Solutions to exercises on delays. P (x = 0 θ = 1)P (θ = 1) P (x = 0) We can replace z in the first equation by its value in the second equation.

Similar documents
4. Score normalization technical details We now discuss the technical details of the score normalization method.

Optimism, Delay and (In)Efficiency in a Stochastic Model of Bargaining

COMMUNICATION BETWEEN SHAREHOLDERS 1

Econometrica Supplementary Material

San Francisco State University ECON 851 Summer Problem Set 1

Research Note REGRESSION ANALYSIS IN MARKOV CHAIN * A. Y. ALAMUTI AND M. R. MESHKANI **

4.1 The basic model of herding

Topic: Lower Bounds on Randomized Algorithms Date: September 22, 2004 Scribe: Srinath Sridhar

Handout #3: Peak Load Pricing

ECE 534 Information Theory - Midterm 2

Chapter 7: Special Distributions

Trading OTC and Incentives to Clear Centrally

The Poisson Regression Model

DYNAMIC COSTS AND MORAL HAZARD: A DUALITY BASED APPROACH. Guy Arie 1

Theory of Externalities Partial Equilibrium Analysis

Standards Battles and Public Policy

6 Stationary Distributions

Solution sheet ξi ξ < ξ i+1 0 otherwise ξ ξ i N i,p 1 (ξ) + where 0 0

Math 4400/6400 Homework #8 solutions. 1. Let P be an odd integer (not necessarily prime). Show that modulo 2,

Uniform Law on the Unit Sphere of a Banach Space

MATH 2710: NOTES FOR ANALYSIS

On a Markov Game with Incomplete Information

Combining Logistic Regression with Kriging for Mapping the Risk of Occurrence of Unexploded Ordnance (UXO)

Notes on Instrumental Variables Methods

CERIAS Tech Report The period of the Bell numbers modulo a prime by Peter Montgomery, Sangil Nahm, Samuel Wagstaff Jr Center for Education

Section 0.10: Complex Numbers from Precalculus Prerequisites a.k.a. Chapter 0 by Carl Stitz, PhD, and Jeff Zeager, PhD, is available under a Creative

AN OPTIMAL CONTROL CHART FOR NON-NORMAL PROCESSES

INTRODUCTION. Please write to us at if you have any comments or ideas. We love to hear from you.

8 STOCHASTIC PROCESSES

Selling Information. May 26, Abstract

B8.1 Martingales Through Measure Theory. Concept of independence

Elementary Analysis in Q p

Stochastic integration II: the Itô integral

i) the probability of type I error; ii) the 95% con dence interval; iii) the p value; iv) the probability of type II error; v) the power of a test.

Objectives. 6.1, 7.1 Estimating with confidence (CIS: Chapter 10) CI)

MATH 829: Introduction to Data Mining and Analysis Consistency of Linear Regression

Objectives. Estimating with confidence Confidence intervals.

Cascades and herds. Chapter 4. One million people cannot be wrong.

Availability and Maintainability. Piero Baraldi

SIGNALING IN CONTESTS. Tomer Ifergane and Aner Sela. Discussion Paper No November 2017

Feedback-error control

Advance Selling in the Presence of Experienced Consumers

Selling Information. September 5, Abstract

Centralized decision making against informed lobbying

1 Extremum Estimators

where x i is the ith coordinate of x R N. 1. Show that the following upper bound holds for the growth function of H:

Online Appendix to Accompany AComparisonof Traditional and Open-Access Appointment Scheduling Policies

ON POLYNOMIAL SELECTION FOR THE GENERAL NUMBER FIELD SIEVE

Lecture: Condorcet s Theorem

Dynamic costs and moral hazard: A duality-based approach

15-451/651: Design & Analysis of Algorithms October 23, 2018 Lecture #17: Prediction from Expert Advice last changed: October 25, 2018

arxiv: v1 [physics.data-an] 26 Oct 2012

Topic 7: Using identity types

Directives, expressives, and motivation

International Trade with a Public Intermediate Good and the Gains from Trade

GOOD MODELS FOR CUBIC SURFACES. 1. Introduction

Partial Identification in Triangular Systems of Equations with Binary Dependent Variables

