On Renegotiation-Proof Collusion under Imperfect Public Information*

Similar documents
Microeconomics for Business Practice Session 3 - Solutions

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program May 2012

MS&E 246: Lecture 12 Static games of incomplete information. Ramesh Johari

REPEATED GAMES. Jörgen Weibull. April 13, 2010

On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E.

Game Theory. Monika Köppl-Turyna. Winter 2017/2018. Institute for Analytical Economics Vienna University of Economics and Business

Economics 3012 Strategic Behavior Andy McLennan October 20, 2006

SELECTION OF MARKOV EQUILIBRIUM IN A DYNAMIC OLIGOPOLY WITH PRODUCTION TO ORDER. Milan Horniaček 1

Solving Extensive Form Games

FORWARD INDUCTION AND SUNK COSTS GIVE AVERAGE COST PRICING. Jean-Pierre Ponssard. Abstract

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on Repeated Games

Lecture 1. Evolution of Market Concentration

Advanced Microeconomics

Limit pricing models and PBE 1

3.3.3 Illustration: Infinitely repeated Cournot duopoly.

Basics of Game Theory

Solution to Tutorial 9

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

Bayesian Games and Mechanism Design Definition of Bayes Equilibrium

Game Theory. Professor Peter Cramton Economics 300

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium

Theory Field Examination Game Theory (209A) Jan Question 1 (duopoly games with imperfect information)

Solution to Tutorial 9

Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 2: Strategic-Form Games and Nash Equilibrium (2)

SURPLUS SHARING WITH A TWO-STAGE MECHANISM. By Todd R. Kaplan and David Wettstein 1. Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel. 1.

On Hotelling s Stability in Competition

Repeated Games with Perfect Monitoring

Informed Principal in Private-Value Environments

A New and Robust Subgame Perfect Equilibrium in a model of Triadic Power Relations *

SF2972 Game Theory Exam with Solutions March 15, 2013

Backwards Induction. Extensive-Form Representation. Backwards Induction (cont ) The player 2 s optimization problem in the second stage

Game Theory Correlated equilibrium 1

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009

Industrial Organization Lecture 3: Game Theory

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Government 2005: Formal Political Theory I

Contracts under Asymmetric Information

Advanced Microeconomics

Symmetric Separating Equilibria in English Auctions 1

Quantum Bertrand duopoly of incomplete information

Negotiation: Strategic Approach

Introduction to Game Theory

Interdependent Value Auctions with an Insider Bidder 1

A Foundation for Markov Equilibria in Infinite Horizon Perfect Information Games

Product differences and prices

Theory of Auctions. Carlos Hurtado. Jun 23th, Department of Economics University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign

Cournot Competition Under Asymmetric Information

Economics 703 Advanced Microeconomics. Professor Peter Cramton Fall 2017

Ex Post Cheap Talk : Value of Information and Value of Signals

NASH IMPLEMENTATION USING SIMPLE MECHANISMS WITHOUT UNDESIRABLE MIXED-STRATEGY EQUILIBRIA

Endogenous Monitoring

4. CONTINUOUS VARIABLES AND ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS

Political Economy of Institutions and Development: Problem Set 1. Due Date: Thursday, February 23, in class.

EC319 Economic Theory and Its Applications, Part II: Lecture 7

Market Power. Economics II: Microeconomics. December Aslanyan (VŠE) Oligopoly 12/09 1 / 39

Revealed Preference Tests of the Cournot Model

Lecture Note II-3 Static Games of Incomplete Information. Games of incomplete information. Cournot Competition under Asymmetric Information (cont )

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples

Strongly Consistent Self-Confirming Equilibrium

Introduction. 1 University of Pennsylvania, Wharton Finance Department, Steinberg Hall-Dietrich Hall, 3620

1 The General Definition

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

Dynamic stochastic game and macroeconomic equilibrium

Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!?

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016

Payoff Continuity in Incomplete Information Games

Equilibrium Refinements

RECIPROCAL RELATIONSHIPS AND MECHANISM DESIGN

Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium. Definition. The single-crossing property. This is a draft; me with comments, typos, clarifications, etc.

