Backward martingale representation and endogenous completeness in finance

Similar documents
Integral representation of martingales and endogenous completeness of financial models

Quadratic BSDE systems and applications

A class of globally solvable systems of BSDE and applications

The concentration of a drug in blood. Exponential decay. Different realizations. Exponential decay with noise. dc(t) dt.

Non Implementability of Arrow Debreu Equilibria by Continuous Trading under Knightian Uncertainty

A new approach for investment performance measurement. 3rd WCMF, Santa Barbara November 2009

HJB equations. Seminar in Stochastic Modelling in Economics and Finance January 10, 2011

arxiv: v1 [math.pr] 24 Sep 2018

Utility Maximization in Hidden Regime-Switching Markets with Default Risk

Mathematical Methods for Neurosciences. ENS - Master MVA Paris 6 - Master Maths-Bio ( )

Stochastic Integration and Stochastic Differential Equations: a gentle introduction

Stochastic Calculus February 11, / 33

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology

Continuous Time Finance

Jump-type Levy Processes

On continuous time contract theory

Market environments, stability and equlibria

Optimal portfolio strategies under partial information with expert opinions

Competitive Equilibria in a Comonotone Market

Stochastic Volatility and Correction to the Heat Equation

Elliptic Operators with Unbounded Coefficients

Discussion Papers in Economics

Lecture 4: Ito s Stochastic Calculus and SDE. Seung Yeal Ha Dept of Mathematical Sciences Seoul National University

p 1 ( Y p dp) 1/p ( X p dp) 1 1 p

Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise

Lecture 4: Introduction to stochastic processes and stochastic calculus

Non-Zero-Sum Stochastic Differential Games of Controls and St

A New Theory of Inter-temporal Equilibrium

arxiv: v2 [math.pr] 12 May 2013

Discretization of SDEs: Euler Methods and Beyond

On the dual problem of utility maximization

Stochastic modelling and equilibrium in mathematical finance and statistical sequential analysis

A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations

of space-time diffusions

The Wiener Itô Chaos Expansion

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the

Nonlinear representation, backward SDEs, and application to the Principal-Agent problem

Skorokhod Embeddings In Bounded Time

On the Multi-Dimensional Controller and Stopper Games

Question 1. The correct answers are: (a) (2) (b) (1) (c) (2) (d) (3) (e) (2) (f) (1) (g) (2) (h) (1)

Hyperfinite Construction of G-expectation

Optimal Stopping Problems and American Options

Some Terminology and Concepts that We will Use, But Not Emphasize (Section 6.2)

Poisson Jumps in Credit Risk Modeling: a Partial Integro-differential Equation Formulation

Stochastic Differential Equations.

Introduction Optimality and Asset Pricing

Moment Properties of Distributions Used in Stochastic Financial Models

Optimal investment strategies for an index-linked insurance payment process with stochastic intensity

Stochastic optimal control with rough paths

Contagious default: application of methods of Statistical Mechanics in Finance

Stochastic Differential Equations

Variance Reduction Techniques for Monte Carlo Simulations with Stochastic Volatility Models

A problem of portfolio/consumption choice in a. liquidity risk model with random trading times

Uniformly Uniformly-ergodic Markov chains and BSDEs

THE ARROW PRATT INDEXES OF RISK AVERSION AND CONVEX RISK MEASURES THEY IMPLY

The multidimensional Ito Integral and the multidimensional Ito Formula. Eric Mu ller June 1, 2015 Seminar on Stochastic Geometry and its applications

Risk Measures in non-dominated Models

SEPARABLE TERM STRUCTURES AND THE MAXIMAL DEGREE PROBLEM. 1. Introduction This paper discusses arbitrage-free separable term structure (STS) models

Some Aspects of Universal Portfolio

Solution of Stochastic Optimal Control Problems and Financial Applications

UNCERTAINTY FUNCTIONAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS FOR FINANCE

ON THE FIRST TIME THAT AN ITO PROCESS HITS A BARRIER

Course Handouts: Pages 1-20 ASSET PRICE BUBBLES AND SPECULATION. Jan Werner

Introduction to Diffusion Processes.

