Scientiae Mathematicae Japonicae Online, Vol. 5, (2001), POSSIBILITY THAT THE CUSTOMERS GIVE UP PURCHASING THE MERCHANDISE

Similar documents
Basics of Game Theory

Oligopoly. Molly W. Dahl Georgetown University Econ 101 Spring 2009

The Replenishment Policy for an Inventory System with a Fixed Ordering Cost and a Proportional Penalty Cost under Poisson Arrival Demands

A Multi-Item Inventory Control Model for Perishable Items with Two Shelves

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing

Advanced Microeconomics

On the Non-Symmetric Nash and Kalai Smorodinsky Bargaining Solutions. Yigal Gerchak

Profitability of price and quantity strategies in a duopoly with vertical product differentiation

On Hotelling s Stability in Competition

Game Theory. Professor Peter Cramton Economics 300

An Uncertain Bilevel Newsboy Model with a Budget Constraint

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 W2005

Discrete Event and Process Oriented Simulation (2)

On revealed preferences in oligopoly games

Industrial Organization Lecture 7: Product Differentiation

Dual Interpretations and Duality Applications (continued)

Sion s minimax theorem and Nash equilibrium of symmetric multi-person zero-sum game

On the relation between Sion s minimax theorem and existence of Nash equilibrium in asymmetric multi-players zero-sum game with only one alien

Oligopoly Theory 2 Bertrand Market Games

Product differences and prices

Dynamic stochastic game and macroeconomic equilibrium

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 7: Supermodular Games

On Renegotiation-Proof Collusion under Imperfect Public Information*

EC3224 Autumn Lecture #03 Applications of Nash Equilibrium

A technical appendix for multihoming and compatibility

ANSWER KEY 2 GAME THEORY, ECON 395

Price and Capacity Competition

Some forgotten equilibria of the Bertrand duopoly!?

Oligopoly Notes. Simona Montagnana

Chapter 7 Duopoly. O. Afonso, P. B. Vasconcelos. Computational Economics: a concise introduction

On strategic complementarity conditions in Bertrand oligopoly

Maximin and minimax strategies in symmetric oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand

Competitive Equilibrium

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

Asymptotic relations in Cournot s game

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

ISM206 Lecture, May 12, 2005 Markov Chain

STRATEGIC TRADE POLICY AND MANAGERIAL DELEGATION IN A MIXED DUOPOLY FANG WEI (UNIVERSITY OF KITAKYUSHU)

Economic lot-sizing games

Game Theory and Algorithms Lecture 2: Nash Equilibria and Examples

Dynamic Pricing in the Presence of Competition with Reference Price Effect

On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E.

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship

Designing Optimal Pre-Announced Markdowns in the Presence of Rational Customers with Multi-unit Demands - Online Appendix

Oligopoly Theory. This might be revision in parts, but (if so) it is good stu to be reminded of...

Coordination mechanisms for inventory control in three-echelon serial and distribution systems

Mixed duopolies with advance production

Online Appendix Liking and Following and the Newsvendor: Operations and Marketing Policies under Social Influence

Answer Key: Problem Set 3

s<1/4 p i = 2 3 s s [1/4, 9/16[ p i = p j + 2 s p j 1 if p j < p j p i = 2 3 s if p j p j p i = p j if p j < p j s 9/16

Discussion Papers in Economics

Optimal Control of an Inventory System with Joint Production and Pricing Decisions

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry!

Computation of Efficient Nash Equilibria for experimental economic games

Static Models of Oligopoly

Spatial Competition and Collaboration Networks

Managerial delegation in multimarket oligopoly

Stackelberg-solvable games and pre-play communication

A SECOND ELEMENTARY PROPOSITION CONCERNING THE FORMATION OF CUSTOMS UNIONS

Nonlinear dynamics in a duopoly with price competition and vertical differentiation

7.1 INTRODUCTION. In this era of extreme competition, each subsystem in different

Multimarket Oligopolies with Restricted Market Access

Introduction to Game Theory Lecture Note 2: Strategic-Form Games and Nash Equilibrium (2)