STA 250: Statistics. Notes 7. Bayesian Approach to Statistics. Book chapters: 7.2

Voting with Behavioral Heterogeneity

Characterizing the Behavior of a Probabilistic CMOS Switch Through Analytical Models and Its Verification Through Simulations

Class Field Theory. Peter Stevenhagen. 1. Class Field Theory for Q

Paper C Exact Volume Balance Versus Exact Mass Balance in Compositional Reservoir Simulation

A note on the preferred hedge instrument

Practice Final Solutions

The non-stochastic multi-armed bandit problem

Estimating Time-Series Models

Lecture 6. 2 Recurrence/transience, harmonic functions and martingales

Towards understanding the Lorenz curve using the Uniform distribution. Chris J. Stephens. Newcastle City Council, Newcastle upon Tyne, UK

Introduction to Probability for Graphical Models

Lecture 14: Introduction to Decision Making

Asymptotically Optimal Simulation Allocation under Dependent Sampling

k- price auctions and Combination-auctions

Generating Swerling Random Sequences

Homework Set #3 Rates definitions, Channel Coding, Source-Channel coding

pp physics, RWTH, WS 2003/04, T.Hebbeker

Confronting Theory with Experimental Data and vice versa. Lecture VII Social learning. The Norwegian School of Economics Nov 7-11, 2011

Sums of independent random variables

Principal Components Analysis and Unsupervised Hebbian Learning

Sequential Choice of Sharing Rules in Collective Contests

ASYMPTOTIC RESULTS OF A HIGH DIMENSIONAL MANOVA TEST AND POWER COMPARISON WHEN THE DIMENSION IS LARGE COMPARED TO THE SAMPLE SIZE

16.2. Infinite Series. Introduction. Prerequisites. Learning Outcomes

Robustness of classifiers to uniform l p and Gaussian noise Supplementary material

Monte Carlo Studies. Monte Carlo Studies. Sampling Distribution

7.2 Inference for comparing means of two populations where the samples are independent

Econ 101A Midterm 2 Th 8 April 2009.

1-way quantum finite automata: strengths, weaknesses and generalizations

3. Show that if there are 23 people in a room, the probability is less than one half that no two of them share the same birthday.

Chemical Kinetics and Equilibrium - An Overview - Key

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec

ECON Answers Homework #2

arxiv:cond-mat/ v2 25 Sep 2002

A Time-Varying Threshold STAR Model of Unemployment

Learning to Coordinate

Field Exam: Advanced Theory

Chapter 10. Classical Fourier Series

#A37 INTEGERS 15 (2015) NOTE ON A RESULT OF CHUNG ON WEIL TYPE SUMS

2x2x2 Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson (H-O-S) model with factor substitution

Decoding Linear Block Codes Using a Priority-First Search: Performance Analysis and Suboptimal Version

A Model for Randomly Correlated Deposition

Almost 4000 years ago, Babylonians had discovered the following approximation to. x 2 dy 2 =1, (5.0.2)

Transcription:

Ec 517 Christohe Chamley Solutions to exercises on delays Ex 1: P (θ = 1 x = 0) = P (x = 0 θ = 1)P (θ = 1) P (x = 0) = 1 z)µ (1 z)µ + 1 µ. The value of z is solution of µ c = δµz(1 c). We can relace z in the first equation by its value in the second equation. When δ tends to 1 the value of z decreases. We can and we should answer the question without the revious answer, using the arbitrage equation (1.2) in the text. At the limit, the value of P (θ = 1 x = 0 tends to c. Verify your intuition. Ex 2: The solution is µ c = δµz(1 γ)(1 c). The value of z is endogenous to γ. The roduct z(1 γ) is constant. When γ iincreases, the value of z increases to comensate for the loss of visibility of investment. Of course, z is bounded by 1. Therefore, there is a maximum value γ for which the argument is true. Ex 3: The arbitrage equation becomes µ c = δµz(1 c + τ). The subsidy increases the incentive to delay and therefore reduces z. The welfare of agent(s) is unchanged because it is equal to µ c and indeendent of τ. Ex 4: In the equilibrium, µ c = δµ(1 (1 z) N 1 (1 c). When N increases, the term (1 z) N 1 is constant. In the good state, the robability of a herd with no investment (following no investment in the first eriod) is (1 z) N = (1 z)(1 z) N 1, which is constant. (Here we have the ower N because we have the oint of view of an outside observer and not the oint of view of a layer who decides to delay and see what other layers (if any) do. The other exercises are related to material that was not covered in the class.

Assignment 3 with answers There are two rojects, X and Y. The ayoff of X is equal to 0 or 2 + a, with equal rior robabilities. a is small and ositive. The ayoff of Y is equal to 1 a or 1 + a with equal rior robabilities. (The rojects return are not random and they are indeendent). As in the BHW model, agents, in an exogenous sequence, have the choice between two rojects. Each individual has a SBS s on the roject X such that P (s = 1 x = 2 + a) = q with > 1/2. Agents have a symmetric binary signal, H or L, of recision q on the ayoff of action 1. There is no signal on the roject Y. By assumtion a is ositive and sufficiently small (whatever will be needed to answer questions). 1. Assume that the outcome of a roject that is imlemented cannot be observed by subsequent individuals. Show that if the first agent has a signal H, a cascade starts in eriod 2. Show that if the first two signals are L and L, then a cascade starts in eriod 3. 2. Comare the revious model with the standard BHW model with two states for a roject, ayoffs 1 and 0, a SBS with recision and a rior µ on the state 1 such that 1/2 < µ <. Determine the robabilities of an eventual cascade in roject X and the robability of an eventual Y cascade. 3. Suose that the first signal is H. Determine in that case, after the signal H becomes ublic, the long-run exected welfare of individuals, that is the average exected value of the ayoff of X for agents. 4. Answer the same question after the signal L. Call that welfare U 0. 5. Using your revious answers, determine the ex ante long-run exected welfare of individuals. 6. Assume now that individuals can observe the ayoff of roject Y at the end of the first eriod in which it is undertaken. (a) Assume the first signal is L and the outut of Y is high (1 + a). Determine the long-run welfare conditional on that event. (b) Assume that the first signal is L and the outut of Y is low (1 a). Show that the imact of the rivate signals on the individual actions are the same from that oint on, as in the case where the outut of Y could not be observed. Using your answer in question 2 to determine the exected long-run welfare from that oint on. (Be careful on the welfare in a Y cascade).

7. Using your revious answers, determine the long-run exected welfare of individuals and show that it is smaller than in the revious question. 8. Assume now the ayoff of Y is observable with one eriod delay. Analyze the model and show that the long-run social welfare is higher than under the condition of the revious question. Answers 1. With no signal, roject X has a higher ayoff that roject Y. Assuming the recision of the signal is sufficiently high (otherwise a cascade on X starts right away), the action in eriod 1 reveals the signal H. In eriod, the imact of a signal L (that reduces the attractiveness of X) on a belief is nullified by the signal H of the first eriod. The belief is the same as with no signal and X has a higher ayoff. A cascade starts after the first eriod. 2. Any sequence of signals with H and L generates a sequence of actions X or Y that is the same as in the BHW model when we relace H and L by the realization 1 and 0 of the rivate signals and the actions X and Y by the actions 1 and 0, resectively. We use the equivalence and these robabilities have been comuted before in the semester. A cascade on X takes lace when the difference between the number of H and L signals is equal to 1. Assume that the state is high (meaning here that X has a ositive ayoff). Let π 0 the robability of a X cascade when the difference between the total H and L signals is 0, and π 1 that robability when the difference is 1. By the revious calculations, π 0 = + (1 )π 1, π 1 = π 0, π 0 = 1 (1 ). If the true state is low (ayoff of X equal to 0), then these robabilities are π 0 = + (1 )π 1, π 1 = π 0, π 0 = 1 1 (1 ). One can for the robabilities. Ex ante, both states are equally likely and the robability of a X cascade is π = (π 0 + π 0 )/2 = 1/2(1 (1 )). The robability of a Y cascade is 1 minus the revious robability (since we always end in one of the two cascades). 3. In a X cascade the ublic belief (robability of ositive ayoff for X) is equal to (because the rior belief is 1/2 and the recision of the signal is. In a X cascade, rivate beliefs are different for the individuals with

