The Geometric Meaning of the Notion of Joint Unpredictability of a Bivariate VAR(1) Stochastic Process

Similar documents
Econ 423 Lecture Notes: Additional Topics in Time Series 1

Unit Root Tests: The Role of the Univariate Models Implied by Multivariate Time Series

Measuring the Distance between Sets of ARMA Models

Introduction to Algorithmic Trading Strategies Lecture 3

ISSN Article

The PPP Hypothesis Revisited

A Non-Parametric Approach of Heteroskedasticity Robust Estimation of Vector-Autoregressive (VAR) Models

On the Error Correction Model for Functional Time Series with Unit Roots

Questions and Answers on Unit Roots, Cointegration, VARs and VECMs

ECON 7335 INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS IN MACRO LECTURE 1: BASICS. 1. Bayes Rule. p(b j A)p(A) p(b)

Lecture Notes 1: Vector spaces

Lecture 2: Univariate Time Series

Multivariate forecasting with VAR models

Projection Theorem 1

Empirical Market Microstructure Analysis (EMMA)

Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo

STAT 151A: Lab 1. 1 Logistics. 2 Reference. 3 Playing with R: graphics and lm() 4 Random vectors. Billy Fang. 2 September 2017

Econ 424 Time Series Concepts

A TIME SERIES PARADOX: UNIT ROOT TESTS PERFORM POORLY WHEN DATA ARE COINTEGRATED

Lecture 5: Unit Roots, Cointegration and Error Correction Models The Spurious Regression Problem

Stable Process. 2. Multivariate Stable Distributions. July, 2006

Convolution Based Unit Root Processes: a Simulation Approach

11. Further Issues in Using OLS with TS Data

Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme?

7. Integrated Processes

Multivariate Time Series Analysis and Its Applications [Tsay (2005), chapter 8]

STA441: Spring Multiple Regression. This slide show is a free open source document. See the last slide for copyright information.

7. Integrated Processes

[y i α βx i ] 2 (2) Q = i=1

Orthogonal Projection and Least Squares Prof. Philip Pennance 1 -Version: December 12, 2016

ECON 4160, Lecture 11 and 12

1 Regression with Time Series Variables

Multivariate Time Series

10) Time series econometrics

Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics & Econometrics

Bootstrapping the Grainger Causality Test With Integrated Data

Lakehead University ECON 4117/5111 Mathematical Economics Fall 2003

Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme?

A Simple Computational Approach to the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing

COMMON COMPLEMENTS OF TWO SUBSPACES OF A HILBERT SPACE

More Powerful Tests for Homogeneity of Multivariate Normal Mean Vectors under an Order Restriction

Cointegration, Stationarity and Error Correction Models.

Departamento de Estadfstica y Econometrfa Statistics and Econometrics Series 27. Universidad Carlos III de Madrid December 1993 Calle Madrid, 126

Vector Auto-Regressive Models

Vector spaces. DS-GA 1013 / MATH-GA 2824 Optimization-based Data Analysis.

Econometrics. Week 11. Fall Institute of Economic Studies Faculty of Social Sciences Charles University in Prague

VAR Models and Applications

Comment On The Interpretation of Instrumental Variables in the Presence of Specification Errors: A Causal Comment

Consistent Bivariate Distribution

The distribution of a sum of dependent risks: a geometric-combinatorial approach

Multivariate Time Series: VAR(p) Processes and Models

9) Time series econometrics

When Do Wold Orderings and Long-Run Recursive Identifying Restrictions Yield Identical Results?

Unit Roots in White Noise?!

Lecture 1: Systems of linear equations and their solutions

13. Time Series Analysis: Asymptotics Weakly Dependent and Random Walk Process. Strict Exogeneity

Cointegrated VAR s. Eduardo Rossi University of Pavia. November Rossi Cointegrated VAR s Financial Econometrics / 56

It is easily seen that in general a linear combination of y t and x t is I(1). However, in particular cases, it can be I(0), i.e. stationary.