Stochastic Equilibrium Problems arising in the energy industry

Bounded Rationality Lecture 2. Full (Substantive, Economic) Rationality

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

Static (or Simultaneous- Move) Games of Complete Information

Ex Post Cheap Talk : Value of Information and Value of Signals

EconS Sequential Competition

THEORY OF OLIGOPOLIES: DYNAMICS AND STABILITY OF EQUILIBRIA

Cloud Service under the Presence of Privacy Concern

Backwards Induction. Extensive-Form Representation. Backwards Induction (cont ) The player 2 s optimization problem in the second stage

Two single-product firms with different quality levels and fixed limited capacities engage in sequential price

Microeconomics Qualifying Exam

Competition between Virtual Operators in a Two-sided Telecommunication Market

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES PRICE AND CAPACITY COMPETITION. Daron Acemoglu Kostas Bimpikis Asuman Ozdaglar

Collaborative Network Formation in Spatial Oligopolies

Mathematical Economics - PhD in Economics

A Stackelberg Game Model of Dynamic Duopolistic Competition with Sticky Prices. Abstract

Mathematical Games and Random Walks

Vertical Product Differentiation and Credence Goods: Mandatory Labeling and Gains from International Integration

Solving a Class of Generalized Nash Equilibrium Problems

Modeling of Chaotic Behavior in the Economic Model

Supermodular Games. Ichiro Obara. February 6, 2012 UCLA. Obara (UCLA) Supermodular Games February 6, / 21

Hotelling's Location Model with Quality Choice in Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

An Evolutionary Game Perspective to ALOHA with power control

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing

1 Basic Game Modelling

Bertrand-Edgeworth Equilibrium in Oligopoly

Pricing in a Duopoly with a Lead Time Advantage

A NOTE ON THE ARTICU "SOMF: EXPERIMENTAL n-person GAMES" ' R. Duncan Luce

Introduction to Game Theory

DRAFT Formulation and Analysis of Linear Programs

Technical Companion to: Sharing Aggregate Inventory Information with Customers: Strategic Cross-selling and Shortage Reduction

Stochastic Analysis of Bidding in Sequential Auctions and Related Problems.

Online Appendix to A search model of costly product returns by Vaiva Petrikaitė

Problem Set Suggested Answers

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

ON HOTELLING S COMPETITION WITH GENERAL PURPOSE PRODUCTS 1

Transcription:

Scientiae Mathematicae Japonicae Online, Vol. 5, (00), 7 79 7 A DUOPOLISTIC INVENTORY PROBLEM INCLUDING THE POSSIBILITY THAT THE CUSTOMERS GIVE UP PURCHASING THE MERCHANDISE HITOSHI HOHJO and YOSHINOBU TERAOKA Received June, 00 revised July, 00 Abstract. This paper considers a competing inventory model with partial re-allocation over the unit interval. The model is described as follows There are two retailers which handle the same kind of products. They open their stores at the both ends of the street with unit distance. Customers are uniformly distributed over the street. Though they are willing to purchase one of products at first, they may give up purchasing it on their way. Under this situation, each retailer is planning to minimize the sum of costs related with holding inventory, shortages and profits. The purpose of each retailer is to decide his order quantity. This model constructs a variation of the unit square games with pure strategies of continuous cardinary. We examine the optimal strategies for two players from the view point of non-zero sum game theory. We are interested in equilibrium analysis giving the optimal strategies. Introduction We consider a duopolistic inventory problem including the possibility that the customers give up purchasing the merchandise. When many retailers are involved in a decision situation, each retailer needs to decide his strategy while giving careful consideration to the opposite strategy. We use the equilibrium concepts instead of the classical optimization concepts to analyze our inventory model. Parlar [9] is the first paper which deals with an inventory problem using game theory. He proved the existence and uniqueness of the Nash solution for an inventory problem with two substitutable products having random demands. Hohjo [4] newly proposed a competitive inventory problem, which introduces the conception on time and distance, for two retailers selling the same kind of products, and then found the optimal strategies under equilibruim for such a competitive inventory problem. However, he was assumed that all customers are eager to purchase products even if the first visiting retailer stocks out. In fact, it is conceivable that some customers may give up purchasing the products with knowledge of stocking out. This paper suggests a concrete duopolistic model with partial re-allocation. We are interested in equilibrium analysis giving the optimal strategies. For researches on equilibrium, the author refers to Bryant [], Kirman and Sobel [5], Levitan [6], Lippman and McCardle [7], and Topkis [0]. For works related to game theory, see Dresher [], Nash [8] and Simaan and Cruz []. The papar is planed as follows. In Section, we introduce a duopolistic inventory model with partial re-allocation over the unit interval. Section calculates the objective functions for two retailers. Section 4 is devote to investigate an equilibrium point. We analyze our model in a way to result in a bimatrix game and find an equilibrium point for two retailers. Finally, the paper is concluded with some remarks. We hope that a work in this paper will give one of criteria to decide the optimal order quantities in the competing cases. 000 Mathematics Subject Classification. 90B05. Key words and phrases. Inventory, Competition, Equilibrium point, Duopolistic, Bimatrix game.