X X 1- Y 1- Y t Cascade The robabilities are in the good state. In the bad state, and 1 are switched. Figure 1: Trajectories H and L signals. However, the exected value of the belief after receiving a signal is also equal to the belief before getting the signal (because of the martingale roerty). Therefore, the long-run exected ayoff in that cascade is (2 + a). 4. The exected ayoff in a Y cascade is 1. If π is the robability to end in a X cascade, the ex ante exected ayoff in the long run is therefore U = 1 + π((2 + a) 1) or U = Note that if a 0, U 1 + π(2 1). 1 + a + 22 2(1 + 2 ). 5. If the first signal is H, the roject is X and there is a cascade with ayoff (2 + a). The robability of that event is 1/2. The contribution to welfare by that branch is therefore (1 + a/2). If the first signal is L (with ex ante robability 1/2), then Y is undertaken. If its ayoff is equal to 1+a, there is a cascade at Y after that. The exected long-run ayoff in that case is (1 + a)/2. The robability of this event is 1/2 and the contribution to total welfare is (1 + a)/4. If its ayoff is 1 a, then in the second eriod, a bad signal leads to a Y cascade with ayoff 1 a because at the oint the exected ayoff of X is lower than 1 a: (2 + a)(1 ) 2 /((1 ) 2 + 2 ) < 1 a if a is sufficiently small (using > 1/2). That event has robability ((1 )(1 ) + 2 )/2 and the contribution to welfare is ((1 ) 2 + 2 )(1 a)/2.

A good signal in eriod 2 leads to X in eriod 2. After eriod 2, the dynamics are the same as in the case with no ayoff observation with the same first belief µ. There is one difference however: in the Y cascade, the ayoff is now 1 a instead of 1 because the (low) outut of Y has been revealed. The robability of that event is (1/2)(1/2)((1 ) + (1 )) = (1 )/2. The contribution to welfare from that oint on is ((1 )/2)(π(2 + a) + (1 π)(1 a)). Adding u all the terms and taking a vanishingly small (we want to rove the result for a small), the long-run exected welfare is V = + 1 4 + (1 )2 + 2 2 + (1 ) (2π + (1 π)). 2 If V (0) = + 1 4 + (1 )2 + 2 + 2π + 1 π < 1 + π(2 1). V < U is equivalent to (1 + a)/2 < U, which is true for sufficiently small a. How come more information leads to a lower welfare gain in the long-run? More information here is more information for agent 2 who chooses to stick to roject Y even if he has a good signal. By doing so, he derives other agents, after eriod 2 of the information about his signal. That feature is at the core of the cascade roerty: agents make a selfish decision without regard to the information that is conveyed to others by their action. In the long-run, the average welfare of agents is lower. 6. In this case, if agent 1 chooses Y and agent 2 has a signal H, he undertakes X and thus reveals to others his signal. (a) If Y is revealed to ay 1 a, then the dynamics that start in eriod 3 are the same as with no outut observation, with the same initial belief µ on the good state for roject Y.