1 Linear Difference Equations

Stock Prices, News, and Economic Fluctuations: Comment

Inner Product, Length, and Orthogonality

University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series

MA 575 Linear Models: Cedric E. Ginestet, Boston University Revision: Probability and Linear Algebra Week 1, Lecture 2

Cointegration between Trends and Their Estimators in State Space Models and Cointegrated Vector Autoregressive Models

Notes on Time Series Modeling

Multivariate Least Weighted Squares (MLWS)

INVARIANT SUBSPACES FOR CERTAIN FINITE-RANK PERTURBATIONS OF DIAGONAL OPERATORS. Quanlei Fang and Jingbo Xia

DS-GA 1002 Lecture notes 0 Fall Linear Algebra. These notes provide a review of basic concepts in linear algebra.

Hilbert Spaces: Infinite-Dimensional Vector Spaces

1 Quantitative Techniques in Practice

Exogeneity and Causality

ECON 4160, Spring term Lecture 12

Linear Regression. Junhui Qian. October 27, 2014

Problem set 1 - Solutions

Cointegrated VARIMA models: specification and. simulation

APPLIED TIME SERIES ECONOMETRICS

The autocorrelation and autocovariance functions - helpful tools in the modelling problem

Financial Econometrics

(I AL BL 2 )z t = (I CL)ζ t, where

Prof. Dr. Roland Füss Lecture Series in Applied Econometrics Summer Term Introduction to Time Series Analysis

Linear Algebra Massoud Malek

7 Introduction to Time Series Time Series vs. Cross-Sectional Data Detrending Time Series... 15

Econ 2148, fall 2017 Gaussian process priors, reproducing kernel Hilbert spaces, and Splines

9. Multivariate Linear Time Series (II). MA6622, Ernesto Mordecki, CityU, HK, 2006.

Lecture 5: Unit Roots, Cointegration and Error Correction Models The Spurious Regression Problem

Volume 30, Issue 1. The relationship between the F-test and the Schwarz criterion: Implications for Granger-causality tests

Time Series 2. Robert Almgren. Sept. 21, 2009

Final Exam November 24, Problem-1: Consider random walk with drift plus a linear time trend: ( t

The regression model with one stochastic regressor (part II)

10. Time series regression and forecasting

Subset-Continuous-Updating GMM Estimators for Dynamic Panel Data Models

ACE 562 Fall Lecture 2: Probability, Random Variables and Distributions. by Professor Scott H. Irwin

Title. Description. var intro Introduction to vector autoregressive models

Geometric interpretation of signals: background

Lecture 3: Multiple Regression

Simultaneous Equation Models Learning Objectives Introduction Introduction (2) Introduction (3) Solving the Model structural equations

Ch. 15 Forecasting. 1.1 Forecasts Based on Conditional Expectations

On Least Squares Linear Regression Without Second Moment

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

The Game of Normal Numbers

Transcription:

Econometrics 2013, 3, 207-216; doi:10.3390/econometrics1030207 OPEN ACCESS econometrics ISSN 2225-1146 www.mdpi.com/journal/econometrics Article The Geometric Meaning of the Notion of Joint Unpredictability of a Bivariate VAR(1) Stochastic Process Umberto Triacca Department of Computer Engineering, Computer Science Mathematics, University of L Aquila, Via Vetoio I-67010 Coppito, L Aquila, I-67100, Italy; E-Mail: umberto.triacca@ec.univaq.it; Tel.: +39-086-2 43-4849, Fax.: +39-086-243-4407 Received: 21 August 2013; in revised form: 5 November 2013 / Accepted: 5 November 2013 / Published: 14 November 2013 Abstract: This paper investigates, in a particular parametric framework, the geometric meaning of joint unpredictability for a bivariate discrete process. In particular, the paper provides a characterization of the joint unpredictability in terms of distance between information sets in an Hilbert space. Keywords: Hilbert spaces; predictability; stochastic process JEL Classification: C18; C32 1. Introduction Let (Ω, F, P ) be a probability space {y t y 1,t, y 2,t ; t 0, 1,...} a bivariate stochastic process defined on (Ω, F, P ). We consider the differenced process { y t y 1,t, y 2,t ; t 1,...}, where is the first-difference operator. Following Caporale Pittis 1 Hassapis et al. 2, we say that the process { y t ; t 1,...} is jointly unpredictable if E( y t+1 σ(y t,..., y 0 )) 0 t (1) where σ(y t,..., y 0 ) is the σ-field generated by past vectors y i i 0,..., t. The goal of this paper is to show that the notion of joint unpredictability, in a particular parametric framework, can be characterized by a geometric condition. This characterization is given in terms of distance between information sets in an Hilbert space. In particular, we will show that the process { y t ; t 1,...} is jointly unpredictable if only if the information contained in its past is much

Econometrics 2013, 3 208 distant from the information contained in its future. Even if our result is not as general as might seem desirable, we think that the intuition gained from this characterization makes the notion of joint unpredictability more clear. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the utilized mathematical framework. Sections 3 presents the geometric characterization. Section 4 concludes. 2. Preliminaries Definitions, notation, preliminary results from Hilbert space theory will be presented prior to establish the main result. An excellent overviews of the applications of Hilbert space methods to time series analysis can be found in Brockwell Davis 3. We use the following notations symbols. Let (Ω, F, P ) be a probability space. We consider the Hilbert space L 2 (Ω, F, P ) of all real square integrable rom variables on (Ω, F, P ). The inner product in L 2 (Ω, F, P ) is defined by z, w E(zw) for any z, w L 2 (Ω, F, P ). The space L 2 (Ω, F, P ) is a normed space the norm is given by w E(w 2 ) 1/2. The distance between z,w L 2 (Ω, F, P ) is d(z,w) z w. A sequence {z n } L 2 (Ω, F, P ) is said to converge to a limit point z L 2 (Ω, F, P ) if d(z n, z) 0 as n. A point z L 2 (Ω, F, P ) is a limit point of a set M (subset of L 2 (Ω, F, P )) if it is a limit point of a sequence from M. In particular, M is said to be closed if it contains all its limit points. If S is a arbitrary subset of L 2 (Ω, F, P ), then the set of all α 1 z 1 +... + α h z h (h 1, 2,...; α 1,..., α h arbitrary real numbers; z 1,..., z h arbitrary elements of S) is called a linear manifold spanned by S is symbolized by sp(s). If we add to sp(s) all its limit points we obtain a closed set that we call the closed linear manifold or subspace spanned by S, symbolized by sp(s). Two elements z, w L 2 are called orthogonal, we write z w, if z, w 0. If S is any subset of L 2 (Ω, F, P ), then we write x S if x s for all s S; similarly, the notation S T, for two subsets S T of L 2 (Ω, F, P ), indicates that all elements of S are orthogonal to all elements of T. For a given z L 2 (Ω, F, P ) a closed subspace M of L 2 (Ω, F, P ), we define the orthogonal projection of z on M, denoted by P (z M), as the unique element of M such that z P (z M) z w for any w M. We remember that if z M, then P (z M) 0. If M N are two arbitrary subsets of L 2 (Ω, F, P ), then the quantity d (M, N) inf { m n ; m M, n N} is called distance between M N. We close this section introducing some further definitions, concerning discrete stochastic processes in L 2 (Ω, F, P ). Let {x t } be a univariate stochastic process. We say that {x t } is integrated of order one (denoted x t I(1)) if the process { x t x t x t 1 } is stationary whereas {x t } is not stationary. We say that the bivariate stochastic process { y t y 1,t, y 2,t } is integrated of order one if y 1,t I(1) y 2,t I(1). A stochastic process {y t } Granger causes another stochastic process {x t }, with respect to a given information set I t that contains at least x t j, y t j, j > 0, if x t can be better predicted by using past values of y than by not doing so, all other information in I t (including the past of x) being

