ON THE EXISTENCE OF HOPF BIFURCATION IN AN OPEN ECONOMY MODEL

Similar documents
Dynamic IS-LM model with Philips Curve and International Trade

ASYMPTOTIC BEHAVIOUR AND HOPF BIFURCATION OF A THREE-DIMENSIONAL NONLINEAR AUTONOMOUS SYSTEM

Solutions to Dynamical Systems 2010 exam. Each question is worth 25 marks.

Nonlinear IS-LM Model with Tax Collection*

5.2.2 Planar Andronov-Hopf bifurcation

Dynamical Systems. Pierre N.V. Tu. An Introduction with Applications in Economics and Biology Second Revised and Enlarged Edition.

APPPHYS217 Tuesday 25 May 2010

BIFURCATION DIAGRAM OF A CUBIC THREE-PARAMETER AUTONOMOUS SYSTEM

Some notes on the structure of limit sets in IS-LM models

Masanori Yokoo. 1 Introduction

The Foley Liquidity / Profit-Rate Cycle Model Reconsidered

FLUCTUATIONS IN A MIXED IS-LM BUSINESS CYCLE MODEL

Linearized geometric dynamics of Tobin-Benhabib-Miyao economic flow

Lotka Volterra Predator-Prey Model with a Predating Scavenger

The Fractional-order SIR and SIRS Epidemic Models with Variable Population Size

(8.51) ẋ = A(λ)x + F(x, λ), where λ lr, the matrix A(λ) and function F(x, λ) are C k -functions with k 1,

= F ( x; µ) (1) where x is a 2-dimensional vector, µ is a parameter, and F :

TWELVE LIMIT CYCLES IN A CUBIC ORDER PLANAR SYSTEM WITH Z 2 -SYMMETRY. P. Yu 1,2 and M. Han 1

Relationships between phases of business cycles in two large open economies

Chapter 2 Hopf Bifurcation and Normal Form Computation

On the convergence of normal forms for analytic control systems

The Invariant Curve in a Planar System of Difference Equations

Production, Capital Stock and Price Dynamics in A Simple Model of Closed Economy *

UNIVERSITY of LIMERICK

2 The model with Kaldor-Pasinetti saving

There is a more global concept that is related to this circle of ideas that we discuss somewhat informally. Namely, a region R R n with a (smooth)

Andronov Hopf and Bautin bifurcation in a tritrophic food chain model with Holling functional response types IV and II

EE222 - Spring 16 - Lecture 2 Notes 1

Dynamical systems tutorial. Gregor Schöner, INI, RUB

Bifurcation and Stability Analysis of a Prey-predator System with a Reserved Area

STABILITY. Phase portraits and local stability

AN AK TIME TO BUILD GROWTH MODEL

investment M. R. Grasselli EPOG Seminar Paris Nord, November 18, 2016

2 Lecture 2: Amplitude equations and Hopf bifurcations

Introduction to Applied Nonlinear Dynamical Systems and Chaos

CHAOTIC BEHAVIOR IN A TWO-DIMENSIONAL BUSINESS CYCLE MODEL

Hamad Talibi Alaoui and Radouane Yafia. 1. Generalities and the Reduced System

Complicated behavior of dynamical systems. Mathematical methods and computer experiments.

EC744 Lecture Notes: Economic Dynamics. Prof. Jianjun Miao

Problem Set Number 5, j/2.036j MIT (Fall 2014)

BIFURCATION PHENOMENA Lecture 4: Bifurcations in n-dimensional ODEs

A Note on the Ramsey Growth Model with the von Bertalanffy Population Law

Automatic Control Systems theory overview (discrete time systems)

AN EFFICIENT METHOD FOR COMPUTING THE SIMPLEST NORMAL FORMS OF VECTOR FIELDS

8.385 MIT (Rosales) Hopf Bifurcations. 2 Contents Hopf bifurcation for second order scalar equations. 3. Reduction of general phase plane case to seco

QUARTERLY OF APPLIED MATHEMATICS

Hopf Bifurcation of a Nonlinear System Derived from Lorenz System Using Centre Manifold Approach ABSTRACT. 1. Introduction

