Granular Comparative Advantage

Similar documents
Granular Comparative Advantage

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 3: Gravity Models

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Melitz, M. J. & G. I. P. Ottaviano. Peter Eppinger. July 22, 2011

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms

International Trade Lecture 16: Gravity Models (Theory)

Measuring the Gains from Trade: They are Large!

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 15: Gravity Models (Theory)

International Prices and Exchange Rates Econ 2530b, Gita Gopinath

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

Eaton Kortum Model (2002)

Import Protection as Export Destruction

Cross-Country Differences in Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selection

Internation1al Trade

For Online Publication Online Appendix to: Merger Policy in a Quantitative Model of International Trade

THE GAINS FROM INPUT TRADE WITH HETEROGENEOUS IMPORTERS

Estimating the effect of exchange rate changes on total exports

Schumpeterian Growth Models

Addendum to: International Trade, Technology, and the Skill Premium

Global Production with Export Platforms

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 4 Competition and Innovation

Consumption-led Growth

International Trade. Lecture 4: the extensive margin of trade. Thomas Chaney. Sciences Po. Thomas Chaney (Sciences Po) International Trade 1 / 17

Trade and Inequality: From Theory to Estimation

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress

Trade, Neoclassical Growth and Heterogeneous Firms

Trade Policies, Firm Heterogeneity, and Variable Markups

Economic Development and the Spatial Allocation of Labor: Evidence From Indonesia. Gharad Bryan (LSE) Melanie Morten (Stanford) May 19, 2015

Gravity Models and the Armington Assumption

Trade and Domestic Policy in Models with Monopolistic Competition

Web Appendix for Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Not for Publication)

Non-Homothetic Gravity

PhD Topics in Macroeconomics

Misallocation Under Trade Liberalization

The Origins of Firm Heterogeneity: A Production Network Approach

Prices and Exchange Rates: A Theory of Disconnect

Wages, Unemployment and Inequality with Heterogeneous Firms and Workers

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

External Economies of Scale and Industrial Policy: A View from Trade

The Geography of Development: Evaluating Migration Restrictions and Coastal Flooding

Trade, Inequality and Costly Redistribution

Quality and Gravity in International Trade

The Impact of Trade Liberalization on Industrial Productivity

Global Value Chain Participation and Current Account Imbalances

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Economic Growth: Lecture 9, Neoclassical Endogenous Growth

Trade Models with Heterogeneous Firms: What About Importing?

R&D Investment, Exporting, and Productivity Dynamics

Import Protection as Export Destruction

Lecture #11: Introduction to the New Empirical Industrial Organization (NEIO) -

Technical Appendix. The Steady State

Firm Entry, Trade, and Welfare in Zipf s World

The Elusive Pro-Competitive Effects of Trade

A Theory of Entry into and Exit from Export Markets

Endogenous information acquisition

Estimating the Productivity Gains from Importing [Preliminary - Comments welcome]

Innovation, Firm Dynamics, and International Trade

Imperfect Competition and Misallocations

Equilibrium in Factors Market: Properties

Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure: Slides

Motivation A Figure 1 Figure 2 Table 1 Table 2

Interest Rate Liberalization and Capital Misallocation 1

Class Notes on New Economic Geography Models

Firm-to-Firm Trade: Imports, Exports, and the Labor Market. IEA: Mexico City. Jonathan Eaton, Samuel Kortum, Francis Kramarz.

Essays in Economic Geography and Development. Dominick Gabriel Bartelme. A dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the

The Aggregate Implications of Innovative Investment. September 2017

SELECTION EFFECTS WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS: ONLINE APPENDIX

Technological Spillovers and Dynamics of Comparative Advantage

Market Structure and Productivity: A Concrete Example. Chad Syverson

Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure: Slides

Globalization, Inequality and Welfare

Inequality, Costly Redistribution and Welfare in an Open Economy

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

The Macro Impact of Micro Shocks: Beyond Hulten s Theorem

Trade Costs and Economic Geography: Evidence from the U.S.