Econometrics 2013, 3 209 used in either case. More formally, we say that {y t } is Granger causal for {x t } with respect to H xy (t) sp {x t, y t, x t 1, y t 1,...} if x t+1 P (x t+1 H xy (t)) 2 < x t+1 P (x t+1 H x (t)) 2 where H x (t) sp {x t, x t 1,...}. Two stochastic processes, {x t }, {y t }, both of which are individually I(1), are said to be cointegrated if there exists a non-zero constant β such that {z t x t βy t } is a stationary (I(0)) process. It is important to note that cointegration between two variables implies the existence of causality (in the Granger sense) between them in at least one direction (see Granger 4). 3. A Geometric Characterization In this section we assume that { y t y 1,t, y 2,t ; t 0, 1,... } be a bivariate stochastic process defined on (Ω, F, P ), integrated of order one, with y 1,0 y 2,0 0, that has a VAR(1) representation y t Ay t 1 + u t (2) where A a 11 a 12 a 21 a 22 is a fixed (2 2) coefficient matrix u t, is i.i.d. with E (u t ) 0 E(u t u t) Σ σ1 2 0 for all t E(u 0 σ2 2 t u s) 0 for s t. In this framework we have that {y 2,t } does not Granger cause {y 1,t } if only if a 12 0. Similarly, {y 1,t } does not Granger cause {y 2,t } if only if a 21 0. We observe that the VAR residuals are usually correlated hence the covariance matrix Σ is seldom a diagonal matrix. However, because the main aim of this study is pedagogical, we assume that Σ is diagonal for analytical convenience. We consider the following information sets: I y1 (t+) { y 1,t+1, y 1,t+2,...}, I y2 (t+) { y 2,t+1, y 2,t+2,...}, H y1 (t) sp { y 1,t, y 1,t 1,...} H y2 (t) sp { y 2,t, y 2,t 1,...}. Theorem 3.1. Let y t be a VAR(1) process defined as in (2). The differenced process { y t ; t 1,...} is jointly unpredictable if only if d (I y1 (t+), H y2 (t)) σ y1 d (I y2 (t+), H y1 (t)) σ y2 Theorem 1 provides a geometric characterization of the notion of joint unpredictability of a bivariate process in term of distance between information sets. It is important to note that d (I y1 (t+), H y2 (t)) σ y1 d (I y2 (t+), H y1 (t)) σ y2 Thus we have that the process { y t y 1,t, y 2,t ; t 1,...} is jointly unpredictable if only if the distances d (I y1 (t+), H y2 (t)) d (I y2 (t+), H y1 (t)) achieve their maximum value, respectively.

