Solving Monetary (MIU) models with Linearized Euler Equations: Method of Undetermined Coefficients

Similar documents
Hansen s basic RBC model

Linearization. (Lectures on Solution Methods for Economists V: Appendix) Jesús Fernández-Villaverde 1 and Pablo Guerrón 2 February 21, 2018

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

News-Shock Subroutine for Prof. Uhlig s Toolkit

Macroeconomics II Money in the Utility function

1 The Basic RBC Model

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Chapter 11 The Stochastic Growth Model and Aggregate Fluctuations

Lecture VI. Linearization Methods

Linearized Euler Equation Methods

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Decentralised economies I

The Real Business Cycle Model

Suggested Solutions to Homework #6 Econ 511b (Part I), Spring 2004

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

New Keynesian Macroeconomics

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

Macroeconomics Theory II

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

"0". Doing the stuff on SVARs from the February 28 slides

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 6. Solving Models with Rational Expectations

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 7. The Real Business Cycle Model

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: Solving Models with Rational Expectations

The Ramsey Model. (Lecture Note, Advanced Macroeconomics, Thomas Steger, SS 2013)

Macroeconomics Theory II

A simple macro dynamic model with endogenous saving rate: the representative agent model

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

Foundation of (virtually) all DSGE models (e.g., RBC model) is Solow growth model

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on Quantitative Analysis in DSGE Models

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Solution Methods. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde. University of Pennsylvania. March 16, 2016

Problem 1 (30 points)

Graduate Macroeconomics - Econ 551

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations?

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics

Lecture 2 The Centralized Economy

Monetary Policy and Equilibrium Indeterminacy in a Cash in Advance Economy with Investment. Abstract

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

Technical appendices: Business cycle accounting for the Japanese economy using the parameterized expectations algorithm

Introduction to Numerical Methods

Problem Set 4. Graduate Macro II, Spring 2011 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims

The welfare cost of energy insecurity

Often, researchers wish to analyze nonlinear dynamic discrete-time stochastic models. This paper

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

Endogenous Information Choice

Learning, Expectations, and Endogenous Business Cycles

Bayesian Estimation of DSGE Models: Lessons from Second-order Approximations

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

HOMEWORK #3 This homework assignment is due at NOON on Friday, November 17 in Marnix Amand s mailbox.

Inference. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

The economy is populated by a unit mass of infinitely lived households with preferences given by. β t u(c Mt, c Ht ) t=0

Lecture 15 Real Business Cycle Model. Noah Williams

1. Using the model and notations covered in class, the expected returns are:

Money in the utility model

New Keynesian DSGE Models: Building Blocks

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Housing and the Business Cycle

The Propagation of Monetary Policy Shocks in a Heterogeneous Production Economy

Lecture 7: Linear-Quadratic Dynamic Programming Real Business Cycle Models

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

The Small-Open-Economy Real Business Cycle Model

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

Advanced Macroeconomics

Stochastic simulations with DYNARE. A practical guide.

Session 4: Money. Jean Imbs. November 2010

Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy

An approximate consumption function

Asset pricing in DSGE models comparison of different approximation methods

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 Solutions

The Dark Corners of the Labor Market

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Structural change in a multi-sector model of the climate and the economy

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, :00 am - 2:00 pm

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Solving Deterministic Models

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Real Business Cycle Models. Jordi Galí. Universitat Pompeu Fabra Spring 2018

CREDIT SEARCH AND CREDIT CYCLES

Lecture 2. (1) Permanent Income Hypothesis (2) Precautionary Savings. Erick Sager. February 6, 2018

Transcription:

Int. J. Res. Ind. Eng. Vol. 6, No. 2 (207) 72 83 International Journal of Research in Industrial Engineering www.riejournal.com Solving Monetary (MIU) models with Linearized Euler Equations: Method of Undetermined Coefficients S.F. Fakhrehosseini, *, M. Kaviani 2 Department of Business Management, Tonekabon Branch, Islamic Azad University, Iran 2 PHD Student (Financial management), Islamic Azad University, Iran (meysamkaviani@gmail.com) A B S T R A C T This paper attempts to solve a benchmark money in utility model by first order Taylor approximation to the policy function. After a brief summary of recent development in first order Taylor approximation in solving dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models, we choose Sidrauski s Money in utility model as a standard model and follow the approach proposed by Uhlig [] to solve for the recursive law of motion at first order. Keywords: DSGE Model, Calibration, monetary models Article history: Received: 05 June 207 Revised : 2 July 207 Accepted: 0 August 207 Available online: 20 August 207. Introduction In this paper I will present another method to solve monetary models or dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models, called the method of undetermined coefficients. The method is proposed by []. He has many papers on this method and nice codes to implement the method easily. Please visit his web page for more information on the method. This paper is basically the summary of []. The method is similar to the method by [2] in the sense that the method crucially depends on linearizing the equations that characterize the solution. In this sense, both methods are categorized as the linearizing Euler equation method. Moreover, both methods are local method. The (potentially) non-linear equations that characterize the solution of the model are linearized around some state, most likely the steady state of the model. Remember that the approximation is valid only around the steady state. Besides, the methods necessarily imply certainty equivalence. We are going to use the monetary model with [3]. We apply these methods to the Sidrauski model. But rather than assuming that * Corresponding author E-mail address: f_fkm2@yahoo.com DOI: 0.2205/riej.207.945.005

73 Solving Monetary (MIU) models with Linearized Euler Equations. utility depends just on consumption and money holdings, we also allow utility to depend on the representative agent s consumption of leisure. This introduces a labor supply decision into the analysis, an important and necessary extension for studying business-cycle fluctuations since employment variation is an important characteristic of cycles. For the production function, we can develop approximations around the steady state that can be solved numerically. We also need to add a source, or sources, of exogenous shocks that disturb the system from its steady-state equilibrium. The two types of shocks we will consider will be productivity shocks, the driving force in real-business-cycle models, and shocks to the growth rate of the nominal stock of money. First, we solve the model using the baby version of the solution method. The model is used to show the basic concept of the solution method. Then we show the general formulation of the method. 2. A Money-in-the-Utility (MIU) Model Let's start by describing the social planner's problem in the economy of [3]. We follow the standard specification in dynamic general equilibrium models by assuming that output is produced using capital and labor according to a Cobb-Douglas, constant returns to scale production function. Consistent with the real business cycle literature, we incorporate a stochastic disturbance to total factor productivity, so that y t = e z tk α α t n t 0 α and z t = ρz t + e t is the process followed by the productivity shock. For the utility function, assume a nested CES specification given by u(c t, m t, n t ) = [ac t b Φ + ( a)m b b t ] + ψ ( n t ) η Φ η Where the maximization is subject to the budget constraint y t + τ t +( δ)k t + ( + i t )b t + m t ( + π t ) = c t + k t + m t + b t

S.F.Fakhrehosseini, M. Kaviani / Int. J. Res. Ind. Eng 6(2) (207) 72-83 74 3. The Procedure You need to take the following steps to solve a model using linearized Euler equations and matrix decomposition. The remaining part of the note explains the procedure to the details step by step [4]. A. Find the system of (potentially non-linear) equations that characterize the solution of the model. B. Find the steady state of the model. C. Approximate the non-linear equations in the system around the steady state, using st order Taylor approximation. D. Fit the system of equations into some matrix representation. Since the representation is closely related to the solution method, the representation differs for each solution method. E. Derive the optimal decision rules (linear functions from the state variables to the control variables) and the laws of motion for endogenous state variables (linear function from the state variables to the state variables in the next period). Once the system of equations is fit into the matrix representation associated with the method of undetermined coefficients, the solution is automatically obtained (solution method doesn't depend on the characteristics of the model). 4. Characterizing the Solution The solution of the social planner's problem can include, most importantly, the first order conditions (including the Euler equation), and laws of motion for state variables. Other equations might be included depending on the state and control variables chosen. In general, if we have k exogenous state variables, m endogenous state variables, and n control (jump) variables, we have k + n + m equations or more [5]. In the current example, we choose k = 2(Z, G), m = 2 (K, M), and n = 8 (C, N, Y,π,λ,X,R, and I). Obviously, there is a degree of freedom in how to choose the control variables. For our current examples, the following system of equations characterize the solution to the social planner's problem: max E 0 [ β t [ [ac t {C t,n t,m t,b t, k t } t=0 b Φ + ( a)m b b t ] Φ + ψ ( n t ) η η ] ] s. t. y t + τ t +( δ)k t + ( + i t )b t + m t ( + π t ) y t = e z tk α α t n t = c t + k t + m t + b t Using the assumed functional forms, and letting X t = ac t b + ( a)m t b,with the maximization problem now an unconstrained one over C t, n t, m t, b t and k t. The first order necessary conditions for this problem are