Modeling firms locational choice

Monopolistic Competition in Trade III Trade Costs and Gains from Trade

The Gains From Input Trade in Firm-Based Models of Importing

Aggregate Implications of Innovation Policy

Quality Heterogeneity and Misallocation: The Welfare Benefits of Raising your Standards Other VES Preferences

The Matching and Sorting of Exporting and Importing Firms: Theory and Evidence. Felipe Benguria 1. May Abstract

Importing Skill-Biased Technology

Quality and Gravity in International Trade

Competitive Search: A Test of Direction and Efficiency

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

Advanced Microeconomics

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

The Role of the Most Favored Nation Principle of the GATT/WTO in the New Trade Model

Trade, Firm Selection, and Innovation: the Competition Channel

Economies of Scale and Industrial Policy: A View from Trade

14.461: Technological Change, Lectures 7 and 8 Innovation, Reallocation and Growth

Chapter 7. Endogenous Growth II: R&D and Technological Change

Productivity Improvements and Falling Trade Costs: Boon or Bane?

ENTRY, EXIT AND MISALLOCATION FRICTIONS JOB MARKET PAPER 1

CROSS-COUNTRY DIFFERENCES IN PRODUCTIVITY: THE ROLE OF ALLOCATION AND SELECTION

The Extensive Margin of Exporting Products: The Continuum Case

Imported Intermediate Goods and Product Innovation: Evidence from India

Skilled Factor Abundance and Traded Goods Prices

International Trade Lecture 3: Ricardian Theory (II)

Transcription:

Granular Comparative Advantage Cecile Gaubert cecile.gaubert@berkeley.edu Oleg Itskhoki itskhoki@princeton.edu RASA IX International Conference Washington DC November 218 1 / 28

Exports are Granular Freund and Pierola (215): Export Superstars Across 32 developing countries, the largest exporting firm accounts on average for 17% of total manufacturing exports Our focus: French manufacturing Average export share of the largest firm Manufacturing 1 industry 7% 2-digit 23 sectors 18% 3-digit 117 sectors 26% 4-digit 316 sectors 37% 1 / 28

Firm-size distribution is: 1 fat-tailed (Zipf s law) 2 discrete } = Granularity Granularity Canonical example: power law (Pareto) with shape θ < 2 Intuitions from Gaussian world fail, even for very large N a single draw can shape N i=1 X illustration i average can differ from expectation (failure of LLN) 2 / 28

Firm-size distribution is: 1 fat-tailed (Zipf s law) 2 discrete } = Granularity Granularity Canonical example: power law (Pareto) with shape θ < 2 Intuitions from Gaussian world fail, even for very large N a single draw can shape N i=1 X illustration i average can differ from expectation (failure of LLN) Most common application: aggregate fluctuations Gabaix (211), di Giovanni and Levchenko (212) The role of granularity for comparative advantage of countries is a natural question, yet has not been explored Can a few firms shape country-sector specialization? 2 / 28

Trade Models Trade models acknowledge fat-tailed-ness but not discreteness emphasis on firms, but each firm is infinitesimal (LLN applies) hence, no role of individual firms in shaping sectoral aggregates Exceptions with discrete number of firms 1 One-sector model of Eaton, Kortum and Sotelo (EKS, 212) 2 Literature on competition/markups (e.g., AB 28, EMX 214, AIK 214, Neary 215) 3 / 28

Trade Models Trade models acknowledge fat-tailed-ness but not discreteness emphasis on firms, but each firm is infinitesimal (LLN applies) hence, no role of individual firms in shaping sectoral aggregates Exceptions with discrete number of firms 1 One-sector model of Eaton, Kortum and Sotelo (EKS, 212) 2 Literature on competition/markups (e.g., AB 28, EMX 214, AIK 214, Neary 215) Our focus: can granularity explain sectoral trade patterns? 1 sector-level comparative advantage (like DFS) 2 firm heterogeneity within sectors (like Melitz) 3 granularity within sectors (like EKS) relax the LLN assumption in a multi-sector Melitz model take seriously that a typical French sector has 35 firms with the largest firm commanding a 2% market share 3 / 28

Granularity Our approach percentiles draws T(z) Productivity draws, ϕ 4 / 28

Granularity Our approach percentiles draws T(z) Productivity draws, ϕ Fundamental vs Granular 4 / 28

Granularity Our approach percentiles draws T(z) Productivity draws, ϕ Fundamental vs Granular: Why do we care? 4 / 28

Roadmap: This paper 1 Basic framework with granular comparative advantage 2 GE Estimation Procedure SMM using French firm-level data 3 Explore implications of the estimated granular model many continuous-world intuitions fail dynamic counterfactuals 5 / 28