Econometrics 2013, 3 210 It is intuitive to think that if these distances achieve their maximum value, then σ(y t,..., y 0 ) does not contain any valuable information about the future of the differenced series, y t y 1,t, y 2,t hence these are jointly unpredictable with respect to the information set σ(y t,..., y 0 ), that is E( y t+1 σ(y t,..., y 0 )) 0. We recall that Theorem 1 holds only in a bivariate setting. 3.1. Lemmas In order to prove Theorem 1, we need the following lemmas. Lemma 3.2. Let V be a closed subspace of L 2 (Ω, F, P ) G a subset of L 2 (Ω, F, P ) such that g η R, g G. G V if only if d (G, V ) η. Proof. Focker Triacca (5, p. 767). Lemma 1 establishes a relationship between the orthogonality of sets/spaces in the Hilbert space L 2 (Ω, F, P) their distance. We note that the orthogonality between G V holds if only if the distance d (G, V ) achieves the maximum value. In fact, d (G, V ) can not be greater than η since 0 V. Lemma 3.3. The processes {y 1,t } {y 2,t } are not cointegrated if only if A I. Proof. By (2) we have y 1,t y 1,t a 11 1 a 12 a 21 a 22 1 y 1,t 1 y 2,t 1 + These equations must be balanced, that is the order of integration of (a 11 1)y 1,t 1 + a 12 y 2,t 1 a 21 y 1,t 1 + (a 22 1)y 2,t 1 must be zero. ( ) If A I, since (a 11 1)y 1,t 1 + a 12 y 2,t 1 I(0) a 21 y 1,t 1 + (a 22 1)y 2,t 1 I(0), we can have three cases. Case (1) A a ij, with a ij 0 i, j 1, 2, i j a ii 1 i 1, 2. Case (2) a 11 a 12 A 0 1 with a 11 1 a 21 0. Case (3) with a 21 0 a 22 1. 1 0 A a 21 a 22 In all three cases, there exists at least a not trivial linear combination of the processes {y 1,t } {y 2,t } that is stationary. Thus we can conclude that {y 1,t } {y 2,t } are cointegrated. ( ) If A I, then a 12 a 21 0 so {y 1,t } does not Granger cause {y 2,t } {y 2,t } does not Granger cause {y 1,t }. It follows that {y 1,t } {y 2,t } are not cointegrated.

Econometrics 2013, 3 211 Lemma 3.4. If {y 1,t } {y 2,t } are cointegrated, then a 11 + a 22 1 < 1. Proof. We subtract y 1,t 1, y 2,t 1 from both sides of Equation (2) by obtaining y 1,t y 2,t y 2,t a 11 1 a 12 a 21 a 22 1 α 2 y 1,t 1 y 2,t 1 If {y 1,t } {y 2,t } are cointegrated, we have y 1,t α 1 y 1,t 1 β 1 β 2 + β 1 ϑ 1 ϑ 2 ϑ 1 ϑ 2 α 1 α 2 y 2,t 1 1 β 2 /β 1 y 1,t 1 1 β y 1,t 1 y 2,t 1 (y 1,t 1 βy 2,t 1 ) + y 2,t 1 where β (β 2 /β 1 ) is the cointegration coefficient ϑ 1 β 1 α 1 ϑ 2 β 1 α 2 are the speed of adjustment coefficients. We observe that y 1,t β y 2,t ϑ 1 y 1,t 1 βϑ 2 y 1,t 1 βϑ 1 y 2,t 1 + β 2 ϑ 2 y 2,t 1 + β (3) + + + By rearranging Equation (3) we obtain an AR(1) model for y 1,t βy 2,t : y 1,t βy 2,t δ(y 1,t 1 βy 2,t 1 ) + β where δ 1 + ϑ 1 βϑ 2 a 11 + a 22 1. Since {y 1,t } {y 2,t } are cointegrated, {y 1,t βy 2,t } is a stationary process so a 11 + a 22 1 < 1 Lemma 3.5. The process { y t y 1,t, y 2,t ; t 0, 1,... } is jointly unpredictable if only if A I Proof. ( ) process { y t y 1,t, y 2,t ; t 0, 1,... } is jointly unpredictable, then E(y t σ(y t 1,..., y 1 )) y t 1 On the other h, since y t Ay t 1 + u t with E (u t ) 0 E(u t u t) Σ for all t E(u t u s) 0 for s t, we have that E(y t σ(y t 1,..., y 1 )) Ay t 1