75 Solving Monetary (MIU) models with Linearized Euler Equations. (X t ) b Φ b a(c t ) b = λ t () ψ( n t ) η λ t = ( α) y t n t (2) (X t ) b Φ b ( a)(m t ) b = λ t βε (λ t+ ( + π t+ ) ) (3) λ t = βε (λ t+ + i t ( + π t+ ) ) (4) λ t = βε (λ t+ (α y t+ k t + ( δ))) (5) Then u m u c = ( a b a ) (m t ) = i t (6) c t + i t u l u c = ψ( n t ) η b Φ b b ax t c t = ( α) y t n t (7) b Φ b b ax t c t = βe t (ar t X t+ b Φ b c t+ b ) (8) 5. Finding Steady State R t = α E ty t+ k t + ( δ) (9) I will skip the details. For more details, please see the lecture note for [2] method. The key of this step is to assume that Z stays at its unconditional mean (Z = Z = Z ). With this assumption, we can solve for the steady state values of all the other variables (K, N, Y, C, π, R and I ) In the steady state foe equation (8), R = β. This condition together with (9) implies that the steady-state output-capital ratio is equal to ( y k ) = α ( + δ). From the production function, β ( y k ) = (n k ) α, or ( n k ) = (y k ) α = [ α ( β + δ)] α

S.F.Fakhrehosseini, M. Kaviani / Int. J. Res. Ind. Eng 6(2) (207) 72-83 76 It follows from the aggregate resource constraint that ( c k ) = (y k ) δ = β α ( ) + ( α β α ) δ Since ( + i ) = R ( + π ) and + π = Θ, i = Θ β + i Θ Therefore, using the utility function to evaluate (6) in the steady state yields and ( m c ) = ( a a ) b ( Θ β Θ ( m k ) = ( a a ) b ( Θ β b c ( Θ k ) 6. Calibration Thirteen parameters appear in the equations that characterize behavior around the steady state: α, δ, ρ M, σ 2 2 M, β, a, b, η, Φ, Θ, ρ z, σ Z ) ) b Table. Baseline Parameter Values Parameters Definition Value α the share of capital income in total income 0.42 δ the rate of depreciation of physical capital 0.042 β the subjective rate of time discount in the utility function 0.98 η leisure parameter 2.7 a weight on consumption in composite good definition 0.95 b interest elasticity.32 Θ plus quarterly rate of nominal money growth.23 Φ coefficient of relative risk aversion.5 ρ M Autocorrelation of money shock 0.562 ρ z the autoregressive coefficient in the productivity process 0.72 σ M the standard deviation of innovations to the money growth 0.062 the standard deviation of productivity innovations 0.045 σ z n Steady state employment 0.33 Source [3] [4] [3] [5] [3] [9] [8] [2] [8] [8] [8] [8] [] Value Table 2. Steady-State Values at Baseline Parameter Values Definition Value R Steady state real interest rate 0.072 y Steady state output to capital 0.084 k c Steady state consumption to capital 0.065 k m Steady state money to capital 0.089 k n Steady state employment to capital 0.02 k