CONTROLLING IN BETWEEN THE LORENZ AND THE CHEN SYSTEMS

Direction and Stability of Hopf Bifurcation in a Delayed Model with Heterogeneous Fundamentalists

Stability and Hopf Bifurcation for a Discrete Disease Spreading Model in Complex Networks

Dynamical System of a Multi-Capital Growth Model

Routes to Complexity in a Macroeconomic Model Described by a Noninvertible Triangular Map

Chapter 3. Second Order Linear PDEs

Example of a Blue Sky Catastrophe

IS-LM Analysis. Math 202. Brian D. Fitzpatrick. Duke University. February 14, 2018 MATH

ZERO-HOPF BIFURCATION FOR A CLASS OF LORENZ-TYPE SYSTEMS

Application demonstration. BifTools. Maple Package for Bifurcation Analysis in Dynamical Systems

PROJECTS on. Multiple Bifurcations of Sample Dynamical Systems

Adaptive Learning and Applications in Monetary Policy. Noah Williams

Additive resonances of a controlled van der Pol-Duffing oscillator

On Returns to Scale Assumption in Endogenous Growth

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Hopf Bifurcation and Limit Cycle Analysis of the Rikitake System

EE 380. Linear Control Systems. Lecture 10

Delay Kaldor-Kalecki Model Revisited. September 2014

NBA Lecture 1. Simplest bifurcations in n-dimensional ODEs. Yu.A. Kuznetsov (Utrecht University, NL) March 14, 2011

ANALYSIS AND CONTROLLING OF HOPF BIFURCATION FOR CHAOTIC VAN DER POL-DUFFING SYSTEM. China

2D-Volterra-Lotka Modeling For 2 Species

HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011

Lyapunov Stability Theory

Monotone and oscillatory solutions of a rational difference equation containing quadratic terms

Nonlinear Phillips Curves, Complex Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Keynesian Macro Model

Phase Synchronization

Assignment #5. 1 Keynesian Cross. Econ 302: Intermediate Macroeconomics. December 2, 2009

AUTOMATIC CONTROL. Andrea M. Zanchettin, PhD Spring Semester, Introduction to Automatic Control & Linear systems (time domain)

Solutions for B8b (Nonlinear Systems) Fake Past Exam (TT 10)

Research Article Hopf Bifurcation Analysis and Anticontrol of Hopf Circles of the Rössler-Like System

Analysis of the Takens-Bogdanov bifurcation on m parameterized vector fields

Introduction to Nonlinear Control Lecture # 3 Time-Varying and Perturbed Systems

1. < 0: the eigenvalues are real and have opposite signs; the fixed point is a saddle point

Theoretical premises of the Keynesian approach

11 Chaos in Continuous Dynamical Systems.

Mathematical Foundations of Neuroscience - Lecture 7. Bifurcations II.

Technical appendices: Business cycle accounting for the Japanese economy using the parameterized expectations algorithm

HOPF BIFURCATION WITH S 3 -SYMMETRY

Lecture 5. Outline: Limit Cycles. Definition and examples How to rule out limit cycles. Poincare-Bendixson theorem Hopf bifurcations Poincare maps

ECON0702: Mathematical Methods in Economics

Research Article A Dynamic Economic Model with Discrete Time and Consumer Sentiment

A modification of Kaldor-Kalecki model and its analysis

Dynamical Systems in Neuroscience: Elementary Bifurcations

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Hopf bifurcations analysis of a three-dimensional nonlinear system

A two-sector Keynesian model of business cycles

LIMIT CYCLES COMING FROM THE PERTURBATION OF 2-DIMENSIONAL CENTERS OF VECTOR FIELDS IN R 3

Counting Roots of the Characteristic Equation for Linear Delay-Differential Systems

BIFURCATION PHENOMENA Lecture 1: Qualitative theory of planar ODEs

Extended IS-LM model - construction and analysis of behavior

Exercises for Chapter 7

Two-Country Model. Masato Nakao. Graduate School of Economics, Chuo University. Abstract

