Online Appendix for Slow Information Diffusion and the Inertial Behavior of Durable Consumption

Similar documents
Slow Information Diffusion and the Inertial Behavior of Durable. Consumption

What We Don t Know Doesn t Hurt Us: Rational Inattention and the. Permanent Income Hypothesis in General Equilibrium

Robustifying the Permanent Income Model with Rational. Inattention

Elastic Attention, Risk Sharing, and International Comovements

Model Uncertainty, State Uncertainty, and State-space Models

Elastic Attention, Risk Sharing, and International Comovements

Lecture 2. (1) Permanent Income Hypothesis (2) Precautionary Savings. Erick Sager. February 6, 2018

Topic 6: Consumption, Income, and Saving

Consumption dynamics under information processing constraints

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Robust Control, Informational Frictions, and International. Consumption Correlations

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

The Real Business Cycle Model

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Demand Shocks with Dispersed Information

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

Endogenous Information Choice

Robustness, Information-Processing Constraints, and the Current Account in Small Open Economies

Rational Inattention

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING

Advanced Macroeconomics

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Model Uncertainty and Intertemporal Tax Smoothing

Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium and Growth

Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-financing Undo Capital Misallocation?

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 2

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

APPENDIX TO RESERVE REQUIREMENTS AND OPTIMAL CHINESE STABILIZATION POLICY

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

Advanced Macroeconomics

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework

New Notes on the Solow Growth Model

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ESTIMATING DISCOUNT FUNCTIONS WITH CONSUMPTION CHOICES OVER THE LIFECYCLE. David Laibson Andrea Repetto Jeremy Tobacman

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy

Macroeconomics Theory II

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 2

"0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

Simulating Aggregate Dynamics of Buffer-Stock Savings Models using the Permanent-Income-Neutral Measure

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

In the Ramsey model we maximized the utility U = u[c(t)]e nt e t dt. Now

The Lucas Imperfect Information Model

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Macroeconomics Theory II

Learning to Optimize: Theory and Applications

Problem Set 4. Graduate Macro II, Spring 2011 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims

Demand Shocks, Monetary Policy, and the Optimal Use of Dispersed Information

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Expectations and Monetary Policy

An approximate consumption function

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

Technical appendices: Business cycle accounting for the Japanese economy using the parameterized expectations algorithm

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Inference. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Estimating Discount Functions with Consumption Choices over the Lifecycle

Stochastic Problems. 1 Examples. 1.1 Neoclassical Growth Model with Stochastic Technology. 1.2 A Model of Job Search

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

ECOM 009 Macroeconomics B. Lecture 3

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

Optimal Monetary Policy with Informational Frictions

Consumption / Savings Decisions

Using Theory to Identify Transitory and Permanent Income Shocks: A Review of the Blundell-Preston Approach

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Ambiguity and Information Processing in a Model of Intermediary Asset Pricing

Model Uncertainty and Intertemporal Tax Smoothing

Lecture notes on modern growth theory

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

Incomplete Markets, Heterogeneity and Macroeconomic Dynamics

Proper Welfare Weights for Social Optimization Problems

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SENTIMENTS AND AGGREGATE DEMAND FLUCTUATIONS. Jess Benhabib Pengfei Wang Yi Wen

Graduate Macroeconomics - Econ 551

Approximation around the risky steady state

Volume 29, Issue 4. Stability under learning: the neo-classical growth problem

The Natural Rate of Interest and its Usefulness for Monetary Policy

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

Journal of International Economics

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model

Lecture 6: Discrete-Time Dynamic Optimization

Problem 1 (30 points)

HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 17 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.