Roadmap: This paper 1 Basic framework with granular comparative advantage 2 GE Estimation Procedure SMM using French firm-level data 3 Explore implications of the estimated granular model many continuous-world intuitions fail dynamic counterfactuals Highlights of the results from the estimated model: 1 A parsimonious granular model fits many empirical patterns. Moments of firm-size distribution explain trade patterns 2 Granularity accounts for 2% of variation in export shares most export-intensive sectors tend to be granular 3 Granularity can explain much of the mean reversion in CA more granular sectors are more volatile death of a single firm can alter considerably the CA 4 Policy in a granular economy: mergers and tariffs 5 / 28

Modeling Framework 6 / 28

Model Structure 1 Two countries: Home and Foreign inelastically-supplied labor L and L 2 Continuum of sectors z [, 1]: { 1 } Q = exp α z log Q z dz 3 Sectors vary in comparative advantage: T z /T z N (µ T, σ T ) 6 / 28

1 Two countries: Home and Foreign inelastically-supplied labor L and L Model Structure 2 Continuum of sectors z [, 1]: { 1 } Q = exp α z log Q z dz 3 Sectors vary in comparative advantage: T z /T z N (µ T, σ T ) 4 Within a sector, a finite number of firms (varieties) K z : Q z = [ Kz i=1 q σ 1 σ z,i ] σ σ 1 5 Each sector has an EKS market structure 6 / 28

Productivity draws in a given sector z: Number of (shadow) entrants: Poisson ( M z ) Entrants productivity draws: Pareto ( θ; ϕ z ) EKS Sectors Denote N ϕ number of firms with productivity ϕ N ϕ Poisson ( T z ϕ θ), T z M z ϕ θ z with T z /T z shaping sector-level CA 7 / 28

Productivity draws in a given sector z: Number of (shadow) entrants: Poisson ( M z ) Entrants productivity draws: Pareto ( θ; ϕ z ) EKS Sectors Denote N ϕ number of firms with productivity ϕ N ϕ Poisson ( T z ϕ θ), T z M z ϕ θ z with T z /T z shaping sector-level CA Marginal cost: c = w/ϕ at home and τw/ϕ abroad Fixed cost of production and exports: F in local labor 7 / 28

Productivity draws in a given sector z: Number of (shadow) entrants: Poisson ( M z ) Entrants productivity draws: Pareto ( θ; ϕ z ) EKS Sectors Denote N ϕ number of firms with productivity ϕ N ϕ Poisson ( T z ϕ θ), T z M z ϕ θ z with T z /T z shaping sector-level CA Marginal cost: c = w/ϕ at home and τw/ϕ abroad Fixed cost of production and exports: F in local labor Oligopolistic (Bertrand) competition and variable markups Atkeson-Burstein (28): {c i } {s i, µ i, p i } Kz i=1 show 7 / 28

Market Entry and GE Assumption: sequential entry in increasing order of unit cost [ w/ϕ c 1 < c 2 <... < c K <..., where c i = i, if Home, τw /ϕ i, if Foreign unique equilibrium Profits: Π i = s i ε(s i ) α zy wf 8 / 28

Market Entry and GE Assumption: sequential entry in increasing order of unit cost [ w/ϕ c 1 < c 2 <... < c K <..., where c i = i, if Home, τw /ϕ i, if Foreign unique equilibrium Profits: Π i = s i ε(s i ) α zy wf Entry: Π K K and ΠK+1 K+1 < determines K z 8 / 28

Market Entry and GE Assumption: sequential entry in increasing order of unit cost [ w/ϕ c 1 < c 2 <... < c K <..., where c i = i, if Home, τw /ϕ i, if Foreign unique equilibrium Profits: Π i = s i ε(s i ) α zy wf Entry: Π K K and ΠK+1 K+1 < determines K z General equilibrium: GE vector X = (Y, Y, w, w ) Within-sector allocations Z = { } K z, {s z,i } Kz i=1 z [,1] Labor market clearing and trade balance (linear in X) Fast iterative algorithm 8 / 28

Estimation and Model Fit 9 / 28

Estimation procedure Data: French firm-level data (BRN) and Trade data Firm-level domestic sales and export sales Aggregate import data (Comtrade) 119 4-digit manufacturing sectors Parametrize sector-level comparative advantage: T (z)/t (z) log N (µ T, σ T ) Based on empirical distribution shown in Hanson et al. (215) Stage 1: calibrate Cobb-Douglas shares {α z } and w/w CD shares read from domestic sales + imports, by sector w/w = 1.13, trade-weighted wage of France s trade partners Normalizations: w = 1 and L = 1 Stage 2: SMM procedure to estimate {σ, θ, τ, F, µ T, σ T }, while (Y, Y, L /L) are pinned down by GE 9 / 28