Nonlinear stability of steady flow of Giesekus viscoelastic fluid

Transcription:

Proceedings of Equadiff-11 005, pp. 9 36 ISBN 978-80-7-64-5 ON THE EXISTENCE OF HOPF BIFURCATION IN AN OPEN ECONOMY MODEL KATARÍNA MAKOVÍNYIOVÁ AND RUDOLF ZIMKA Abstract. In the paper a four dimensional open economy model describing the development of output, exchange rate, interest rate and money supply is analyzed. Sufficient conditions for the existence of equilibrium stability and the existence of business cycles are found. Formulae for the calculation of bifurcation coefficients are derived. Key words. dynamical model, equilibrium, stability, bifurcation, cycles AMS subject classifications. 37Gxx 1. Introduction. In economic theory there are many macroeconomic models describing the development of output Y in an economy. The majority of them are based on the well-known IS-LM model. One of them is the Schinasi s model (see [5]) describing the development of output Y, interest rate R and money supply L s in a closed economy. In [8] the Schinasi s model was extended to an open economy model of the kind Ẏ = α [ I(Y, R) + G + X(ρ) S(Y D, R) T (Y ) M(Y, ρ) ] ρ = β [M(Y, ρ) + C x (R) X(ρ) C m (R)] Ṙ = γ [L(Y, R) L S ] L S = G + M(Y, ρ) + C x (R) T (Y ) X(ρ) C m (R), (1.1) where Y output, ρ exchange rate, R interest rate, L S money supply, I investments, S savings, G government expenditures, T tax collections, X export, M import, C x capital export, C m capital import, L money demand, α, β, γ positive parameters, t time and Y D = Y T (Y ), Ẏ = dy dt, dρ ρ = dt, Ṙ = dr dt, L S = dl S dt. The economic properties of the functions in (1.1) are expressed by the following partial derivatives: I(Y, R) I(Y, R) T (Y ) X(ρ) ρ C x (R) C m (R) S(Y D, R) M(Y, ρ) L(Y, R) S(Y D, R) M(Y, ρ) ρ L(Y, R) < 0. (1.) Department of Mathematics and Descriptive Geometry, Faculty of Wood Sciences and Technology, Technical university Zvolen, Zvolen, Slovakia (kmakovin@vsld.tuzvo.sk). Department of Quantitative Methods and Informatics, Faculty of Economics, Matej Bel University, Banská Bystrica, Slovakia (rudolf.zimka@umb.sk). 9

30 K. Makovínyiová and R. Zimka The development of Y, ρ, R and L S in the model (1.1) in a neighborhood of its equilibrium was studied under fixed exchange rate regime in [6] and under flexible exchange rate regime in [] from the point of equilibrium stability and the existence of business cycles. In [4] this model was analyzed under assumption that both ρ and R are flexible. In the paper [4] the assertion on the existence of business cycles was formulated under assumption of the existence of the Liapunov bifurcation constant a. In the present paper a formula for the calculation of this Liapunov bifurcation constant a is found supposing that the functions I(Y, R) and S(Y D, R) are nonlinear with respect to Y and linear with respect to R, and other functions in (1.1) are linear with respect to all their variables except government expenditures G, which are constant. In the end of the paper an example illustrating the achieved results is presented.. Analysis of the model (1.1). Using denotation the model (1.1) has the form B(Y, R) = I(Y, R) S(Y D, R) C(R) = C m (R) C x (R) D(Y ) = G T (Y ) F (Y, ρ) = X(ρ) M(Y, ρ), Ẏ = α [B(Y, R) + D(Y ) + F (Y, ρ)] ρ = β [F (Y, ρ) + C(R)] Ṙ = γ [L(Y, R) L S ] L S = D(Y ) F (Y, ρ) C(R), (.1) where on the base of (1.) B(Y, R) C(R) D(Y ) F (Y, ρ) F (Y, ρ) ρ and the sign of B(Y,R) can be positive or negative or zero according to the properties of I(Y, R) and S(Y D, R). Assume: 1. The functions I(Y, R), S(Y D, R), T (Y ), C(R), D(Y ), F (Y, ρ), L(Y, R) are of the kind I(Y, R) = i 0 + i 1 Y i3 R, C(R) = c 0 + c 3 R, S(Y D, R) = s 0 + s 1 (Y D ) + s 3 R, D(Y ) = d 0 d 1 Y, Y D = Y T (Y ), F (Y, ρ) = f 0 f 1 Y + f ρ, T (Y ) = t 0 + t 1 Y, L(Y, R) = l 0 + l 1 Y l 3 R, with positive coefficients i 1, i 3, s 1, s 3, t 1, c 3, d 1, f 1, f, l 1, l 3.. The model (.1) has an isolated equilibrium E = (Y, ρ, R, L S ), Y ρ R L S > 0. Remark 1. A sufficient condition for the existence of an isolated equilibrium E of the model (.1) was presented in [4]. Consider an isolated equilibrium E = (Y, ρ, R, L S ) of (.1). After the transformation Y 1 = Y Y, ρ 1 = ρ ρ, R 1 = R R, L S 1 = L S L S,