Econometrics 2013, 3 212 Hence we have so Ay t 1 y t 1 A I ( ) If A I then y t y t 1 + u t with E (u t ) 0 E(u t u t) Σ for all t E(u t u s) 0 for s t, hence we have E(y t σ(y t 1,..., y 0 )) y t 1 Thus we can conclude that the process { y t y 1,t, y 2,t ; t 1,... } is jointly unpredictable. Before to conclude this subsection we observe that Equation (2) can be written in lag operator notation. The lag operator L is defined such that Ly t y t 1. We have that (I AL)y t u t or 1 a 11 L a 12 L a 21 L 1 a 22 L y 1,t y 2,t 3.2. Proof of Theorem 1 Sufficiency. If then, by Lemma 1, we have d (I y1 (t+), H y2 (t)) σ y1 d (I y2 (t+), H y1 (t)) σ y2 I y1 (t+) H y2 (t) I y2 (t+) H y1 (t) Now we assume that a 12 a 21 are not both equal to zero. We can have three cases. Case (1) a 12 0 a 21 0. This implies that r 1,t (a 11 1)y 1,t + a 12 y 2,t + Thus y 2,t < y 1,t+1, y 2,t > E( y 1,t+1 y 2,t ) (a 11 1)E(y 1,t ) + a 12 E(y 2,t ) + E(+1 ) t (a 11 1)E(y 1,t ) + a 12 E( u 2,s ) (a 11 1)E(y 1,t ) + a 12 σ 2 2 s1

Econometrics 2013, 3 213 Now, we note that Thus but this is absurd since E(y 1,t ) a t 11E(y 1,0 ) 0 < y 1,t+1, y 2,t > a 12 σ 2 2 0 I y1 (t+) H y2 (t) Case (2) a 12 0 a 21 0. In this case we have < y 2,t+1, y 1,t > a 21 σ 2 1 0 Again this is absurd since I y2 (t+) H y1 (t) Case (3) a 12 0 a 21 0. We note that y 1,t (1 a 22 L)γ(L) a 12 Lγ(L) a 21 Lγ(L) (1 a 11 L)γ(L) y 2,t where γ(l) 1 L (1 a 11 L)(1 a 22 L) a 12 a 21 L 2 By Lemma 2, we have that {y 1t } {y 2t } are cointegrated hence the matrix a 11 1 a 12 A I a 21 a 22 1 has rank 1. It follows that a 12 a 21 (1 a 11 )(1 a 22 ) Thus γ(l) 1 L (1 a 11 L)(1 a 22 L) (1 a 11 )(1 a 22 )L 2 1 L (1 L)(1 + L) (1 L)(a 11 + a 22 )L 1 1 + L (a 11 + a 22 )L 1 1 (a 11 + a 22 1)L 1 1 δl where δ a 11 + a 22 1. Since {y 1t } {y 2t } are cointegrated, by Lemma 3 we have that δ < 1 hence Now, we can have two cases. γ(l) 1 + δl + δ 2 L 2 +...

Econometrics 2013, 3 214 Case (a) δ 0. In this case we have y 1,t a 22 1 + a 12 1 y 2,t a 21 1 + a 11 1 Thus but this is absurd since < y 1,t+1, y 2,t > a 12 σ2 2 0 < y 2,t+1, y 1,t > a 21 σ1 2 0 I y1 (t+) H y2 (t) I y2 (t+) H y1 (t) Case (b) δ 0. In this case we have Thus y 1,t + (a 11 1) 1 + δ(a 11 1) 2 +...a 12 1 + a 1 2 +... + (a 11 1) δ i 1 i + a 1 i 1 i i0 y 2,t + (a 22 1) 1 + δ(a 22 1) 2 +...a 21 1 + a 21 δ 2 +... + (a 22 1) δ i 1 i + a 21 δ i 1 i i0 < y 1,t+1, y 2,t > (a 11 1)σ1 1 δ a δ 2 21 + 1 + (a 22 1) σ 1 δ 2a 2 2 12 < y 2,t+1, y 1,t > (a 22 1)σ2 1 δ a δ 2 12 + 1 + (a 11 1) σ 1 δ 1a 2 2 21 Now, we consider the system 1 + (a22 1) δ 1 δ σ 2 2 2 (a 11 1)σ1 1 δ 2 (a 22 1)σ2 1 δ 1 + 2 (a11 1) δ 1 δ σ 2 2 1 i0 i0 a 12 a 21 0 0 The determinant of the matrix 1 + (a22 1) δ 1 δ σ 2 2 2 (a 11 1)σ1 1 δ 2 (a 22 1)σ2 1 δ 1 + 2 (a11 1) δ 1 δ σ 2 2 1 is σ 2 1σ 2 2 ( 1 δ ) 1 + δ