Lecture Notes on Game Theory

Patience and Ultimatum in Bargaining

The Revenue Equivalence Theorem 1

Area I: Contract Theory Question (Econ 206)

A Stackelberg Game Model of Dynamic Duopolistic Competition with Sticky Prices. Abstract

DEMB Working Paper Series N. 39. Limit pricing and secret barriers to entry. Luigi Brighi * Marcello D Amato ** December 2014

Crowdsourcing contests

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Repeated Downsian Electoral Competition

Global Dynamics in Repeated Games with Additively Separable Payoffs

EVOLUTIONARY STABILITY FOR TWO-STAGE HAWK-DOVE GAMES

BELIEFS & EVOLUTIONARY GAME THEORY

Economics Discussion Paper Series EDP A new look at the classical Bertrand duopoly

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly

Mechanism Design: Implementation. Game Theory Course: Jackson, Leyton-Brown & Shoham

6.207/14.15: Networks Lecture 16: Cooperation and Trust in Networks

Internalization. a Game-Theoretic Approach. Rolf Ziegler Institute of Sociology University of Munich

Industrial Organization, Fall 2011: Midterm Exam Solutions and Comments Date: Wednesday October

EconS Advanced Microeconomics II Handout on The Intuitive Criterion

Non-Existence of Equilibrium in Vickrey, Second-Price, and English Auctions

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing

Econ 618: Correlated Equilibrium

Msc Micro I exam. Lecturer: Todd Kaplan.

Online Appendices for Large Matching Markets: Risk, Unraveling, and Conflation

Empirical Industrial Organization (ECO 310) University of Toronto. Department of Economics Fall Instructor: Victor Aguirregabiria

Static Models of Oligopoly

Title: The Castle on the Hill. Author: David K. Levine. Department of Economics UCLA. Los Angeles, CA phone/fax

First Prev Next Last Go Back Full Screen Close Quit. Game Theory. Giorgio Fagiolo

Game Theory. Strategic Form Games with Incomplete Information. Levent Koçkesen. Koç University. Levent Koçkesen (Koç University) Bayesian Games 1 / 15

Transcription:

Journal of Economic Theory 85, 38336 (999) Article ID jeth.998.500, available online at http:www.idealibrary.com on NOTES, COMMENTS, AND LETTERS TO THE EDITOR On Renegotiation-Proof Collusion under Imperfect Public Information* Kiho Yoon KISDI (Korea Information Society Development Institute), - Juam-dong, Kwachun, Kyunggi-do, Republic of Korea, 47-070 kihosunnet.kisdi.re.kr Received May, 998; revised November 7, 998 We construct a weakly renegotiation-proof equilibrium in Green and Porter's (984, Econometrica 5, 8700) imperfect public information model, which Paretodominates the Cournot-Nash equilibrium. Journal of Economic Literature Classification Numbers: C7, D43, D8. 999 Academic Press Key Words: renegotiation-proof equilibrium; collusion; CournotNash equilibrium.. INTRODUCTION In a recent paper, Chen [] shows an example of a weakly renegotiation-proof equilibrium (WRPE) in Green-Porter [4]'s imperfect public information model, where firms are engaged in a Cournot competition and the observable market price is determined by the unobservable aggregate output chosen by the firms and a random variable. That example was to falsify van Damme []'s conjecture that the only WRPE in that model is the repetition of the Cournot-Nash equilibrium (CNE). In doing so, he first proves a proposition [, Proposition ] which, among other things, implies that firms cannot sustain a collusion in any stage of a WRPE. That is, in no stage of a WRPE, can firms simultaneously entertain higher profits than the CNE profits. He also concludes, after constructing an asymmetric equilibrium, that the only symmetric WRPE is the repetition of the CNE. * This paper is based on Chapter 3 of my dissertation submitted to the University of Minnesota, Minneapolis. I thank my advisor, Professor Andrew McLennan, and an anonymous referee for their helpful comments. 00-05399 30.00 Copyright 999 by Academic Press All rights of reproduction in any form reserved. 38