Equadiff-11. On the existence of Hopf bifurcation in an open economy model 31 the equilibrium E goes into the origin E1 = (Y1 = 0, ρ 1 = 0, R1 = 0, L S 1 = 0) and the model (.1) takes the form Ẏ 1 = α [B(Y 1 + Y, R 1 + R ) + D(Y 1 + Y ) + F (Y 1 + Y, ρ 1 + ρ )] ρ 1 = β [F (Y 1 + Y, ρ 1 + ρ ) + C(R 1 + R )] Ṙ 1 = γ [L(Y 1 + Y, R 1 + R ) L S 1 L S 1 ] L S 1 = D(Y 1 + Y ) F (Y 1 + Y, ρ 1 + ρ ) C(R 1 + R ). (.) Performing Taylor expansion of the functions on the right-hand side in (.) at the equilibrium E1 we get the model [ 4 ] Ẏ 1 = α [(b 1 d 1 f 1 )Y 1 + f ρ 1 b 3 R 1 ] + α a k Y1 k + O( Y 1 5 ) ρ 1 = β (f 1 Y 1 f ρ 1 c 3 R 1 ) Ṙ 1 = γ (l 1 Y 1 l 3 R 1 L S 1 ) L S 1 = (f 1 d 1 )Y 1 f ρ 1 c 3 R 1, k= (.3) where b 1 = B(Y,R ), b 3 = i 3 + s 3, a k = k B(Y,R ), k =, 3, 4. k The linear approximation matrix of (.3) is α(b 1 d 1 f 1 ) αf αb 3 0 A(α, β, γ) = βf 1 βf βc 3 0 γl 1 0 γl 3 γ. (.4) f 1 d 1 f c 3 0 The characteristic equation of A(α, β, γ) is λ 4 + a 1 (α, β, γ)λ 3 + a (α, β, γ)λ + a 3 (α, β, γ)λ + a 4 (α, β, γ) = 0, (.5) where a 1 = α( b 1 + d 1 + f 1 ) + βf + γl 3, a = γc 3 + βγf l 3 + α(βf ( b 1 + d 1 ) + γ(b 3 l 1 + l 3 ( b 1 + d 1 + f 1 ))), a 3 = αγ(βf (l 1 (b 3 + c 3 ) + l 3 ( b 1 + d 1 )) c 3 ( b 1 + d 1 + f 1 ) b 3 (f 1 d 1 )), a 4 = αβγd 1 f (b 3 + c 3 ). As we are interested in equilibrium stability and in the existence of cycles in the model (.3) it is suitable to find such values of parameters α, β, γ at which the equation (.5) has a pair of purely imaginary eigenvalues λ 1 = iω, λ = iω, and the rest two eigenvalues λ 3, λ 4 are negative or have negative real parts. We shall call such values of parameters α, β, γ as critical values of the model (.3) and denote them α 0, β 0, γ 0. Mentioned types of eigenvalues are ensured by the Liu s conditions ([3]): a 1 a a 3 a 4 (.6) 3 = (a 1 a a 3 )a 3 a 1 a 4 = 0. (.7)