Macroeconomic Theory II Homework 2 - Solution

Advanced Macroeconomics

Transcription:

Online Appendix for Slow Information Diffusion and the Inertial Behavior of Durable Consumption Yulei Luo The University of Hong Kong Jun Nie Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Eric R. Young University of Virginia June 30, 014 1. Solving Bernanke s Adjustment Costs Model Given the utility function and the budget constraints u c t, k t, k t 1 ) = 1 c c t) ϱ k k t ) ϑ k t k t 1 ) 1) a t+1 = Ra t + 1 δ) k t 1 k t + y t c t, ) we can solve for the following decision rules of nondurables and durables following the same procedure used in Bernanke 1985): c t = G c at + G k k t 1 + G y y t ) + g0, 3) k t = x 1 k t 1 + x 1 1 β 1 δ)) ) c t + h 0, 4) d 1 x 1 = βϱ+1+β)ϑ βϑ where g 0 and h 0 are irrelevant constant terms, x 1 and x satisfying x 1 + x and x 1 x = 1 β are two real eigenvalues suppose x 1 < x without loss of generality) for the secondorder stochastic difference equation: k t 1 + hk t + βe t k t+1 = 0, School of Economics and Finance, Faculty of Business and Economics, The University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong. Email address: yluo@econ.hku.hk. Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. E-mail: jun.nie@kc.frb.org. Department of Economics, University of Virginia, Charlottesville, VA 904. Email address: eyd@virginia.edu. 1

and G y = 1 R 1, 5) x 1 G k = β 1 δ) + β 1 δ) 1), 6) R x 1 1 G c = R 1) 1 + 1 β 1 δ)) R x 1 ). 7) R x 1 ϑ 1 x 1 Note that as ϑ goes to 0, 3) and 4) reduces to 7) and 8) in the main text because lim ϑ 0 x 1 = 0 x and lim 1 ϑ 0 ϑ1 x 1 ) = 1 βϱ. To obtain the explicit dynamics of nondurables and durables consumption in this model, we define a new state variable, permanent income s t, as s t = a t + G k k t 1 + G y y t, and reformulate the original budget constraint ) as s t+1 = s t + G y ε t+1. 8) after using 3) and 4). We can then obtain the dynamics of c t, k t ), 53) and 54) of the text, by combining 3), 4), with 8).. Solving the CARA Model under SID In the CARA model with the utility function: u c t, k t ) = 1 α c exp α c c t ) ϱ α k exp α k k t ), where α c > 0 and α k > 0, following the same procedure adopted in Caballero 1990) and using the same budget constraint specified in Section 6.3, we can readily solve for the decision rules for both nondurable and durable consumption under full information as follows: 1 where s t = a t + 1 δ R k t 1 + 1 R 1 y t, H c = R 1) ) Ω k = 1 α k ln R+δ 1 ϱ, Π c = 1 R 1Φ, and Φ = 1 α c ln βr) + 1 α c c t = H c s t + Ω c + Π c, 9) k t = Ω k + α c α k c t, 10) 1, 1 + R+δ 1) Rϱ Ωc = R+δ 1 R 1 + 1 1 + R+δ 1) Rϱ Ωk, R + δ 1) ω. 11) ϱr Comparing 7) and 8)) with 9) and 10)), it is clear that the MPC out of permanent income in the model with a quadratic utility function and the model with a CARA utility function are the same. Consequently, the two models lead to the same stochastic properties of the joint dynamics of nondurable and durable consumption. 1 Note that here we set α c α k = R+δ 1 ϱ such that the ratios of the marginal propensity to consume MPC) in the durable and nondurable consumption functions are the same as in both the quadratic and CARA-PIH models.