77 Solving Monetary (MIU) models with Linearized Euler Equations. 7. Log-linearization Next, we need to linearize the model around the steady state. With the exception of interest rates and inflation, variables will be expressed as percentage deviations around the steady state. Percentage deviations of a variable X around its steady-state value will be denoted by x, X t = X a ( + ax t) X t a = X a ( + ax t) Where η = f(x t) X. X f(x) X t a Y t β = X a Y β ( + ax t + βy t) f(x t ) = f(x) ( + ηx t) If we apply the rules to log-linearize to the system of equations for our current model, we obtain the following system of log-linearized equations: ( y k ) y t = ( c k ) c t + k t ( δ)k t (0) r t = α ( y k ) (E ty t+ k t) () 0 = E t [Ω (c t+ c t ) + Ω 2 (m t+ m t)] r t (2) n y t Ω c t + Ω 2 m t = ( + η n ) n t (3) i t = E t π t+ + r t (4) m t = M t p t = c t ( b ) i t (5) m t = m t π t + u t (6) z t = ρ z z t + e t (7) u t ρ M u t + φ t (8) Where γφ + ( γ)b = Ω, (b Φ)( γ) = Ω 2 γ = [ + a ( a) (m c ) b ]

S.F.Fakhrehosseini, M. Kaviani / Int. J. Res. Ind. Eng 6(2) (207) 72-83 78 Equations () (8) constitute a linearized version of Sidrauski s MIU model. These equations represent a linear system of difference equations involving expectational variables. The endogenous state variables are k and m; the endogenous jump variables are y; c; n; p; i; r, and l; the exogenous variables are z and u. 8. Solving Linear Rational Expectations Models with Forward-Looking Variables This sections provides a brief overview of the approach used to solve linear rational expectations models. This discussion follows [], to which the reader is referred for more details. General discussions can be found in Farmer (993, chapter 3) or the user s guide in [6]. See also [7]. Let x t = (k t, m t ) be the vector of endogenous state variables, and let y t = (y t, c t, n t, i t, π t, r t, λ t ) be the vector of other endogenous variables. The equilibrium conditions of the MIU model can be written in the form 0 = Ax t + Bx t + Cy t + Dz t (9) 0 = E t [Fx t+ + Gx t + Hx t + Jy t+ + Ky t + Lz t+ + Mz t ] (20) z t+ = Nz t + ε t+ ; E t [ε t+ ] = 0 (2) Where x is a vector of endogenous state variables (size m* ), y is a vector of control variables (size n * ), z is a vector of exogenous state variables (size k * ). ε t+ is a vector of shocks (size k * ). C is of size n * n. F is of size m * n, and N has only stable eigenvalues. It is assumed that C is of full column rank and that the eigenvalues of N are all within the unit circle. For this paper A = 0 0 0 0 Ω 2 κ 0 [ 0 ] δ 0 α 0, B = 0 0 0 [ δ 0] D = 0 0 ξ 0 [ ] κ = α(α ) ( y k ) η ( n n ), ξ = α (y k ) ( + η ( n n )) ρ z, Ω 2 = (b Φ)( γ) C is 8*8 then, c = y k, c 2 = c k, c 2 =, c 23 = α, c 32 =, c 35 = b, c 47 =, c 5 =, c 53 = ( + η ( n n )), c 54 =, c 62 = Ω, c 64 =, c 74 = α( α) ( y k )), c 76 = (δ + η ( n n ) + α( α) (y k )), c 88 = δ