74 HITOSHI HOHJO and YOSHINOBU TERAOKA Model and Notation Consider a single period duopolistic inventory model with partial re-allocation. The model is described as follows There are two retailers, Player and, who open their stores at the both end points 0 and on the unit interval [0 ], respectively. They simultaneously begin to sell some product to customers and share all customers. Their initial inventory levels are zero. Their orders for products are placed once at the beginning of period, and the products are delivered without lead time. When they order the products, the set-up costs are not charged but the ordering costs are charged in proportion to their order quantities. If they have some stock to sell, then they are charged the holding costs. On the other hand, if the all products have been already stocked out when the demand has occurred, then they will bear penalty costs for shortage. Holding costs, penalty costs and profits are incurred in proportion to their inventory quantities, shortage quantities and demand, respectively. In this model we can assume that the ordering costs are equal to 0. Players have a penalty in the sense that they will lose their confidence to customers if they have nothing to sell in inventory. Although excess demand for a player is not backlogged by himself, it is re-allocated to another player. Assume that two players mutually know values of the opposite unit holding cost, penalty cost and profit. Customers are uniformly distributed over the range [0 ]. Each customer goes to a shop located closer to him so as to purchase one unit product. As soon as he gets information such that in the first visiting shop the stock out occurs, he travels to another shop with a certain probability in order to satisfy his demand. The customers start from their positions at the same time and travel with the same speed. Then the arrival time taken from their positions to the shop is proportional to the travel distance. The customers do not know inventory quantities in the shops at any time. We treat a non-cooperative model for two players. The purpose of each player is to decide his order quantity which minimizes his total expected cost, taking account of the inventory holding, shortages and profit. As the first step in our analysis, we will calculate the total expected costs and find the optimal order quantities which attain their purposes. We describe the notation and assumptions used in this paper z i order quantity chosen by Player i, z i 0 q probability withwhich customers give up purchasing a product, 0 <q» r i profit/unit for Player i, r i 0 h i holding cost/unit for Player i, h i 0 p i penalty cost/unit for Player i, p i 0 t traveling time per unit distance. Suppose that all values except for z i are given. The planning period is t if they wait for the last possible customer until the time when he may come. We assume that the number of customers in a market is equal to without loss of generality. In order to avoid an excessive inventory, henever place an order for products more than demand. Consequently, his strategy z i can be restricted to the interval [0 ] if he has a positive holding cost h i. ObjectiveFunction There are six situations by taking account of the order quantity z i and our model assumptions. We may consider just four situations because of symmetry on behavior of players. In order to explain these situations, we suppose that C i(z j z ) denotes the total expected cost for Player i(i = ), and the number j(j = 6), corresponding to each situation described below. We give the inventory quantity Q i (T ) for Player i at time T and calculate the total expected cost C i(z j z ) as follows. (i) Let» z i» i =. Then both players can supply products to all customers without stocking out by time t. No demand occurs after that time.