Incorporating the SID assumption into the CARA model, we formulate the optimization problem for the typical household facing state uncertainty: v ŝ t ) = max {c t,k t+1 } E t u c t, k t ) + βv ŝ t+1 subject to where η t+1 = θ ŝ t+1 = Rŝ t c t 1 β 1 δ)) k t + η t+1, 1) ω η = var η t+1 ) = ) θrξ t + ξ t+1, 1 1 θ)r L 13) θ 1 1 θ) R ω ζ > ω ζ, for θ < 1, 14) ζ t+1 1 1 θ)r L and given â 0. Solving this Bellman equation yields the following consumption and durable accumulation functions: c t = H c ŝ t + Ω c + Π c, 15) k t = Ω k + α c α k c t. 16) Given the original budget constraint and the two decision rules, the expression for individual saving, d t R 1) a t + y t c t k t 1 δ) k t 1 )), can be written as: 1 + R + δ 1) /ϱ d t = 1 1 + R + δ 1) / ϱr) R η t + R 1) s t ŝ t ) + 1 + R + δ 1 Φ, H c ϱ ) ζ where η t = θ t + ξ 1 1 θ)r L t θrξ t 1 and s 1 1 θ)r L t ŝ t = 1 θ)ζ t 1 1 θ)r L θξ t 1 1 θ)r L. Following the same aggregation procedure presented in the last section, aggregating across all consumers yields the expression for aggregate saving, Expression 59) in the text. Using 59), the expression for Φ: Φ = 1 α c ln βr) + 1 α c 1 + R + δ 1) ω, ϱr and the corresponding expression for aggregate saving in the benchmark model in which 1 + R + δ 1) /ϱ θζ t d t = 1 1 + R + δ 1) / ϱr) 1 1 θ)r L + R 1) 1 θ) ζ t 1 1 θ)r L, we can obtain 60) in the text. If RI is considered as the microfoundation for the slow information diffusion, the results from the CARA case are valid only approximately when the capacity is not too low. 3

3. Fixed Cost and Infrequent Adjustment Consider the SID model proposed in Section 6.4. Here for simplicity we only consider the original Mankiw model no nondurable goods) in which the utility function uk t ) = 1 ). k k t Under SID, the agent adjusts optimal consumption plans in every period but the adjustments are incomplete. In this case, the welfare loss due to incomplete adjustment is v 1 = min E t 1 β j t k j k j ) where E t is formed using processed information and is subject to noisy observations described in Section 6.3, and k j = H k s j is the first-best FI-RE plan. As shown in Section 4., the optimal consumption plan under SID can be written as k t = H k E t s t, where E t s t is the perceived state variable. Substituting the optimal rule under SID into the objective function, the welfare loss due to incomplete adjustments can be rewritten as v 1 = 1 β s t E t k j H k E j sj ), H k σ = 1 1 β, where j t, and σ = var j sj ) = Ej k j H k E j sj ) is the steady state conditional variance from the Kalman filter. Here we assume that the typical consumer with imperfect state observations faces fixed costs F > 0) in each period for adjusting optimal plans; the present value of fixed costs is then βf 1 β. We now consider a model of infrequent adjustment in durable consumption. The key assumption of this model is that consumers are inattentive in the sense that every period they update the information about their permanent income with some probability and thus adjust optimal plans infrequently; in other words, only a fraction of them update their information and make optimal adjustments in any period. Following the literature, we assume that the exogenous probability at which the typical consumer updates his expectations and re-optimizes in any given period is π, independent of the length of time since the optimal plan was set. The consumer sets his optimal consumption plan at t to minimize a quadratic loss function that depends on the difference between the consumer s actual consumption plan at period t, k t, and his first-best instantaneously-adjusted plan k t. If the consumer chooses to adjust at period t, he sets optimal consumption to minimize 1 E t β j t k j k j ), where E t is formed using all available information. The following diagram illustrates the evolu- 4