3 K. Makovínyiová and R. Zimka The conditions (.6) are satisfied if b 1 + d 1 0, α > α = c 3 l 3 ( b 1 + d 1 + f 1 ) + b 3 l 1, ( b 1 + d 1 + f 1 )c 3 + (f 1 d 1 )b 3 < 0. The relation (.7) can be expressed in the form [ ] a (1) (β, γ)β + a () γ α + where in the power of (.8) there is [ b (1) (β, γ)β + b () (γ)γ a () = ( b 1 + d 1 + f 1 )[b 3 (f 1 d 1 ) ] α + c (1) (β, γ)β + c () γ = 0, +c 3 ( b 1 + d 1 + f 1 )][ b 3 l 1 l 3 ( b 1 + d 1 + f 1 )] c () = c 3 l 3 [b 3 (f 1 d 1 ) + c 3 ( b 1 + d 1 + f 1 )] < 0. Take γ at any positive level and denote it γ 0. Then a () γ 0 > 0 and c () γ 0 < 0. Denote A(β) = a (1) (β, γ 0 )β + a () γ 0, B(β) = b (1) (β, γ 0 )β + b () (γ 0 )γ 0, C(β) = c (1) (β, γ 0 )β + c () γ 0. (.8) Take β such small that A(β) > 0 and C(β) < 0. Denote this β as β 0. Then the equation A(β 0 )α + B(β 0 )α + C(β 0 ) = 0 has two roots α 1, = B(β 0) ± { (B(β 0 )) 4A(β 0 )C(β 0 ) α1 < 0 = A(β 0 ) α > 0, and the function 3 (α) = A(β 0 )α + B(β 0 )α + C(β 0 ) has the following form (Fig..1): Fig..1. Denote α = α 0. The triple (α 0, β 0, γ 0 ) is the critical triple of the model (.3). Thus for given specific values of β 0, γ 0 it is always possible to find such a value α 0 that the condition (.7) is satisfied. From Figure 1 we get in a small neighborhood of α 0 : If α > α 0 then 3 (α) = (a 1 a a 3 )a 3 a1 a 4 > 0. If α < α 0 then 3 (α) = (a 1 a a 3 )a 3 a1 a 4 < 0. (.9) If α = α 0 then 3 (α) = (a 1 a a 3 )a 3 a1 a 4 = 0.