A DUOPOLISTIC INVENTORY PROBLEM 75 For Player i the on-hand inventory Q i (T ) is written as () ρ zi Q i (T )= T 0» T< t t z i t» T» t Then the total expected cost C i (z z ) for Player i in this situation is given by () C i (z z ) = h i I (z z )+p i I (z z ) r i» 5 = h i z i h i + r i where I (z z ) and I (z z ) denote the average inventory quantity and the average shortage quantity, respectively. We see that the total expected cost C i (z z ) is an increasing linear function of z i. Therefore he chooses z Λ = as his optimal strategy. i (ii) Let 0» z < and let +q z» z». Then Player stocks out by time t and Player satisfies the demands not only for the first visiting customers but also for the re-allocated customers by Player. Hence they can supply all customers with products. For Player, the on-hand inventory Q (T ) is given by Eq.(). Then the total expected cost C(z z ) is given by () C (z z ) = h I (z z )+p I (z z ) r z = [p + r ]z + h + p z + 5 p The total expected cost C (z z )isobviously a convex function of z. This fact leads to the following strategies (4) ffl If 0» r < h p, the optimal strategy for Player is z Λ = (r +p) (h+p). ffl If r h p, the optimal strategy for Playerisz Λ =. For Player, the on-hand inventory Q (T ) is written as 8 < z T 0» T< t t Q (T )= z t» T<( + z )t z + q z + T t ( + z )t» T» t Then the total expected cost C (z z )isgiven by (5) C (z z ) = h I (z z )+p I (z z ) r + q z ψ 5 = h z h + q z! r + q z Givenavalue of z, the total expected cost C(z z ) is an increasing linear function of z. Therefore he chooses z Λ = + q zλ as his optimal strategy if Player chooses his optimal strategy z Λ. (iii) Let 0» z < and let» z < + q z. Then Player stocks out by time t and Player satisfies the demands for the first visiting customers and a part of the demands for customers re-allocated from Player. Hence they can not supply all customers with products.

76 HITOSHI HOHJO and YOSHINOBU TERAOKA Player has the same strategies as those of Case (ii). For Player, the inventory quantity Q (T ) is given by Eq.(4). Givenafixedz, let t denote the time T satisfying z + q z + T t =0and(+ z )t» T < t simultaneously. The expected total cost C (z z )isgiven by (6) C (z z ) = h I (z z )+p I (z z ) r z = r z + h + p qt t + h q ( + z ) + p q t 4 t For the fixed z, the total expected cost C (z z ) is convex in z.we suppose that Player always chooses his optimal strategy z Λ. Then it tells us to the following strategies ffl If 0» r < (h +p) z Λ + h p, the optimal strategy for Playerisz Λ =. ffl If (h +p) z Λ + h p q(zλ + ).» r <h, the optimal strategy for Playerisz Λ = (r +p) (h+p) q + ffl If r h, the optimal strategy for Player is z Λ = + q zλ (iv) Let 0» z i < i =. Then both players stock out by time t. They satisfy a part of the demands for the first visiting customers. Hence no players do not supply their demands for re-allocated customers. For Player, the on-hand inventory Q (T ) is written as (7) 8 < z T 0» T< t t Q (T )= z t» T<( + z )t z + q z + T t ( + z )t» T» t Then the total expected cost C 4(z z ) is given by. (8) C 4 = h I (z z )+p I (z z ) ψr z = [p + r ]z + h + p z q + p z + 5! Hence the total expected cost C 4(z z )isaconvex function of z for fixed z. Therefore it leads to the following strategies ffl If 0» r < h p, the optimal strategy for Player is z Λ = (r+p) (h+p). ffl If r h p, the optimal strategy for Player is z Λ =. For Player we obtain the similar results to those of Player. It can be seen that the cases (v) and (vi) correspond to the situations in which are exchanged a role by Player and in the situations (ii) and (iii) respectively, although we omit to show it. 4 Equilibrium In the previous section, given the order quantity of a player, we can obtain the optimal order quantity z Λ with conditions related to r i i so as to minimize the total expected cost for opposite player. Those conditions on r i give some dominated pure strategies. We shall analyze our model in a way togive a reduced payoff bimatrix under these strategies and find an equilibrium point for both Player and.

