of BSDE and applications

Regularization by noise in infinite dimensions

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 Sep 2018

Sample of Ph.D. Advisory Exam For MathFinance

Probability via Expectation

Numerical Methods with Lévy Processes

Liquidation in Limit Order Books. LOBs with Controlled Intensity

Nonlinear representation, backward SDEs, and application to the Principal-Agent problem

Choquet Integral and Its Applications: A Survey

Introduction Optimality and Asset Pricing

Mean-Variance Hedging for Continuous Processes: New Proofs and Examples

Lecture 02: Summations and Probability. Summations and Probability

Fundamentals in Optimal Investments. Lecture I

X

HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011

Set-Valued Risk Measures and Bellman s Principle

Stochastic Volatility and Correction to the Heat Equation

Mathematics for Economics and Finance

Malliavin Calculus in Finance

Trajectorial Martingales, Null Sets, Convergence and Integration

Noncommutative Geometry and Stochastic Calculus: Applications in Mathematical Finance

High order Cubature on Wiener space applied to derivative pricing and sensitivity estimations

Stochastic Modelling Unit 1: Markov chain models

Discrete-Time Finite-Horizon Optimal ALM Problem with Regime-Switching for DB Pension Plan

THE ASYMPTOTIC ELASTICITY OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS 1

Regression: Ordinary Least Squares

Backward martingale representation and endogenous completeness in finance

Numerical scheme for quadratic BSDEs and Dynamic Risk Measures

Slides II - Dynamic Programming

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs

Minimal Sufficient Conditions for a Primal Optimizer in Nonsmooth Utility Maximization

A MODEL FOR THE LONG-TERM OPTIMAL CAPACITY LEVEL OF AN INVESTMENT PROJECT

Minimal entropy preserves the Lévy property: How and why

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 4

Quadratic BSDE systems and applications

Multi-Factor Finite Differences

STRICT LOCAL MARTINGALE DEFLATORS AND PRICING AMERICAN CALL-TYPE OPTIONS. 0. Introduction

Market environments, stability and equlibria

Least Squares Estimators for Stochastic Differential Equations Driven by Small Lévy Noises

Approximation of BSDEs using least-squares regression and Malliavin weights

An application of hidden Markov models to asset allocation problems

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Short-time expansions for close-to-the-money options under a Lévy jump model with stochastic volatility

The Real Option Approach to Plant Valuation: from Spread Options to Optimal Switching

1 Markov decision processes

A Simple Computational Approach to the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing

ISSN Article. Optimal Dynamic Portfolio with Mean-CVaR Criterion

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Macro 1: Dynamic Programming 1

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 2

Asymptotic distribution of the sample average value-at-risk

Chapter 2 Event-Triggered Sampling

Equilibrium Valuation with Growth Rate Uncertainty

2.3. The heat equation. A function u(x, t) solves the heat equation if (with σ>0)

QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE

Convex Stochastic Control and Conjugate Duality in a Problem of Unconstrained Utility Maximization Under a Regime Switching Model

A problem of portfolio/consumption choice in a. liquidity risk model with random trading times

An Option Value Problem from Seinfeld

Geometry and Optimization of Relative Arbitrage

MATHEMATICS (MATH) Mathematics (MATH) 1

MFM Practitioner Module: Risk & Asset Allocation. John Dodson. February 4, 2015

Dynamic Pricing for Non-Perishable Products with Demand Learning

Order book resilience, price manipulation, and the positive portfolio problem

Controlled Diffusions and Hamilton-Jacobi Bellman Equations

Transcription:

Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise Robert J. Elliott 1 Samuel N. Cohen 2 1 Department of Commerce, University of South Australia 2 Mathematical Insitute, University of Oxford

Outline Risk and Expectation What is a BSDE? A special case: Black-Scholes pricing BSDEs on Markov Chains. Uses of BSDEs Comparing BSDEs The Comparison Theorem When the comparison fails Building Nonlinear Expectations Geometry of Solutions Conclusions and Future Work

Risk and Expectation Risk and Expectation With recent events it has become increasingly clear that we need to have a good understanding of risk. One aspect of this is the development of simple ways of representing risk numerically. Some of these ways are well known value at risk, expected shortfall, etc... Unfortunately, these methods are static, and fail to give consistent answers when considered at multiple time points.

Risk and Expectation Various progress has been made in developing dynamic risk measures, which give time consistent answers. These are closely related to the g-expectations considered by Peng and others. Central to the mathematical study of these is the theory of Backward Stochastic Differential Equations (BSDEs). Most work in this area uses only noise from a Brownian motion; we here consider using a Markov chain instead.

What is a BSDE? What is a BSDE? Replicating portfolios are a common theme in Mathematical Finance the classic example in a complete market is replicating the payoff of an option using a combination of the stock and a risk free asset. Backward Stochastic Differential Equations can be thought of as a generalisation of this.

What is a BSDE? Q = Y t F (ω, u, Y u, Z u )du + Z u dm u ]t,t ] ]t,t ] Q is the random terminal value Y t corresponds to the value of a replicating portfolio Z t corresponds to the hedging components of the portfolio F is a driver function which gives the cost of holding the portfolio at time t, in some sense. This function can be random and non-linear. For simplicity, we shall assume Q, Y t, F all take values in R.