Equadiff-11. On the existence of Hopf bifurcation in an open economy model 33 Consider a critical triple (α 0, β 0, γ 0 ) of the model (.3). Further we shall investigate the behavior of Y 1, ρ 1, R 1 and L S1 around the equilibrium E 1 with respect to parameter α, α (α 0 ε, α 0 + ε), ε and fixed parameters β = β 0, γ = γ 0. Performed considerations enable us to answer the question about the stability of the equilibrium E 1 of the model (.3) in a small neighborhood of the critical value α 0. Theorem 1. Let the conditions (.8) be satisfied and let (α 0, β 0, γ 0 ) be such a critical triple of the model (.3) that A(β 0 ) > 0 and C(β 0 ) < 0. Then: 1. If α 0 α then at every α > α the equilibrium E 1 is asymptotically stable.. If α 0 > α then at every α > α 0 the equilibrium E 1 is asymptotically stable and at every α < α < α 0 the equilibrium E 1 is unstable. Proof. The conditions (.8) guarantee that a 1 a a 3 and a 4 > 0 what together with (.9) at α > α α 0 means that the Routh-Hurwitz necessary and sufficient conditions for all the roots of the equation (.5) to have negative real parts ( 1 (α) > 0, (α) 3 (α) 4 (α) > 0) are satisfied. If α < α < α 0 then 3 (α) < 0 what means that the Routh-Hurwitz conditions are not satisfied. To gain the bifurcation equation of the model (.3) it is suitable to transform (.3) to its partial normal form on invariant surface. After the shift of α 0 into the origin by relation α 1 = α α 0 the model (.3) takes the form Ẏ 1 = α 0 [(b 1 d 1 f 1 )Y 1 + f ρ 1 b 3 R 1 ] + (b 1 d 1 f 1 )Y 1 α 1 4 4 + f ρ 1 α 1 b 3 R 1 α 1 + α 0 a k Y1 k + α 1 a k Y1 k + O( Y 1 5 ) k= ρ 1 = β 0 (f 1 Y 1 f ρ 1 c 3 R 1 ) Ṙ 1 = γ 0 (l 1 Y 1 l 3 R 1 L S 1 ) L S 1 = (f 1 d 1 )Y 1 f ρ 1 c 3 R 1. k= (.10) Consider the matrix M which transfers the matrix A(α 0, β 0, γ 0 ) into its Jordan form J. Then the transformation x = My, x = (Y 1, ρ 1, R 1, L S1 ) T, y = (Y, ρ, R, L S ) T takes the model (.10) into the model Ẏ = λ 1 Y + F 1 (Y, ρ, R, L S, α 1 ) ρ = λ ρ + F (Y, ρ, R, L S, α 1 ) Ṙ = λ 3 R + F 3 (Y, ρ, R, L S, α 1 ) L S = λ 4 L S + F 4 (Y, ρ, R, L S, α 1 ), (.11) where ρ = Y, F = F 1, and F 3, F 4 are real (the symbol - means complex conjugate expression in the whole article; for the sake of simplicity we suppose that λ 3, λ 4 are real and not equal). Theorem. There exists a polynomial transformation Y = Y 3 + h 1 (Y 3, ρ 3, α 1 ) ρ = ρ 3 + h (Y 3, ρ 3, α 1 ) R = R 3 + h 3 (Y 3, ρ 3, α 1 ) L S = L S3 + h 4 (Y 3, ρ 3, α 1 ), (.1)

34 K. Makovínyiová and R. Zimka where h j (Y 3, ρ 3, α 1 ), j = 1,, 3, 4, are nonlinear polynomials with constant coefficients of the kind h j (Y 3, ρ 3, α 1 ) = ν (m1,m,m3) Y m1 3 ρ m 3 α m3 1, j = 1,, 3, 4, h = h 1, m 1,m,m 3 with the property h j ( α 1 Y 3, α 1 ρ 3, α 1 ) = m 1,m,m 3 ν (m1,m,m3) ( α 1 ) k Y m1 3 ρ m 3, k 4, which transforms the model (.11) into its partial normal form on invariant surface Ẏ 3 = λ 1 Y 3 +δ 1 Y 3 α 1 +δ Y 3 ρ 3 +U (Y 3, ρ 3, R 3, L S3, α 1 )+U (Y 3, ρ 3, R 3, L S3, α 1 ) ρ 3 = λ ρ 3 + δ 1 ρ 3 α 1 + δ Y 3 ρ 3 + U + U Ṙ 3 = λ 3 R 3 + V (Y 3, ρ 3, R 3, L S3, α 1 ) + V (Y 3, ρ 3, R 3, L S3, α 1 ) L S 3 = λ 4 L S3 + W (Y 3, ρ 3, R 3, L S3, α 1 ) + W (Y 3, ρ 3, R 3, L S3, α 1 ), (.13) where U (Y 3, ρ 3, 0, 0, α 1 ) = V (Y 3, ρ 3, 0, 0, α 1 ) = W (Y 3, ρ 3, 0, 0, α 1 ) = 0 and U ( α 1 Y 3, α 1 ρ 3, α 1 R 3, α 1 L S3,α 1 )=V ( α 1 Y 3, α 1 ρ 3, α 1 R 3, α 1 L S3,α 1 ) = W ( α 1 Y 3, α 1 ρ 3, α 1 R 3, α 1 L S3, α 1 ) = O( α 1 ) 5. The resonant terms δ 1 and δ in the model (.13) are determined by the formulae δ 1 = F 1 α 1, δ = 1 λ F 1 F 1 + 1 F 1 ρ 6λ 1 ρ F + 1 λ 1 F 1 ρ F ρ 1 λ 3 F 1 F 3 ρ + 1 F 1 F 3 (λ 1 λ 3 ) ρ 1 F 1 F 4 1 F 1 F 4 + λ 4 Ls ρ (λ 1 λ 4 ) ρ Ls + 1 3 F 1 ρ, where all derivatives in δ 1 and δ are calculated at E 1 and α 1 = 0. Proof. Differentiating (.1) in the power of (.11) and (.13) we get the equations for the determination of the individual terms of the polynomials h j, j = 1,, 3, 4, and the resonant terms δ 1, δ by standard step by step procedure. As the whole record of this procedure is rather long we are omitting it. The model (.13) takes in polar coordinates Y 3 = re iϕ, ρ 3 = re iϕ the form ṙ = r(ar + bα 1 ) + Ũ (r, ϕ, R 3, L S3, α 1 ) + Ũ (r, ϕ, R 3, L S3, α 1 ) ϕ = ω + cα 1 + dr + 1 r [Φ (r, ϕ, R 3, L S3, α 1 ) + Φ (r, ϕ, R 3, L S3, α 1 )] Ṙ 3 = λ 3 R 3 + Ṽ 1 (r, ϕ, R 3, L S3, α 1 ) + Ṽ 1 (r, ϕ, R 3, L S3, α 1 ) L S 3 = λ 4 L S3 + W 1 (r, ϕ, R 3, L S3, α 1 ) + W 1 (r, ϕ, R 3, L S3, α 1 ), (.14) where a = Re δ, b = Re δ 1.