RENEGOTIATION-PROOF COLLUSION 39 In this note, contrary to his proposition and conclusion, we construct a symmetric WRPE such that firms can sustain a collusion in some stages of the equilibrium. Moreover, this equilibrium is shown to Pareto-dominate the CNE, thus partially answering the open question of how high total profits can be in a WRPE. The best way to understand how we are able to construct the asserted equilibrium is to look at Chen's Proposition. Chen's proof relies on the fact that players' continuation payoffs depend only on the previous period's price realization. But players' actions, and thus continuation payoffs, can depend on other things, e.g., different phases. Chen himself does use two phases when he shows an example of WRPE, and the continuation payoffs are different across phases with the same price realization p. In constructing the equilibrium, we introduce a simple bi-valued public randomizing device which is used when determining who should be punished in case of an unfavorable public outcome, i.e., low price. Maintaining a collusion implies that there is at least one stage of the equilibrium where firms' payoff vector Pareto-dominates the CNE payoff vector. Consequently, there are periods in which firms' outputs are less than the CNE outputs. In those periods, each firm has an incentive to increase its output. To support the collusion, there must be a punishment scheme when the price is low enough. Since we are interested in finding a renegotiation-proof equilibrium, this punishment should not give every player a lower continuation payoff. That means one firm has to entertain a higher continuation payoff after a low price. By making the punishment random and the expected value of the continuation payoffs from the punishment lower than that from collusion, we can deter deviations.. THE MODEL The model presented here is the same as that in Chen []. There are two firms (firm and firm ) producing a homogeneous good with zero cost, and they are engaged in a Cournot competition. When the output produced by firm i is q i, the price realized in the market is P =P(Q)+'~, where Q=q +q and '~ is a random variable with density g. We assume g is differentiable, single-peaked at, and symmetric around 0. Let G be the cumulative distribution function. Each firm observes the price realized in the market and its own output, but not the quantity of output produced by the other firm. We can approximate this device by using the price realization of the past period judiciously. See Section 3 for a discussion of the randomizing device. Please refer to Section 3 for a detailed discussion.

330 KIHO YOON.. Stage Game Both firms simultaneously choose their respective outputs q and q (q i # R + ). The payoff (profit) for firm i is?~ i (q i, P )=q i P, and the expected payoff is? i (q i ; q j )=q i P(Q). The stage game is denoted by =(R + ;?,? ; G)... Repeated Game ($) ($) is the infinite repetition of the stage game with the common discount factor $ # (0, ). Period t runs from to. Fort, a public history h t is ( p(), p(),..., p(t&)), that is, past price realizations up to, but not including, t. A private history for firm i, denoted h t, is i (q(), q(),..., q(t&)). Let H t and H t i be the sets of all public and private histories in period t respectively. A strategy for firm i is _ i =(_ t i ) where t= _ i # R + and _ t:(ht i, H t) R i + for t=, 3,... A strategy pair _=(_, _ ) will be called a strategy profile. Given a strategy profile _, we can determine the probability distribution over all the possible histories in each period, and consequently the probability distribution over stage-game payoffs. Firm i's objective in ($) is to maximize the expected value of the discounted average payoff (&$) : t= $ t&? t i, where? t i is the period t stage-game payoff. We will deal only with public strategy profiles, that is, the strategy profiles that depend only on public histories. In this case, each firm's belief regarding exactly at which node it is, given a public history, does not matter to the subsequent play. Besides, we can unambiguously refer to the continuation payoffs, since firms have identical probability distributions over stage-game payoffs after any public history. We will use the perfect Bayesian equilibrium (PBE) concept in this note. Especially, we use the weakest notion of PBE: each player's strategy after any history (i.e., at any information set) maximizes his expected payoff given others' strategies and his belief about nodes, and beliefs after any history to which the strategy profile assigns positive probability are

RENEGOTIATION-PROOF COLLUSION 33 obtained using Bayes' rule. A PBE is called a WRPE if none of its continuation payoff vector is strictly Pareto-dominated by another. 3 3. AN EXAMPLE Let P(Q)=a&bQ if Q(ab), and 0 otherwise. Then the best response function of player i is q i =R(q j )= a&bq j b i, j=,, i{ j. Note that, given the other players' output q j, player i's expected stage game payoff as a function of his own output,? i (q i ; q j ), is single-peaked. We find a WRPE which Pareto-dominates the Cournot-Nash equilibrium. Let a=6, b=, that is, P(Q)=6&Q as in Chen []. Then the CNE is (q, q )=(, ) and (?,? )=(4, 4). The strategy profile _ below is a WRPE. In the profile, we use parameters }, {, p,andp whose values will be determined shortly. Phase : Play (q, q )=(&}, &}). The expected price is E( p)= +} and the expected payoff (?,? )is(4+}&},4+}&} ). Keep playing it until p goes below p.ifp<p, then go to phase - with probability, and to phase - with probability. 4 Phase -: Play (q, q )=(+{, 3). Then E( p)=&{ and (?,? ) is (+{&{,6&3{). If p>p, then go to phase -; otherwise go to phase. Phase -: Play (q, q )=(3, +{). Then E( p)=&{ and (?,? ) is (6&3{, +{&{ ). If p>p, then go to phase -; otherwise go to phase. We assume that 0<}< and 0<{<. Let V h i be firm i's continuation payoff at phase h (i=,, h=,, ). Before proving the claim, let us explain the intuition. In phase, firm has a short-term incentive to increase its output. But doing so will increase the probability of going out of phase and entering into phase - or phase - with equal probability. Since V > (V +V ) (Eq. () below) by construction, firm 's short-term incentive is checked by a long-term consideration. Phase - is a phase in which firm is being punished. In 3 See Farrel and Maskin [3] for this concept. 4 See below how this can be done.