79 Solving Monetary (MIU) models with Linearized Euler Equations. Ω = γφ + ( γ)b,γ = [ + a ( a) (m c ) b ] F = [ 0 0 ], G = [0 ], H = [0 ], J = [0 0 0 0 ], K = [ 0 0 0 0 0 0 ], L = [0 ], M = [0 ], N = [ρ z 0 ] 0 ρ m Then if an equilibrium solution to this system of equations exists, it takes the form of stable laws of motion: 9. General Solution Method: Solving the Matrix Equations x t = Px t + Qz t (2) y t = Ry t + Sz t (22) As we did for the simple case, let's substitute out x t, x t+, y t+, y t and z t+ using (20), (2), and (22). Then the equations (9) and (20) become the followings: 0 = A(Px t + Qz t ) + Bx t + C(Rx t + Sz t ) + Dz t 0 = (AP + B + CR)x t + (AQ + CS + D)z t (23) 0 = E t [F(Px t + Qz t+ ) + G(Px t + Qz t ) + Hx t + J(Rx t + Sz t+ ) + K(Rx t + Sz t ) + L(Nz t + ε t+ ) + Mz t ] = F(P(Px t + Qz t ) + QNz t ) + G(Px t + Qz t ) + Hx t + J(R(Px t + Qz t ) + SNz t ) + K(Rx t + Sz t ) + LNz t + Mz t = [(FP + G + JR)P + H + KR]x t + [(FQ + JS + L)N + (FP + G + JR)Q + KS + M]z t (24) Collecting terms and using E t [ε t+ ] = 0. Since the two equations have to be satisfied for any x t and z t : 0 = AP + B + CR (25) 0 = AQ + CS + D (26) 0 = FP 2 + GP + JRP + H + KR (27) 0 = FPQ + FQN + GQ + JRQ + JSN + KS + LN + M (28) Notice (25) and (26) contain only P and R. Solve (25) for R and substitute into (27) and we obtain:

Collecting terms: S.F.Fakhrehosseini, M. Kaviani / Int. J. Res. Ind. Eng 6(2) (207) 72-83 80 FP 2 + GP + J( C AP C B)P + H + K( C AP C B) = 0 (F JC A)P 2 (JC B G + KC A)P KC B + H = 0 (29) To simplify the notation, let's express (29) as follows: ΨP 2 ΓP Θ = 0 (30) This is a matrix quadratic equation of P. There are many ways to solve the equation in general, but an often-used method is to use the generalized eigenvalue problem (also called the QZ decomposition). One of the attractive features for the method is that the method does not require invertibility of Ψ matrix. In general, suppose we have two matrices of the same size X and Y. The generalized eigenvalue problem is to find the generalize eigenvalues λ i and generalized eigenvectors d i satisfying: Xd i = λ i Yd i If we use Y = I, we go back to the standard eigenvalue problem. How do we apply the generalized eigenvalue problem to our matrix quadratic equation? Let's define the following two matrices: Ξ = [ Γ Θ I m,m 0 m.m ], Δ = [ Ψ 0 m.m 0 m.m I m,m ] Where I m,m represents the identity matrix of size m m and 0 m.m represents the m m matrix with only zero entries. Since both Γ and Ψ are m n matrices, both Ξ and Δ are 2m 2m matrices. Now, apply the generalized eigenvalue problem to the pair of matrices. [ Γ Θ I m,m 0 ] [ d i, ] = λ m.m d i [ Ψ 0 m.m i,2 0 m.m I ] [ d i, ] m,m d i,2 If we separate the top and bottom half of the equation, we get: Γd i, + Θd i,2 = λ i Ψd i, d i, = λ i d i,2 The second equation can be used to substitute out d i,. Now we have only one equation (To clean up the notation, let's redefined i = λ i d i,2 ): Γλ i d i + Θd i = λ i Ψλ i d i (3) Suppose we can find m eigenvalues corresponding m linearly independent eigenvectors. Then we have the counterpart of [2] condition.

8 Solving Monetary (MIU) models with Linearized Euler Equations. Proposition If all of the m eigenvalues are inside the unit circle (i.e., maxi λ i < ), the solution is stable [9]. Suppose the condition is satisfied. We can combine (30) for all i as follows: ΨΩΛ 2 ΓΩΛ Θ = 0 (32) Where Ω is m*m matrix which contains all the eigenvectors in each column, and Λ is m*m diagonal matrix with m eigenvalues. Specifically: Ω = [d d 2 d m ] (33) λ 0 Λ = [ ] (34) 0 λ m Multiply (32) by Ω from the right, and we get: ΨΩΛ 2 Ω ΓΩΛΩ Θ = 0 (35) Compare (35) with (35). The equation (35) implies that P = ΩΛΩ. In sum, once we implement the generalized eigenvalue decomposition with respect to Ξ and Δ, we basically got P. Once P is obtained, (25) is used to obtain R as P = [ 0.95578 7.57E 5 0.5694 4.40E 5 ] R = C (AP + B) (36) R = 0.38499 9.27E 06 0.55298 4.607E 05 0.045928 6.076E 06 0.82958 6.88E 05 0.0835.3448E 05 0.036684 2.964E 06 [ 0.5694 0.052865.804E 03 ] The remaining two equations, (26) and (28), contains Q and S. Solve (26) for S and we get: S = C (AQ + D) (37)