Equadiff-11. On the existence of Hopf bifurcation in an open economy model 35 The behavior of solutions of the model (.14) around its equilibrium for small parameters α 1 depends on the signs of the constants a, b. It is known that to every constant solution of the bifurcation equation ar +bα 1 = 0 a periodic solution of (.14) corresponds (see for example [1]). The following theorem ([4]) gives a sufficient condition for the negativeness of the coefficient b. Theorem 3. Let the assumptions of Theorem 1 be satisfied. Let in addition α 0 > α and the critical value β 0 be such that c 3 β 0 f l 3 > 0. Then the value of the coefficient b is negative. Analyzing the model (.14) and taking into account all transformations which have been done to get (.14) we can formulate on the base of Poincaré-Andronov-Hopf bifurcation theorem (see for example [7]) the following statement. Theorem 4. Let the assumptions of Theorem 1 be satisfied. Let in addition α 0 > α and the critical value β 0 be such that c 3 β 0 f l 3 > 0. Then: 1. If a > 0 then the equilibrium E 1 of the model (.3) is unstable also at the critical triple (α 0, β 0, γ 0 ) and to every α > α 0 there exists an unstable limit cycle.. If a < 0 then the equilibrium E 1 of the model (.3) is asymptotically stable also at the critical triple (α 0, β 0, γ 0 ) and to every α < α < α 0 there exists a stable limit cycle..1. Numerical example. Take the functions I, S, T, C, D, F, L from the model (1.1) in the form I = 1.8 + 0.6 Y 0.3R, S = 0.8 + 0.01(Y D ) + 0.3R, Y D = 0.7Y + 0., T = 0. + 0.3Y, C = 0.04 + 0.R, D =.7 0.3Y, F = 0.6 0.05Y + 0.03ρ, L = + 0.8Y 0.R. Then (1.1) has the following form [ Ẏ = α 0.6 ] Y 0.01(0.7Y + 0.) 0.35Y + 0.03ρ 0.6R + 4.7 ρ = β ( 0.05Y + 0.03ρ + 0.R 0.576) Ṙ = γ (0.8Y 0.R L S + ) L S = 0.5Y 0.03ρ 0.R + 3.76. (.15) The equilibrium of (.15) is E = (Y = 9, ρ = 1.541667, R = 4.941875, L S = 8.1165), where the values of Y and L S are taken in 10 milliards. After the transformation of E into the origin and Taylor expansion the model (.15) has the form Ẏ 1 = α( 0.341Y 1 + 0.03ρ 1 0.6R 1 ) [ + α 691 90000 Y 1 + 1 6480 Y 1 3 1 ] 9331 Y 1 4 + O( Y 1 5 ) ρ 1 = β (0.05Y 1 0.03ρ 1 0.R 1 ) Ṙ 1 = γ (0.8Y 1 0.R 1 L S 1 ) L S 1 = 0.5Y 1 0.03ρ 1 0.R 1. (.16)