What is a BSDE? Q = Y t F (ω, u, Y u, Z u )du + Z u dm u ]t,t ] ]t,t ] M is a martingale (in R N ), and so the last term is a stochastic integral. Z is takes values in R 1 N, so Z u dm u is scalar. Most people consider the case where M is a Brownian motion. We shall consider what happens when M is the martingale component of a Markov chain.

What is a BSDE? Q = Y t F (ω, u, Y u, Z u )du + Z u dm u ]t,t ] ]t,t ] The key idea is that: Q is not known until time T The dynamics are given over the future interval ]t, T ]. The solution is a pair (Y, Z ), which is adapted, that is, Y t and Z t are known at time t. In fact, Z is a predictable (typically left-continuous) process.

What is a BSDE? A special case: Black-Scholes pricing A special case: Black-Scholes pricing Suppose we have a market with two assets: a stock S following a simple geometric Brownian motion, and a risk free Bond B. Assume zero interest rates (for simplicity). Let Q = Y T be a contingent payoff. Standard theory tells us that there is a unique no-arbitrage price at time t, [ ] dq Y t = E P dp Y T F t.

What is a BSDE? A special case: Black-Scholes pricing We can also write Y T = E P (Y T F t ) + L T t where E P (Y t+1 F t ) is the (real-world) conditional mean value of Y t+1, and L T t is an F T -measurable random variable with F t -conditional mean value zero. Using the Martingale Representation theorem, we can write L T t = Z u dm u ]t,t ] where M is the underlying Brownian motion, and Z is a predictable process.

What is a BSDE? A special case: Black-Scholes pricing We can then do some basic algebra: Y T = E P (Y T F t ) + L T t = Y t E Q (Y T F t ) + E P (Y T F t ) + = Y t E Q (Y T E P (Y T F t ) F t ) + ]t,t ] ]t,t ] Z u dm u Z u dm u ( ) = Y t E Q Z u dm u F t + Z u dm u. ]t,t ] ]t,t ]

What is a BSDE? A special case: Black-Scholes pricing Through the use of Girsanov s Theorem, one can show ( ) E Q Z u dm u F t = θ u Z u du ]t,t ] ]t,t ] for some process θ. Hence the price of Y is simply the solution of Y T = Y t θ u Z u du + Z u dm u ]t,t ] ]t,t ] This is a special case of a BSDE, with F(ω, t, Y t, Z t ) = θ t Z t.

What is a BSDE? BSDEs on Markov Chains. Markov Chains and Martingales Suppose we have an N state Markov chain X, with rate matrix A. We associate each of the states of X with the standard basis vectors in R N. We can write X as a semimartingale X t = X 0 + A u X u du + M u. ]0,t] (A u X u ) is a vector giving the rate, at time u, at which X will jump into each of the alternative states.

What is a BSDE? BSDEs on Markov Chains. Existence of BSDE solutions Theorem (Pardoux & Peng (1990)) Suppose M is an N-dimensional Brownian motion generating {F t }. If Q L 2 (F T ), (Q has finite variance and is known at time T ) and F is uniformly Lipschitz continuous dt P-a.e., then there exists a unique solution (Y, Z ) which is square integrable and adapted. Theorem (Cohen & Elliott (2008)) This is also true when M is the martingale component of a Markov chain.

What is a BSDE? Uses of BSDEs Uses of BSDEs Markov Chains have been used to model various market characteristics particularly where regime switching is involved. BSDEs can be used to price assets defined in these markets. BSDEs can also be used for other things pricing with constraints, recursive utilities, risk theory.

Comparing BSDEs Comparing BSDEs For many of these applications, we need to be able to compare the solutions to BSDEs with different terminal conditions. When thinking about pricing, we need to ensure that the prices we give are Arbitrage free. When thinking about risk, we want a more positive outcome to be preferred to a less positive outcome The key result here is the comparison theorem. This is very closely related to the maximum principle for second-order nonlinear PDEs.

Comparing BSDEs The Comparison Theorem The Comparison Theorem Consider two BSDEs. Suppose (i) Q 1 Q 2 a.s. (ii) F 1 (ω, u, Yu, 2 Zu 2 ) F 2 (ω, u, Yu, 2 Zu 2 ) a.s. for almost all u. (iii) There exists ɛ > 0 such that, for all u, if (e j A ux u )[Z 1 u Z 2 u ](e j X u ) ɛ Z 1 u Z 2 u Xu for all e j then F 1 (u, Y 2 u, Z 1 u ) F 1 (u, Y 2 u, Z 2 u ) [Z 1 u Z 2 u ]A t X u with equality only if Z 1 u Z 2 u Xu = 0. Then Y 1 t Y 2 t for all t.