Estimated Parameters Parameter Estimate Std. error Auxiliary variables σ 5 κ = θ θ 4.37.246 σ 1 1.77 τ 1.341.61 w/w 1.13 F ( 1 5 ).946.252 L /L 1.724 µ T.137.193 Y /Y 1.526 σ T 1.422.232 Π/Y.211 1 / 28

Moment Fit Moments Data, ˆm Model, M( ˆΘ) Loss (%) 1. Log number of firms, mean log M 5.631 5.624.1 2. st. dev. z 1.451 1.222 7.9 3. Top-firm market share, mean.197.26 3.5 s 4. st. dev. z,1.178.149 3.8 5. Top-3 market share, mean 3 j=1 s.356.343 2. z,j 6. st. dev..241.175 11.5 7. Imports/dom. sales, mean Λ z.365.351 2.2 8. st. dev..24.268 14.8 9. Exports/dom. sales, mean Λ.328.35 6. 1. st. dev. z.286.346 6.5 Fraction of sectors with { } 11. P Xz > exports>dom. sales.185.92 37.9 Ỹz X z Regression coefficients 12. export share on top-firm share ˆb 1.215.243 2.6 (.156) (.14) 13. export share on top-3 share ˆb 3.254.232 1.1 (.18) (.9) 14. import share on top-firm share ˆb 1.16.2. (.97) (.79) 15. export share on top-3 share ˆb 3.2.5.1 (.74) (.69) show id 11 / 28

(a) Number of French firms (b) Top market share.3 Data Model 4.2 3 2.1 1 1 1 1 1 1.1.2.3.4.5 (c) Domestic import share (d) Pareto shape of sales.8 3.6 2.4.2 1.1.1.5 1.5 1 1.5 2 12 / 28

Non-targeted Moments Correlation between top market share and number of firms: s z,1 = const + γ M log M z + γ Y log Ỹ z + ɛ s z Data:.94.18 (.8) (.8) Model:.64.25 (.7) (.6) Extensive margin of sales: log M z = c d + χ d Data:.563 (.82) Model:.861 (.11) log(ỹ z X z ) + ɛ d z 13 / 28

1.4 Equilibrium markups 1.35 1.3 1.25 Other Top 4 Top 3 Top 2 Top firm Oligopolistic (Bertrand) markups: averages (blue bars) and 1 9% range (red intervals) across industry σ Monopolistic competition markup: all oligopolistic markups σ 1 = 1.25 is lower bound for 14 / 28

Quantifying Granular Trade 15 / 28

Foreign share: Properties of the Granular Model Λ z X z α z Y = K z i=1 (1 ι z,i)s z,i Expected foreign share: { } T Φ z = E Λ z z T = z Granular residual: 1 1 + (τω) θ Tz T z Γ z Λ z Φ z : E T {Γ z } = E T {Λ z Φ z } = Aggregate exports: X = Y 1 α z Λ z dz = ΦY, Φ 1 α z Φ z dz 15 / 28

Decomposition of Trade Flows Variance decomposition of X z = Λ zα z Y with Λ z = Φ z + Γ z: var(λ z) = var(φ z) + var(γ z), var(log X z ) var(log α z ) + var(log Λ z) Table: Variance decomposition of trade flows Granular contribution Export share contribution Common θ Sector-specific θ z (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) var(γ z ) var(λ z ) 17.% 22.3% 26.% 28.4% 2.3% var(log Λ z ) var(log X z ) 57.2% 59.2% 62.5% 63.9% 59.% Pareto shape parameter κ z = θz σ 1 1.8 1. 1.2.96 1.15 Estimated Pareto shape ˆκ z 1.1 1.2 1.7 1.2 1.21 Top-firm market share s z,1.21.25.26.29.21 show fit 16 / 28

Export Intensity and Granularity Granularity does not create additional trade on average Yet, granularity creates skewness across sectors in exports most export-intensive sectors are likely of granular origin.25.2 (a) Fraction of granular sectors 1/4 Granular 1/3 Granular 1/2 Granular (b) Granular contribution to trade.3 Export share Granular exports.15.2.1.1.5.2.4.7.1.15.21.29.4.58 1 Deciles of sectors, by export intensity Λ z -.5.2.4.7.1.15.21.29.4.58 1 Deciles of sectors, by export intensity Λ z 17 / 28