36 K. Makovínyiová and R. Zimka The matrix of linear approximation of this model is A(α, β, γ) = 0.341α 0.03α 0.6α 0 0.05β 0.03β 0.β 0 0.8γ 0 0.γ γ 0.5 0.03 0. 0. = 0.6774. The eigenval- Take β 0 = 1, γ 0 = 1. Then α 0 = 5(661077753+46357 46690885481) 93377956749 ues of the matrix A(α 0, β 0, γ 0 ) are. λ 1. = 0.3886 i, λ. = 0.3886 i, λ3. = 0.3748, λ4. = 0.086. The formulae for the calculation of the resonant constants δ 1 and δ, which are introduced in Theorem, give the values The bifurcation coefficients are δ 1. = 0.3180 0.3537 i, δ. = 0.000 0.004 i. a = Re δ. = 0.000, b = Re δ1. = 0.3180, and the partial normal form of the model (.16) on invariant surface for critical triple (α 0, β 0, γ 0 ) = (0.6774, 1, 1) in polar coordinates is ṙ = r(0.000r 0.3180α 1 ) + Ũ (r, ϕ, R 3, L S3, α 1 ) + Ũ (r, ϕ, R 3, L S3, α 1 ) ϕ = 0.3886 0.3537α 1 0.004r + 1 r [Φ + Φ ] Ṙ 3 = 0.3748R 3 + Ṽ 1 (r, ϕ, R 3, L S3, α 1 ) + Ṽ 1 (r, ϕ, R 3, L S3, α 1 ) L S 3 = 0.086L S3 + W 1 (r, ϕ, R 3, L S3, α 1 ) + W 1 (r, ϕ, R 3, L S3, α 1 ). The value of α from (.8) is α. = 0.3648. On the base of the values a and b we get. the following result: To every value of parameter α > α 0 = 0.6774 the equilibrium of the model (.15) is asymptotically stable and there exists an unstable limit cycle. To every value of parameter α (0.3648, 0.6774) this equilibrium is unstable. REFERENCES [1] Yu. N. Bibikov, Multi-frequency non-linear oscillations and their bifurcations, The Publishing House of the Saint Petersburg University, Saint Petersburg, 1991, (in Russian). [] P. Fellnerová and R. Zimka, On Stability and Fluctuations in Open Economy Model under Flexible Exchange Rate Regime, Prace Naukowe Akademii Ekonomicznej we Wroclawiu, 1036 (004), 339 347. [3] W. M. Liu, Criterion of Hopf Bifurcations without using Eigenvalues, Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications, 18 (1994), 50 56. [4] K. Makovínyiová and R. Zimka, On Fluctuations in an Open Economy Model, Proceeding of the 7 th International conference Applications of Mathematics and Statistics in Economy, University of Economics Prague, Faculty of Informatics and Statistics, Professional Publishing, Prague (004), 144 15. [5] G. J. Schinasi, Fluctuations in a Dynamic, Intermediate-Run IS-LM Model: Applications of the Poincaré-Bendixon Theorem, Journal of Economics Theory, 8 (198), 369 375. [6] L. Striežovská and R. Zimka, Cycles in an Open Economy Model under Fixed Exchange Rate Regime with Pure Money Financing, Operations Research and Decisions, Quarterly 3 4, Wroclaw (00), 133 141. [7] S. Wiggins, Introduction to Applied Nonlinear Dynamical Systems and Chaos, Springer-Verlag, Berlin, 1990. [8] E. Zimková and R. Zimka, The Stability of an Open Economy Model, Mundus Symbolicus 10, Economic University, Prague (00), 187 193.