An Introduction to Malliavin calculus and its applications

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs

Equilibria in Incomplete Stochastic Continuous-time Markets:

Trading Volume in Dynamically Efficient Markets

Theoretical Tutorial Session 2

I forgot to mention last time: in the Ito formula for two standard processes, putting

Bernardo D Auria Stochastic Processes /12. Notes. March 29 th, 2012

THE ASYMPTOTIC ELASTICITY OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS 1

Radner Equilibria under Ambiguous Volatility

Pathwise volatility in a long-memory pricing model: estimation and asymptotic behavior

MATH4210 Financial Mathematics ( ) Tutorial 7

Robust Mean-Variance Hedging via G-Expectation

Ambiguity and Information Processing in a Model of Intermediary Asset Pricing

Prof. Erhan Bayraktar (University of Michigan)

Reflected Brownian Motion

WELL-POSEDNESS FOR HYPERBOLIC PROBLEMS (0.2)

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

A Barrier Version of the Russian Option

Tyler Hofmeister. University of Calgary Mathematical and Computational Finance Laboratory

A MODEL FOR THE LONG-TERM OPTIMAL CAPACITY LEVEL OF AN INVESTMENT PROJECT

Lecture 12: Diffusion Processes and Stochastic Differential Equations

ALEKSANDAR MIJATOVIĆ AND MIKHAIL URUSOV

Density models for credit risk

Worst Case Portfolio Optimization and HJB-Systems

Economics 2010c: Lectures 9-10 Bellman Equation in Continuous Time

Brownian Motion. An Undergraduate Introduction to Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan. J. Robert Buchanan Brownian Motion

On pathwise stochastic integration

Mean-Variance Hedging for Continuous Processes: New Proofs and Examples

Information and Credit Risk

Weak solutions of mean-field stochastic differential equations

Some Tools From Stochastic Analysis

Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem

Backward Stochastic Differential Equations with Infinite Time Horizon

Additional information and pricing-hedging duality in robust framework

Mean-field SDE driven by a fractional BM. A related stochastic control problem

Pavel V. Gapeev, Neofytos Rodosthenous Perpetual American options in diffusion-type models with running maxima and drawdowns

Transcription:

Backward martingale representation and endogenous completeness in finance Dmitry Kramkov (with Silviu Predoiu) Carnegie Mellon University 1 / 19

Bibliography Robert M. Anderson and Roberto C. Raimondo. Equilibrium in continuous-time financial markets: endogenously dynamically complete markets. Econometrica, 76(4):841 97, 28. J. Hugonnier, S. Malamud, and E. Trubowitz. Endogenous completeness of diffusion driven equilibrium markets. Econometrica, 8(3):1249 127, 212. Frank Riedel and Frederik Herzberg. Existence of financial equilibria in continuous time with potentially complete markets. arxiv:127.21v1, July 212. Dmitry Kramkov and Silviu Predoiu. Integral representation of martingales motivated by the problem of endogenous completeness in financial economics. arxiv:111.3248v3, October 212. 2 / 19

Martingale Integral Representation (Ω, F 1, F = (F t ) t [,1], P): a complete filtered probability space. Q: an equivalent probability measure. S = (S j t ): J-dimensional martingale under Q. We want to know whether any local martingale M = (M t ) under Q admits an integral representation with respect to S, that is, M t = M + H u ds u, t [, 1], for some predictable S-integrable process H = (H j t). Completeness in Mathematical Finance. Jacod s Theorem (2nd FTAP): the integral representation holds iff Q is the only martingale measure for S. Easy to verify if S is given in terms of local characteristics ( forward description). 3 / 19

Backward Martingale Representation Inputs: random variables ζ > and ψ = (ψ j ) The density of the martingale measure Q is defined by dq dp = const ζ. ψ is the terminal value for S: S t E Q [ψ F t ], t [, 1]. Problem Determine (easily verifiable) conditions on ζ and ψ so that the martingale representation property holds under Q and S. 4 / 19

Radner equilibrium Inputs: M agents with utility functions U m and initial random endowments Λ m, interest rate r =, J stocks with terminal values (dividends) ψ = (ψ j ). Output: stocks price process S = (St j ) such that 1. S 1 = ψ. 2. Given the S-market, the agents optimal strategies (stock s quantities) H m = (Ht m,j ) satisfy the clearing condition: M m=1 H m,j t =, t [, 1], j = 1,..., J. 5 / 19