A DUOPOLISTIC INVENTORY PROBLEM 77 Definition 4. Let X Y denote sets of strategies for Player and, respectively. A pair of strategies x Λ X, y Λ Y is an equilibrium point for a non-zero-sum minimizing game if for any strategies x X, y Y it holds the following equations M (x y Λ ) M (x Λ y Λ ) M (x Λ y) M (x Λ y Λ ) where M ( ) denotes Player 's loss and M ( ) denotes Player 's loss. We need to analyze it in the following eight parametric ranges (a) 0» r i < h i p i i= (b) 0» r < h p h p» r < (h + p ) r +p h+p + h p (c) 0» r < h p (h + p ) r +p + h p h+p (d) 0» r < h p r h (e) h p» r <h» r < (h + p ) r +p h+p + h p 0» r < h p (f) (h + p ) r +p + h p» r h+p <h 0» r < h p (g) r h 0» r < h p (h) r i h i p i i=. Now we shall examine an equilibrium point in the case of (a). Player has three pure strategies having dominated in some situations I = (r +p),i (h+p) = and I = + q (r +p). Also Player has three dominated pure strategies II (h+p) = (r +p), (h+p) II = and II = + q (r +p). It is seen that I (h+p) < I < I and II < II < II from conditions on r i. Then we make the following reduced payoff bimatrix by arranging these strategies for Player and. Then, the values of the total expected costs are given by I I I 0 II (C4(I II )C4(I II )) II (C(I II )C(I II )) II (C(I II )C(I II )) @ (C6(I II )C6(I II )) (C(I II )C(I II )) (C(I II )C(I II )) A (C5(I II )C5(I II )) (C(I II )C(I II )) (C(I II )C(I II )) The indexes denote the situation's number. For instance, if Player takes Strategy I and Player takes Strategy II, the total expected costs are calculated according to Situation 4. The optimality of the total expected cost C (z z )andthecontinuity of the total expected cost for Player lead to the following relationship (9) C (I II ) <C (I II )=C (I II ) From the optimality of the total expected cost C (z z ), we obtain (0) C (I k II ) <C (I k II ) k= Hence Strategy II is dominated by Strategy II. On the bimatrix reduced by domination, the similar argument gives that Strategy II is dominated by Strategy II. Furthermore the optimality of the total expected cost C 6 (z z ) and the continuity of the total expected cost for Player yield the relationship () C 6(I II ) <C 6(I II )=C 5(I II ) Also from the optimality of the total expected cost C 4(z z ) and the continuity, we obtain () C 4(I II ) <C 4(I II )=C 6(I II )

78 HITOSHI HOHJO and YOSHINOBU TERAOKA Hence Strategies I and I are dominated by Strategy I on the reduced matrix. Therefore the equilibrium point is (r +p) (r +p). (h+p) (h+p) By the similar argument we obtain the following theorem. Theorem 4. Let k i = (r i+p i ) (h i +p i i =. This model is interpreted as one of the unit ) square games with pure strategies of continuous cardinary. We then have eight results as an equilibrium point (z ΛzΛ ) on the conditions described above. (a) (k k ) (b) k (c) k q (k + k ) (d) k + q k (e) k (f) q (k + k ) k (g) + q k k (h). In the remaining of this section, we make a comparison between results obtained in the case of taking no thought of the opposite and our results. If both players never consider influence from the opposit, they should behave the optimal policies based on the first visiting customers. If they take nothought of the opposite, we obtain the following solutions, from the similar arguments to (i) and (ii),in above parametric ranges (k k ) for (a) (k ) for (b),(c) and (d) ( k ) for (e),(f) and (g) ( ) for (h). Hence we have characteristic solutions on the conditions (c),(d),(f) and (g), respectively. Consider the situation on the condition (c). To compare our results with ordering policies determined without taking thought of the opposite, we calculate difference of two total expected costs. () C(k ) C (k q(k + k )) ρ = r + p h ff + p ( + k + k ) q(k k ) 0 The last inequality is obtained from the condition r h p +(h + p ) r +p. The total h+p expected cost for the strategy is more expensive than that for the strategy in our results, q(k + k ). Therefore Player will save the costs by fr + p h +p ( + k + k )gq(k k ). For the condition (d) we have (4) C (k ) C (k + q( k )) ρ = r + p h + p ( 5 ff + k ) q k 0 where the last inequality follows because r < h p and r h. Therefore, using our results, Player will save the costs by fr + p h +p ( 5 + k )gq( k ). We have the similar arguments for (f) and (g). Hence we verified that our results are better solutions. 5 Concluding Remarks We have considered the duopolistic inventory model with reallocation over the unit interval, and have concretely examined the equilibrium point by resulting in one of bimatrix games. It has been confirmed from the result that there exists a unique equilibrium point. Then we have obtained the characteristic result in the duopolistic model. Also we found that the optimal order quantityisdependent on time at which a player stocks out. This time is given by a fixed value, whether customers give up purchasing a product with a certain probability or not. Hence the order quantity is decided by the optimal stocking out time.