tion of infrequent adjustments over time. 3 π: adjust at t + 1 If adjust at t π: adjust at t + { 1 π: not adjust at t + 1 1 π: not adjust at t + π: adjust at t + 3 1 π: not adjust at t + 3 Therefore, the present discounted welfare losses if the agent adjusts at time t and re-optimizes with the same probability π at t + 1), v, can be written as v = E t 1 1 π) β) j t k t k j ) + +1 1 π) j t 1 β j t π v + F ). 17) The first term in 17) measures the welfare losses due to deviations of actual plans from desired first-best) plans, and the losses are discounted by the discount factor β j t) and the probability that k t will still be set in period j 1 π) j t) ; the second term represents the value of adjusting consumption plans at period j j > t) and continuing the procedure. Solving 17) gives 1 β) v = 1 1 β 1 π E t 1 π) β) j t k t k j ) + πβf; the first order condition with respect to k t means that k t = 1 β 1 π = H k ŝ t k t, for any t 0, β 1 π)) j t E t k j, j t where we use the facts that under noisy signals and slow learning k j = H k ŝ j, s j+1 = s j + ζ j+1, and ŝ j+1 = ŝ j + η j+1. We can therefore calculate that which implies that 1 β) v = 1 H k H k v = 1 1 β β 1 π) 1 β 1 π) ω ζ + σ + πβf, β 1 π) 1 β 1 π) ω ζ + σ + πβ F. 18) 1 β In this case, if the agent adjusts in every period v reduces to v 1 + βf 1 β.4 Furthermore, if we allow for endogenous choice of the probability π, the first-order condition 3 Kiley 000) applied a similar idea to a firm optimization problem. 4 Note that we have imposed the restriction that βr = 1. 5

for 18) implies that the optimal probability is π = H kω ζ β F + β 1 β, 19) which means that the optimal frequency of adjustment is increasing in the volatility of the innovation to permanent income ω ζ ) and decreasing in the fixed cost F. Therefore, we have the following key result: If the fixed cost is small enough, i.e., F < F 1 H k ω ζ, 0) it is optimal for the inattentive consumer to adjust in each period. The result can be obtained by substituting 18) and 19) into v < v 1 + βf 1 β. Note that it is optimal for the consumer to adjust infrequently if and only if v < v 1 + βf 1 β. 4. Aggregate Consumption under Infrequent Adjustment Denote ki,t = H k ŝ t, the optimal durables stock chosen by a household i who updated expectations about permanent income in the current) period t. 5 Hence, this consumer s actual consumption equals the optimal levels of consumption chosen: k i,t = k i,t. Households who do not update their expectations in period t + 1 consume k i,t+1 = k i,t = k i,t until they update their expectations; we assume updating happens with the probability π. 6 Nondurable and durable consumption per capita in period t that would prevail if all consumers updated their expectations are K t = ˆ 1 0 k i,t di. 5 As shown in Section 4., ŝ t = θ ζ t 1 1 θ)r L + ξ t θrξ t 1. 1 1 θ)r L 6 This specification differs from Reis 006); in his model, consumption can evolve deterministically over the planning period. Given any distaste for intertemporal variance of consumption combined with perfect capital markets, such deterministic variation would be suboptimal anyway. 6

Because the set of consumers who choose to update is randomly selected from the continuum of agents, the mean consumption of those consumers who choose to update can be written as K π t = ˆ 1 0 π i,t k i,t di = π K t. If this result holds in every past period, it leads to the following expressions for per capita nondurable and durable consumption 7 K ia t = π 1 π) j K t j. 1) j=0 Aggregating the change in individual consumption across all consumers, k i,t = θh k ζ t 1 1 θ)r L + θrξ ξ t t 1, ) 1 1 θ)r L we obtain which means that K ia t = ζ t K t = θh k 1 1 θ)r L πθh k ζ t 1 1 π) L) 1 1 θ)r L). 3) References 1 Bernanke, B. 1985), Adjustment Costs, Durables, and Aggregate Consumption, Journal of Monetary Economics 15, 41-68. Caballero, R.J. 1990), Consumption Puzzles and Precautionary Savings, Journal of Monetary Economics 5, 113-136. 3 Carroll, C.D. and J. Slacalek 006), Sticky Expectations and Consumption Dynamics, mimeo, Johns Hopkins University. 4 Kiley, M. 000), Endogenous Price Stickiness and Business Cycle Persistence, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 3, 8-53. 5 Reis, R. 006), Inattentive Consumers, Journal of Monetary Economics 53, 1761-1800. 7 See Carroll and Slacalek 006) for the derivation. 7