Econometrics 2013, 3 215 Since σ 2 1σ 2 2 > 0 δ 1+δ 1, we have that σ 2 1σ 2 2 ( 1 δ ) 0 1 + δ Thus a 12 0, a 21 0 implies that < y 1,t+1, y 2,t > 0 or < y 2,t+1, y 1,t > 0, but this is absurd since I y1 (t+) H y2 (t) I y2 (t+) H y1 (t) In all Cases (1 3) we obtain an absurd conclusion, thus we can state that Now, we prove that a 11 a 22 1. We have that a 12 0, a 21 0 y i,t (a ii 1)y i,t + u it i 1, 2 Since the error term u t, is stationary these equations must be balanced, that is the order of integration of y i,t (a ii 1)y i,t must be the same. By the hypothesis that y i,t I(1), it follows that y it I(0) (i.e., stationary) (a ii 1)y i,t is I(1), hence y i,t (a ii 1)y i,t + u i,t i 1, 2 implies that a 11 a 22 1. Thus A I hence, by Lemma 4, it follows that the process { y t ; t 1,...} is jointly unpredictable. Necessity. If the process { y t ; t 1,...} is is jointly unpredictable, then by Lemma 4 it follows that A I hence y 1,t y 2,t t. This implies that P ( y 1,t+h H y2 (t)) 0 P ( y 2,t+h H y1 (t)) 0 h > 0. Therefore we have that y 1,t+h H y2 (t) y 2,t+h H y1 (t) h > 0. Thus, by Lemma 1, it follows that Theorem 1 is proved. d (I y1 (t+), H y2 (t)) σ y1 d (I y2 (t+), H y1 (t)) σ y2 4. Conclusions In this paper we have considered the following geometric condition concerning the distance between information sets d (I y1 (t+), H y2 (t)) σ y1 d (I y2 (t+), H y1 (t)) σ y2 (4) It says that the distances d (I y1 (t+), H y2 (t)) d (I y2 (t+), H y1 (t)) achieve their maximum value, respectively. Theorem 1 tells us that, under the hypothesis that the process y t follows a bivariate VAR(1) model, the condition Equation (4) represents a geometric characterization of the notion of joint unpredictability. If this condition holds, the processes y 1 y 2 are jointly unpredictable since the past of the bivariate process y t does not contain any valuable information about the future of the differenced series. The information in the past is too far from the future information. Even if the bivariate VAR(1) assumption is far from general, we think that this geometric characterization is useful in order to throw light on the concept of joint unpredictability of a stochastic process.

Econometrics 2013, 3 216 Acknowledgments We thank two anonymous referees for their helpful constructive comments, Fulvia Focker for helpful comments. Conflicts of Interest The author declares no conict of interest. References 1. Caporale, G.M.; Pittis, N. Cointegration predictability of asset prices. J. Int. Money Financ. 1998, 17, 441 453. 2. Hassapis C.; Kalyvitis, S.; Pittis, N. Cointegration joint efficiency of international commodity markets. Q. Rev. Econ. Financ. 1999, 39, 213 231. 3. Brockwell, P.J.; Davis, R.A. Time Series: Theory Methods, 2nd ed.; Springer-Verlag: New York, NY, USA, 1991. 4. Granger, C.W.J. Developments in the study of cointegrated economic variables. Oxf. Bull. Econ. Stat. 1986, 48, 213 228. 5. Focker, F.; Triacca, U. Interpreting the concept of joint unpredictability of asset returns: A distance approach. Physica A 2006, 2, 765 770. c 2013 by the author; licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerl. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/).