A DUOPOLISTIC INVENTORY PROBLEM 79 The optimal strategies under equilibrium are summarized as follows If a player has some stock at time t, he places an order so that his inventory level at that time is equal to 0. If a player stocks out by time t, he places an order so that his inventory level at time (r i +p i ) (h i+p i) t is equal to 0. For instance, suppose that customers purchase a kind of foods. They choose whether parchasing at another store or substituting the other kind of foods, if they go to purchase foods at a store and the store stocks out. The former means that customers are re-allocated and the latter means that they give up purchasing the foods. Let q =05h =07p = 0h =06p =0r =0. Then, ordering almost 04% of total demands is the optimal strategy for P. On the other hand, the optimal strategy for P is approximately to order 04% if r =005 05% if r =08 05% if r =068 and 054% if r =0.When P is greedy for his profits, we suppose that he set r =0. Then, a pair of the optimal strategies for P and P is (04 054) if r =005 (05 05) if r =08 068, or 0. In a word, the strategy has to change in consideration of the opposite profit. There are several competitive inventory models, i.e. with many retailers, locations, and different ordering time and planning period for retailers. These models should be compared with our simple model, though they are still remained research problems. References [] J. Bryant, Competitive Equilibrium with Price Setting Firms and Stochastic Demand, International Economic Review,, 69-66 (980). [] M. Dresher, Games of Strategy, Theory and Applications, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey (954). [] D. P. Heymand and M. J. Sobel, Handbooks in OR and MS, Vol., Elsevier Science Publishers (990). [4] H. Hohjo, A Competitive Inventory Model with Reallocation under Uniform Demand Distribution, Mathematica Japonica, 49, 5-64 (999). [5] A. P. Kirman and M. J. Sobel, Dynamic Oligopoly with Inventories, Econometrica, 4, 79-87 (974). [6] R. Levitan, Price Variation Duopoly with Differentiated Products and Random Demand, Journal of Economic Theory,, -9 (97). [7] S. A. Lippman and K. F. McCardle, The Competitive Newsboy, Operations Research, 45, 54-65 (997). [8] J. Nash, Noncooperative Games, Annals of Mathematics, 54, 86-96 (95). [9] M. Parlar, Game Theoretic Analysis of the Substitutable Product Inventory Problem with Random Demand, Naval Research Logistics, 5, 97-409 (988). [0] D. M. Topkis, Equilibrium Points in Nonzero-Sum n-person Submodular Games, SLAM J. Control and Optimization, 7, 77-787 (979). [] M. Simaan and J. B. Cruz, A Stackelberg Solution for Games with Many Players, IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control, AC-8, -4 (977). DEPARTMENT OF MATHEMATICS AND INFORMATION SCIENCES, OSAKA PREFECTURE UNIVERSITY, - GAKUEN-CHO, SAKAI, OSAKA 599-85, JAPAN E-mailhojo@mi.cias.osakafu-u.ac.jp