33 KIHO YOON this phase, firm has a short-term incentive to increase its output. But doing so will decrease the probability of entering phase - instead of phase. Since V >V (Eq. () below) by construction, this short-term incentive is checked. In phase -, firm has a short-term incentive to decrease its output. Since doing so will increase the probability of entering phase - instead of phase and V >V by Eq. (3) below, this incentive is checked. A symmetric argument applies for firm. Let us briefly discuss the randomizing device. When price p is below the threshold level p in phase, a randomizing device determines which phase among phase - or - to enter. The probability of entering either phase is. We assume it is independent across periods. It would not be difficult to find such a device in the real world. Alternatively, we can partition the interval [0, p ]intonequal-sized subintervals, with enumerating them from to N. Taking N to be sufficiently large and arranging to punish player if the price falls in the odd-numbered intervals and player if it falls in the even-numbered intervals, we can make the punishment approximately random. Observe that the implementation of the randomizing device should not be under firms' control in each period. Otherwise, firms would like to back off from implementing it and thus entering phase - or phase - when they have to, which upsets the proposed _. We can think of many schemes which do not give the firms the right to decide whether to implement the randomizing devicesunspots, simultaneous determination of a coin toss and the price realization, etc. The interval-partitioning scheme described above also supports the weak renegotiation-proofness of the equilibrium. 3.. Renegotiation-proofness Note that Similarly, Then we have: [] Phase. Prob(P p E( p)=+})=g( p &&}). Prob(P p E( p)=&{)=g( p &+{). V =(&$)(4+}&} )+$[(&G( p &&})) V + G( p &&})(V +V )] V =(&$)(4+}&} )+$[(&G( p &&})) V + G( p &&})(V +V )]

RENEGOTIATION-PROOF COLLUSION 333 [] Phase -. V =(&$)(+{&{ )+$[G( p &+{) V +(&G( p &+{)) V ] V =(&$)(6&3{)+$[G( p &+{) V +(&G( p &+{)) V ] [3] Phase -. V =(&$)(6&3{)+$[G( p &+{) V +(&G( p &+{)) V ] V =(&$)(+{&{ )+$[G( p &+{) V +(&G( p &+{)) V ] It is clear that V =V, V =V, and V =V. From now on, we only deal with firm 's continuation payoffs explicitly. Let :=G( p &&}) and ;=G( p &+{). Since the value functions V, V,andV form a system of linear equations, we can solve them to get V & +{+{ ) (V +V )=(&$)(4}&4} (&$+:$+;$) V &V = (&$) (+$&;$)(&$+:$+;$) V &V = (&$) (+$&;$)(&$+:$+;$) () () (3) where =4(&}+} )&6{+$(&;)[{(&{)&4(+}&} )] +$:(&{) (4) =4(+}&} )&{(&{)+$(&;)[6{&4(&}+} )] +$:(&{) (5) &(V +V )>0. We Since 0<}< and 0<{< by assumption, V will choose : and ; such that 0<:< and <;<. In that case, is positive for all 0<$< and (}, {)'s satisfying &6}+6} >5{+{.We will choose } and { such that &6}+6} >5{+{ (-) in the following. Therefore, V &V >0. Since & =(+$&;$) (4}&4} +{+{ )>0, we have V &V >V &V. In particular, V & V >0.