Comparing BSDEs The Comparison Theorem The Comparison Theorem Consider two BSDEs. Suppose (i) Q 1 Q 2 a.s. (ii) F 1 (ω, u, Y 2 u, Z 2 u ) F 2 (ω, u, Y 2 u, Z 2 u ) a.s. for almost all u. (iii) Either 1. All jumps of M have no impact on Y 1 Y 2, or 2. One of the jumps of M should result in a (significant) decrease in Y 1 Y 2, or 3. The difference between Z 1 and Z 2 should have a decreasing effect on Y 1 Y 2 when there are no jumps. Then Y 1 t Y 2 t for all t.

Comparing BSDEs The Comparison Theorem The Comparison Theorem The intuitive version of this result is: Provided conditions (ii) and (iii) hold, if the terminal value Q 1 is more than the value Q 2 with probability one, then the initial value Y 1 0 must be more than Y 2 0. In terms of prices if one asset is always worth more than another in the future, it must have a higher price today.

Comparing BSDEs When the comparison fails When the comparison fails When M is a Brownian motion, Assumption (iii) is not needed. There are various technical reasons for this basically because we know that equivalent martingale measures exist for certain quantities. In our setting, Assumption (iii) is unavoidable. (In some cases it can be shown to be a necessary condition.)

Comparing BSDEs When the comparison fails When the comparison fails Without (iii), we could have the situation where Y0 1 Y 0 2 starts just below zero, increases between jumps of M, and jumps up at each jump of M. Then Y 1 T Y 2 T = Q1 Q 2 ends above zero so we have a situation where the terminal values are Q 1 Q 2, but the initial values are Y 1 0 Y 2 0.

Building Nonlinear Expectations Given this theory, we are now able to construct explicit examples of nonlinear expectations. These are the g-expectations in a Markov Chain context (cf. Peng and others for Brownian motion) We begin with a general definition.

Building Nonlinear Expectations Nonlinear Expectations For some terminal time T, we define an F t -consistent nonlinear expectation E to be a family of operators with E( F t ) : L 2 (F T ) L 2 (F t ); t T 1. (Monotonicity) If Q 1 Q 2 P-a.s., E(Q 1 F t ) E(Q 2 F t ) 2. (Constants) For all F t -measurable Q, E(Q F t ) = Q

Building Nonlinear Expectations Nonlinear Expectations 3. (Recursivity) For s t, E(E(Q F t ) F s ) = E(Q F s ) 4. (Regularity) For any A F t, E(I A Q F t ) = I A E(Q F t ).

Building Nonlinear Expectations Nonlinear Expectations Two further properties are commonly desirable 5. (Translation invariance) For any q L 2 (F t ), E(Q + q F t ) = E(Q F t ) + q. 6. (Concavity) For any λ [0, 1], E(λQ 1 + (1 λ)q 2 F t ) λe(q 1 F t ) + (1 λ)e(q 2 F t )

Building Nonlinear Expectations Nonlinear Expectations There is a relation between nonlinear expectations and convex risk measures: If (1)-(6) are satisfied, then for each t, ρ t (Q) := E(Q F t ) defines a dynamic convex risk measure. These risk measures are time consistent. Using risk measures related to BSDEs is less intuitive than Value at Risk, etc..., but gives better behaviour we know when they are convex and time consistent.

Building Nonlinear Expectations Theorem Let F be a driver for a BSDE. Suppose F(ω, t, Y t, 0) = 0 and F satisfies Assumption (iii) of the comparison theorem, then the solution to a BSDE is a nonlinear expectation, that is E(Q F t ) = Y t gives a nonlinear expectation satisfying Axioms (1-4).

Building Nonlinear Expectations If F does not depend on Y, then the nonlinear expectation is translation invariant, (Axiom 5), i.e. for all q L 2 (F t ), E(Q + q F t ) = E t (Q F t ) + q. If F is concave, then E( F t ) is concave (Axiom 6), that is, the nonlinear expectation is risk averse.

Building Nonlinear Expectations Geometry of Solutions Geometry When F does not depend on Y and F(ω, u, Y u, 0) = 0, then the values Y t must lie between the possible values of Q, given information up to time t. Q Y 0

Building Nonlinear Expectations Geometry of Solutions Geometry If we think of Y as the discounted price of an asset, this means that the current value of the asset must lie within the possible range of future values if the value can increase, then it could also decrease. This result can be generalised to when Y is undiscounted but interest rates are deterministic, or, mathematically, when F(ω, t, Y, 0) is deterministic. The comparison theorem requires that this holds for the difference of two Y values. The details of these assumptions are critical when considering these equations on infinite horizons.

Conclusions and Future Work Conclusions The theory of BSDEs based on Markov chains allows us to develop dynamic risk measures/nonlinear expectations in this setting. A significant distinction between the case of Markov chain noise and Brownian noise is the requirements for the comparison theorem. Combining Brownian motion and Markov Chains into a single system (as in Regime switching models) would be a straightforward extension of this work.

Conclusions and Future Work Future work Extending the comparison theorem to other settings is nontrivial, but would help with developing a more general theory of BSDEs. (We have some results here.) Are all dynamic nonlinear expectations BSDE solutions? In discrete time, yes; With Brownian noise/general processes, yes, under certain boundedness assumptions (Coquet et al 2002, Hu et al 2008, Cohen 2012) Calculating the values of these solutions is of practical interest. This can be done using Monte-Carlo regression methods.