Export Intensity and Granularity Granularity does not create additional trade on average Yet, granularity creates skewness across sectors in exports most export-intensive sectors are likely of granular origin (a) Distribution of Λ z Φ z (b) Distribution of Φ z Λ z 1 p5 p75 p9 p95 p99 1 p5 p75 p9 p95 p99.8.8.6.6.4.4.2.2.2.4.6.8 1.2.4.6.8 1 17 / 28

Properties of Granular Exports Γ z = Λ z Φ z are orthogonal with Φ z, log(α z Y ) and log M z Best predictor of Γ z is s z,1, the relative size of the largest firm Table: Projections of granular exports Γ z (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) s z,1.335.373.379.357.354 s z,1.254.268 log M z.8.12.16.11 log(α z Y ).5.13 Φ z.4.73 R 2.13.353.375.376.52.539 18 / 28

Identifying Granular Sectors Which sectors are granular? Neither Φ z, nor Γ z are observable P{Γ z ϑλ z Λ Λ z, r z } = z Φ ϑλ g( Φ z, Λ ) z, r z dφ z z 1 g( ), Φ z, Λ z, r z dφ z 19 / 28

Dynamics of Comparative Advantage 2 / 28

Dynamic Model Use the granular model with firm dynamics to study the implied time-series properties of aggregate trade Shadow pull of firms in each sector with productivities {ϕ it } Productivity of the firms follows a random growth process: log ϕ it = µ + log ϕ i,t 1 + νε it, ε it iidn (, 1) with reflection from the lower bound ϕ and µ= θν 2 /2 Each period: static entry game and price setting equilibrium Calibrate idiosyncratic firm dynamics (volatility of shocks ν) using the dynamic properties of market shares No aggregate shocks 2 / 28

Firm Dynamics and CA Empirical evidence in Hanson, Lind and Muendler (215): 1 Hyperspecialization of exports 2 High Turnover of export-intensive sectors Moment Data HLM France Model SR persistence std( s z,i,t+1 ).18.17 LR persistence corr( s z,i,t+1, s z,i,t ).86.83 Top-1% sectors export share 21% 17% 18% Top-3% sectors export share 43% 3% 33% Turnover I: remain in top-5% after 2 years 52% 71% Turnover II: remain in top-5% after 1 years 8% 79% Idiosyncratic firm productivity dynamics explains the majority of turnover of top exporting sectors over time show more 21 / 28

Mean Reversion in CA Idiosyncratic firm dynamics in a granular model predicts mean reversion in comparative advantage In addition, granular sectors are more volatile (a) Mean reversion in Λ z (b) Volatility of Λ z Expected change in export share, Λ z.4.2 -.2 -.4 -.6 5 years 2 years Variation in export share, std( Λ z).6.5.4.3.2.1 -.8-1 -.38 -.24 -.14 -.7.4.13.24.42 1 Deciles of sectors, by granular Γ z -1 -.38 -.24 -.14 -.7.4.13.24.42 1 Deciles of sectors, by granular Γ z 22 / 28

Death of a Large Firm Death (sequence of negative productivity shocks) of a single firm can substantially affect sectoral comparative advantage In the most granular sectors, death of a single firm can push the sector from top-5% of CA into comparative disadvantage.4 Top firm share Loss in export share.3.2.1-1 -.8 -.4 -.1.1.3.6.9.13.21 1 Deciles of sectors, by granular Γ z show more 23 / 28

Granularity and reallocation Sectoral labor allocation: L z L α z + θ NX z σκ 1 Y Interaction between trade openness and granularity results in sectoral reallocation and aggregate volatility Figure: Total and Sectoral Labor Reallocation (fraction of total L) 24 / 28

Policy Counterfactuals 25 / 28

Policy counterfactuals 1 Misallocation and trade policy policies that hinder growth of granular firms why trade barriers often target individual foreign firm? 2 Merger analysis 25 / 28

Policy counterfactuals 1 Misallocation and trade policy policies that hinder growth of granular firms why trade barriers often target individual foreign firm? 2 Merger analysis Welfare analysis of a policy: Ŵ d log Y P = wl dtr d log w + Y Y + 1 and across sectors Ŵ = 1 α zŵzdz In partial equilibrium: Ŵ z = α z dπ z α z Y dz dtrz +dπz α z Y 1 d log P z α z d log P z dz In general equilibrium: spillovers to other sectors via (w, Y ) 25 / 28