Plugging into (28), and we get: S.F.Fakhrehosseini, M. Kaviani / Int. J. Res. Ind. Eng 6(2) (207) 72-83 82 (FP + JR + G KC A)Q + (F JC A)QN JC DN + LN KC D + M = 0 (38) The equation contains only Q as unknown, but it's not trivial as Q is sandwiched in some terms. In this case, we can use the vectorization. The following is useful: vec(axb) = (B T A)vec(X) Where denotes the Kronecker product of the two matrices. Apply vectorization to (38) and we get: (N T (F JC A) + I (FP + JR + G KC A))vec(Q) = vec((jc D L)N + KC D M) (39) Once Q is obtained, we can use (37) to compute S. (N (F JC A) + I k (FP + JR + G KC A))vec(Q) = vec((jc D L)N + KC D M) (40) Q = [ 0.394 0.000245 0.686 0.3805 ] 0. Conclusion s = S = C (AQ + D).0476 3.683E 005 0.76.0022904 0.08094 5.388E 005 0.264 0.0004899 0.00466 0.42284 0.047722.055E 005 [ 0.686.38 3.393 0.0058558 ] In this paper, we have practiced the approach of first order approximation to the policy function in a Money in utility model. We have theoretically solving the approach of approximation to the policy function with the usual approach at the first order. References [] Uhlig, H. (995). A toolkit for analyzing nonlinear dynamic stochastic models easily. [2] Blanchard, O. J., & Kahn, C. M. (980). The solution of linear difference models under rational expectations. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 305-3. [3] Walsh, C. E. (2003). Labor market search and monetary shocks. Elements of Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis, 45-486.

83 Solving Monetary (MIU) models with Linearized Euler Equations. [4] Ruge-Murcia, F. J. (2007). Methods to estimate dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 3(8), 2599-2636. [5] TAEI, H. (2007). An Estimation of Labour Supply Function Using the Iranian Micro Data. [6] Hartley, J. E., Hoover, K. D., & Salyer, K. D. (Eds.). (998). Real business cycles: A reader. Psychology Press. [7] Turnovsky, S. J. (996). Applications of continuous-time stochastic methods to models of endogenous economic growth. Annual reviews in control, 20, 55-66. [8] Fakhrhosseini, S.F. (203). Evaluation of Effects of Monetary Policy on Iranian Economy In a Monetary Business Cycle Framework. Journal of Monetary And Banking Researches, 6(4),-32. [9] Davoudi, P., Zarepour, Z.(2007). The Role of Definition of Money in the Stability of the Iranian Demand for Money. Iranian economic research, 29, 47-74. [0] Sidrauski, M. (967). Rational choice and patterns of growth in a monetary economy. The American Economic Review, 57(2), 534-544. [] Kavand, H. and Shahmoradi, A.(2009). The Effect of Oil Price Changes on the Technological Fluctuations in an Oil Exporting Country: A DSGE. ISF 2009 conference, Hong Kong, June 2-24. [2] Khaliliaraghi, M., Shakouri ganjavi, H., & Zanganeh, M. (2009). Optimal Monetary Policy for the Iranian Economy: An Application of Optimal Control Theory. Journal of Economic Research (Tahghighat-E-Eghtesadi) (JTE), Volume 44, Issue 3, Winter 200. [3] Shahmordi, A. and Ebrahimi, F.(200). The Impacts of Monetary Policies in Iran: A DSGE Approach. Journal of Monetary And Banking Researches, 2(3), 3-56. [4] Amini, A., Neshat, H. (2005). Estimating the Time series of Capital stock In the economy of Iran During the period of 338-38.(in Persian) The Journal of Planning and Budgeting, 0(), 53-86.