334 KIHO YOON In summary, we have V >V >V and V >V >V. Since no pair of continuation payoff vectors are Pareto ranked, the proposed strategy profile _ is a WRPE if we can show that no firm has an incentive to deviate from the proposed strategy profile _. 3.. No Incentive to Deviate We will show that there is no profitable one-shot deviation at any phase. Then, by the unimprovability principle, _ is a PBE. Let V h (q i i) be the continuation payoff of firm i when it produces q i in this period at phase h and then follows the proposed strategy thereafter, assuming that the other firm is following the proposed strategy. [] Phase. V (q )=(&$) q (4+}&q )+$[(&G( p &4&}+q )) V + G( p &4&}+q )(V +V )] V $ (q )=(&$)(4+}&q )+$g( p &4&}+q )[ (V +V )&V ] V " (q )=&(&$)+$g$( p &4&}+q )[ (V +V )&V ] If we show V $ " (&})=0 and V <0 for all q # R +, then firm has no incentive to deviate at phase and then conform afterwards. Since V $ (&})=3}(&$)+$g( p &&})[ (V +V )&V ]>0 as p or p &, we need 3}(&$)+$g(0)[ (V +V )&V ]<0 to have a p which solves V $ (&})=0. That is, by Eq. () above, g(0)> 6}(&$+:$+;$) $(4}&4} +{+{ ). (C) Also we need g$(') < 4(&$+:$+;$), \' #(&, ). (C) $(4}&4} +{+{ ) A similar argument for firm will lead to the same conditions (C) and (C).

RENEGOTIATION-PROOF COLLUSION 335 [] Phase -. V (q )=(&$) q (3&q )+$[G( p &3+q ) V +(&G( p &3+q )) V ] V $ (q )=(&$)(3&q )+$g( p &3+q )[V &V ] V " (q )=&(&$)+$g$( p &3+q )[V &V ] Since 0<{< by assumption, V $ (+{)=(&$)(&{)+$g( p &+{)[V &V ]>0 as p or p &. Thus we need, by Eqs. () and (4), Also we need g(0)> (&{)(+$&;$)(&$+:$+;$) $. (C3) g$(') < 4(+$&;$)(&$+:$+;$) $, \' #(&, ). (C4) [3] Phase -. Since V (q )=(&$) q (5&{&q )+$[G( p &5+{+q ) V +(&G( p &5+{+q )) V ] V $ (q )=(&$)(5&{&q )+$g( p &5+{+q )[V &V ] V " (q )=&(&$)+$g$( p &5+{+q )[V &V ] V $ (3)=&(&$)(+{)+$g( p &+{)[V &V ]<0 as p or p &, we need, by Eqs. (3) and (5), Also we need g(0)> (+{)(+$&;$)(&$+:$+;$) $. (C5) g$(') < 4(+$&;$)(&$+:$+;$) $, \' #(&, ). (C6)

336 KIHO YOON A similar argument for firm will lead to the same conditions (C3)t(C6). For firm, conditions (C5) and (C6) will apply to phase -, and conditions (C3) and (C4) will apply to phase -. In the following, we will denote the right-hand side of condition (Ci) (i=,..., 6) by c i. It is easy to see that (C6) implies (C) and (C4). Summing up, our problem is to find p, p, }, and { such that equations 5 and 6}(&$+:$+;$)=$g( p &&})(4}&4} +{+{ ), (&{)(+$&;$)(&$+:$+;$)=$g( p &+{), (+{)(+$&;$)(&$+:$+;$)=$g( p &+{) hold, and both (-) and (C6) are satisfied. (If we find such p, p, }, and {, then conditions (C), (C3), and (C5) will be automatically satisfied.) For a concrete example, consider a logistic distribution with density g(')= 0 3 exp(&(03) ') (+exp(&(03) ')) and $=0.99. Note that G(')=(+exp(& 0 3 '))&. A solution for the given specification is ( p, p, }, {)=(.99759,.9880, 0., 0.05). The maximum of g$(') is achieved at '= 3 0ln(\- 3), which is.0697, and c 6 is.55. Thus, (C6) is satisfied. It is also easy to see that (-) is satisfied. We have V =4.0446, V =4.0807, and V =4.053, implying that the proposed equilibrium _ Pareto-dominates the Cournot Nash equilibrium. REFERENCES. K. Chen, On renegotiation-proof equilibrium under imperfect monitoring, J. Econ. Theory 65 (995), 60060.. E. van Damme, Renegotiation-proof equilibrium in repeated prisoner's dilemma, J. Econ. Theory 47 (989), 067. 3. J. Farrel and E. Maskin, Renegotiation in repeated games, Games and Econ. Behavior (989), 37360. 4. E. Green and R. Porter, Noncooperative collusion under imperfect price information, Econometrica 5 (984), 8700. 5. K. Yoon, ``Essays on Repeated Games and Double Auctions,'' Ph.D. thesis, University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, June 997. 5 Recall that :=G( p &.) and ;=G( p &+{).