Merger Merger is more beneficial: 1 The larger is the productivity spillover ϱ ϕ z,2 = ϱϕ z,1 + (1 ϱ)ϕ z,2. Baseline ϱ =.5. For low ϱ =.1 2 The more open is the economy τ 3 The more granular is the sector Γ z click (a) Welfare effect of a merger, Ŵ Z (b) Decomposition of Ŵ Z, τ =1.34 2.5% 2% 1.5% 1%.5% Baseline τ =1.34 Low τ =1 High τ =2.68 3% Baseline ŴZ Profits d Π/Y Price dlog P 2% 1% % % -1% -.5% 1 2 3 4 5 Quintiles of sectors by granular Γ z -2% 1 2 3 4 5 Quintiles of sectors by granular Γ z 26 / 28

Import Tariff Tariff on the top importer ς z,1 vs a uniform import tariff ς z yielding the same tariff revenue ς z,1 ς z, particularly in the foreign granular industries (Γ z ) (a) Uniform tariff (b) Granular tariff.6%.4% Overall welfare Tariff revenue Producer surplus Consumer surplus.6%.4% Overall welfare Tariff revenue Producer surplus Consumer surplus.2%.2% % % -.2% -.2% 1 2 3 4 5 Quintiles of sectors by import granularity Γz 1 2 3 4 5 Quintiles of sectors by import granularity Γz 27 / 28

Conclusion 28 / 28

Conclusion The world is granular! (at least, at the sectoral level) We better develop tools and intuitions to deal with it Applications: 1 Innovation, growth and development 2 Misallocation 3 Industrial policy 4 Cities and agglomeration 28 / 28

APPENDIX 29 / 28

Granularity Illustration The role of top draw, as the number of draws N increases ( corr max i X i, ) X i i max i X i i X i 1 1.8.8.6.6.4.4.2.2 1 2 1 1 1 1 Number of draws 1 2 1 1 1 1 Number of draws back to slides 3 / 28

Sectoral equilibrium Sectoral equilibrium system: p i = µ i c i, µ i = ε i ε i 1 where ε i = σ(1 s i ) + s i, s i = ( pi ) ( 1 σ K ) 1/(1 σ) where P = P i=1 p1 σ i. back to slides 31 / 28

6.5 (a) Number of French firms F θ τ µt σt.3 (b) Top French firm share F θ τ µt σt 6.25 5.5.2 5-1 -.5.5 1.15-1 -.5.5 1.5 (c) Domestic import share F θ τ µt σt (d) Export projection coefficient.5 F θ τ µt σt.4.4.3.3.2.1.2-1 -.5.5 1-1 -.5.5 1 32 / 28

(a) Pareto shape, κ z = θz σ 1 (b) Estimated Pareto, ˆκ z 1.5 1 κ 1.2 H1 H2 H3 1.5 Data H1 H2 H3 1.5.5.5 1 1.5 2.5 1 1.5 2 (c) Top-firm sales share, s z,1 (d) Number of firms, M z.4 4.3 3 2.2 1.1.1.2.3.4.5 1 1 1 1 1 back 33 / 28

Probability a sector remains among top-5% of export-intensive sectors 1.9.8.7.6.5 T = 1 2 3 4 5 T, years back 34 / 28

Trade effects of individual firm exit (a) All sectors, deciles of Γ z (b) All sectors, deciles of Λ z.3.25 Top firm share Loss in export share.25.2 Top firm share Loss in export share.2.15.15.1.1.5.5-1 -.8 -.5 -.3 -.2 -.1 -.1.4.1 1 Deciles of sectors, by granular Γ z.2.4.7.1.15.21.29.41.58 1 Deciles of sectors, by export share Λ z back 35 / 28

Merger Low spillover ϱ =.1.5% % Welfare effect of a merger, Ŵ Z Baseline τ =1.34 Low τ =1 High τ =2.68 4% 3% 2% Decomposition of Ŵ Z, τ = 1.34 Baseline ŴZ Profits d Π/Y Price dlog P 1% % -.5% -1% -2% -1% 1 2 3 4 5 Quintiles of sectors by granular Γ z -3% 1 2 3 4 5 Quintiles of sectors by granular Γ z back 36 / 28