Construction of Radner equilibrium Two steps: 1. Find static (Arrow-Debreu) equilibrium, that is, find a pricing measure Q such that if economic agents can trade any payoff ξ at the price p = E Q [ξ], then the clearing condition holds: the total wealth does not change. Main tool: Brower s fixed point theorem. 2. Define S t = E Q [ψ F t ], t [, 1], (ψ is the terminal dividend) and verify endogenous completeness of the S-market = Radner equilibrium. Other applications: equilibrium based price impact models (a project with Peter Bank; David German) and model s completion with options (Davis and Obloj). 6 / 19

Diffusion framework The random variables ψ = S 1 and ζ = const dq dp 1 ζ G(X 1 )e β(t,xt)dt, ψ j F j 1 (X 1 )e αj (t,x t)dt + 1 + where Y t E[ζ F t ] and 1 are given by f j (t, X t )e αj (s,x s)ds dt g j (t, X t ) e (αj (s,x s)+β(s,x s))ds dt, j = 1,..., J, Y t F j, G : R d R and f j, g j, α j, β : [, 1] R d R are deterministic functions; X = (X i t ) is a d-dimensional diffusion: X t = X + b(s, X s )ds + σ(s, X s )dw s, t [, 1], with drift and volatility functions b i, σ ij : [, 1] R d R. 7 / 19

Assumptions on functions 1. The functions F j = F j (x) and G = G(x) are weakly differentiable and have exponential growth: 2. The Jacobian matrix F j + G Ne N x. ( F j x i ) the Lebesgue measure on R d. has rank d almost surely under 3. The maps t e N f j (t, ) ( e N x f j (t, x) ) x R d, t e N g j (t, ) and t α j (t, ), t β(t, ) of [, 1] to L are analytic on (, 1) and Hölder continuous on [, 1]. Careful with item 3: stronger than pointwise analyticity! Seems to be overlooked in the cited literature. 8 / 19

Assumptions on the diffusion X 1. The map t b i (t, ) of [, 1] to L is analytic on (, 1) and Hölder continuous on [, 1]. 2. The map t σ ij (t, ) of [, 1] to C is analytic on (, 1) and Hölder continuous on [, 1]. Moreover, σ = σ(t, x) is uniformly continuous with respect to x: σ(t, x) σ(t, y) ω( x y ). for some strictly increasing function ω = (ω(ɛ)) ɛ> such that ω(ɛ) as ɛ, and has a bounded inverse: σ 1 (t, x) N (uniform ellipticity for σσ ). Counter-example on t-analyticity condition in σ = σ(t, x). 9 / 19

Main result Theorem Assume that F = F X. Under the conditions above the martingale representation property holds for the probability measure Q with the density and the Q-martingale dq dp ζ E[ζ], S t E Q [ψ F t ], t [, 1]. 1 / 19

Comparison with the literature Assumptions on functions: In Anderson and Raimondo (28), Hugonnier et al. (212), and Riedel and Herzberg (212) The Jacobian matrix ( F j x i ) needs to have full rank only on some open set (counter-example in our setting). The small letter functions, that is, the functions of (t, x) should be (t, x)-analytic. Assumptions on diffusion X : In Anderson and Raimondo (28) X is a Brownian motion. In Hugonnier et al. (212) the diffusion coefficients b = b(t, x) and σ = σ(t, x) are either analytic with respect to (t, x) or the transitional probability is C 7. 11 / 19

Idea of the proof when P = Q ψ j F j 1 (X 1 )e αj (t,x t)dt + Ito s formula implies that 1 St j E[ψ j F t ] = e αj (s,x s)ds u j (t, X t )+ e αj (s,x s)ds f j (t, X t )dt, j = 1,..., J. where u j = u j (t, x) solves the parabolic equation: u j t + (L(t) + α j )u j + f j =, u j (T, x) = F j (x). Here L(t) the infinitesimal generator of X : L(t) = 1 2 d (σσ ) ij 2 (t, x) x i x j + i,j=1 r e αj (s,x s)ds f j (r, X r )dr, d i=1 b i (t, x) x i. 12 / 19

Idea of the proof when P = Q Our assumptions imply that 1. u j (t, ) F j as t T in Sobolev s spaces W 1 p for all p > 1. 2. t u j (t, ) is an analytic map of (, 1) to W 2 p. It follows that (t, x) det u x (t, x) is 1. continuous on [, 1] R d ; 2. t-analytic on (, 1); 3. det u x (1, x) = det F x (x), x R d a.s. Then det u x (t, x) on [, 1] R d a.s.. As s S t = u(, X ) + e α(r,xr )dr u x (s, X s )σ(s, X s )dw s, we deduce that every martingale is a stochastic integral under S. 13 / 19

Elements of the proof Parabolic PDEs: Evolution equations in L p spaces (maximal regularity, analyticity theorem by Kato and Tanabe). Elliptic equations in Sobolev spaces (sectoriality property). Interpolation theory (W 1 p is the midpoint of L p and W 2 p in complex interpolation). Stochastic Analysis: Krylov s variant of Ito s formula (instead of C 2 we can have W 2 p with p d under the uniform ellipticity condition). 14 / 19

Counter-example on t-analyticity in σ = σ(t, x) X t = X + b(s, X s )ds + σ(s, X s )dw s, t [, 1]. Recall that b = b(t, x) and σ = σ(t, x) have only minimal classical regularity conditions with respect to x; very strong analyticity assumptions with respect to t. We gave an explicit (!) example which shows that the t-analyticity assumption on the volatility matrix can not be removed. In our construction, dimension d = J = 2 (will not work for d = 1) both σ and its inverse σ 1 are C -matrices on [, 1] R 2 which are bounded with all their derivatives and have analytic restrictions to [, 1 2 ) R2 and ( 1 2, 1] R2. 15 / 19

Counter-example on t-analyticity in σ = σ(t, x) g = g(t) is a C -function on [, 1] which equals on [, 1 2 ], while it is analytic and strictly positive on ( 1 2, 1]. h = h(t, y) is an analytic function on [, 1] R such that h 1, h(1, ) const, and For instance, we can take h t + 1 2 h 2 y 2 =. h(t, y) = 1 t 1 (1 + e 2 sin y). 2 2-dimensional diffusion (X, Y ) on [, 1]: X t = 1 + g(s)h(s, Ys )db s, Y t = W t, where B and W are independent Brownian motions. 16 / 19

Counter-example on t-analyticity in σ = σ(t, x) Set where Q = P, ψ = (F (X 1, Y 1 ), H(X 1, Y 1 )), F (x, y) = x, H(x, y) = x 2 1 h(1, y) 1 g(t)dt. The determinant of the Jacobian matrix for (F, H): F H x y F H y x = h (1, y) y as h(1, ) is non-constant and analytic. 1 g(t)dt, 17 / 19

Counter-example on t-analyticity in σ = σ(t, x) Ito s formula shows that S t E[F (X 1, Y 1 ) F t ] = X t, R t E[H(X 1, Y 1 ) F t ] = X 2 t t h(t, Y t ) As g(t) = for t [, 1 2 ], it follows that on [, 1 2 ] S t = B t, R t = B 2 t t. g(s)ds, Clearly, the Brownian motion Y = W can not be written as a stochastic integral with respect to (S, R). 18 / 19

Summary We gave conditions on diffusion X and functions F j, G, α j, β = β(t, x), and f j, g j so that the integral representation holds for the measure Q and the Q-martingale S = (S j ) defined by dq/dp = const ζ and S j 1 = ψj, where 1 ζ G(X 1 )e β(t,xt)dt, ψ j F j 1 (X 1 )e αj (t,x t)dt + 1 + and Y t E[ζ F t ]. 1 f j (t, X t )e αj (s,x s)ds dt g j (t, X t ) e (αj (s,x s)+β(s,x s))ds dt, j = 1,..., J, Y t The diffusion coefficients of X have only minimal x-regularity. However, they are t-analytical (a counter-example for σ). The study is motivated by the problem of endogenous completeness in financial economics. 19 / 19