Why Do Firms Conduct Bi-Sourcing? 1

Similar documents
Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure: Slides

Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure: Slides

Incomplete Contracts and the Product Cycle. Pol Antràs. Harvard University, NBER and CEPR

Bargaining, Contracts, and Theories of the Firm. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

Design Patent Damages under Sequential Innovation

Mechanism Design: Basic Concepts

SELECTION EFFECTS WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS: ONLINE APPENDIX

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Cournot and Bertrand Competition in a Differentiated Duopoly with Endogenous Technology Adoption *

Input Specificity and Location

Lecture 8: Incomplete Contracts

Deceptive Advertising with Rational Buyers

Growing competition in electricity industry and the power source structure

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods

5. Externalities and Public Goods

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann

A New and Robust Subgame Perfect Equilibrium in a model of Triadic Power Relations *

Technical Appendix for: Complementary Goods: Creating, Capturing and Competing for Value

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES CONTRACTUAL FRICTIONS AND GLOBAL SOURCING. Pol Antràs Elhanan Helpman. Working Paper

Organizing the Global Value Chain: Online Appendix

Sequential mergers with differing differentiation levels

Mechanism Design: Bayesian Incentive Compatibility

Patience and Ultimatum in Bargaining

On the Pareto Efficiency of a Socially Optimal Mechanism for Monopoly Regulation

Strategic Outsourcing under Economies of Scale

Online Appendix for Sourcing from Suppliers with Financial Constraints and Performance Risk

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

SURPLUS SHARING WITH A TWO-STAGE MECHANISM. By Todd R. Kaplan and David Wettstein 1. Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, Israel. 1.

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS YALE UNIVERSITY P.O. Box New Haven, CT

On the Unique D1 Equilibrium in the Stackelberg Model with Asymmetric Information Janssen, M.C.W.; Maasland, E.

Free Entry and Social Inefficiency under Vertical Oligopoly: Revisited

s<1/4 p i = 2 3 s s [1/4, 9/16[ p i = p j + 2 s p j 1 if p j < p j p i = 2 3 s if p j p j p i = p j if p j < p j s 9/16

Appendix of Homophily in Peer Groups The Costly Information Case

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance.

Information Acquisition in Interdependent Value Auctions

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry!

Online Appendix for Dynamic Ex Post Equilibrium, Welfare, and Optimal Trading Frequency in Double Auctions

Partial Privatization under Multimarket Price Competition

UC Berkeley UC Berkeley Previously Published Works

Intro Prefs & Voting Electoral comp. Voter Turnout Agency GIP SIP Rent seeking Partisans. 7. Special-interest politics

Bilateral Trading in Divisible Double Auctions

Costly Expertise. Dino Gerardi and Leeat Yariv yz. Current Version: December, 2007

Advanced Microeconomics

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

The Revenue Equivalence Theorem 1

Layo Costs and E ciency with Asymmetric Information

Managing Supply Uncertainty under Chain-to-Chain Competition

Blocking Development

General Equilibrium and Welfare

General idea. Firms can use competition between agents for. We mainly focus on incentives. 1 incentive and. 2 selection purposes 3 / 101

Dutch treat versus Oriental treat

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

Efficient Union Contracts in the Presence of Homogeneous Labor and Differentiated Unions

Game Theory, Information, Incentives

Endogenous information acquisition

Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship

Wireless Network Pricing Chapter 6: Oligopoly Pricing

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Supervision, Collusion, and Optimal Contract Design with Costly Information Acquisition

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Team Production and the Allocation of Creativity across Global and Local Sectors

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix

Contracts and Technology Adoption

Dynamic Games and Bargaining. Johan Stennek

A Preliminary Introduction to Mechanism Design. Theory

Impatience vs. Incentives

Oligopoly. Oligopoly. Xiang Sun. Wuhan University. March 23 April 6, /149

The Political Economy of International Factor Mobility

Group Size, Collective Action and Complementarities in Efforts

TAXES AND SUBSIDIES IN A POLLUTING AND POLITICALLY POWERFUL INDUSTRY. Israel Finkelshtain and Yoav Kislev

TitleAsymmetric Information and Global S.

Are innocuous Minimum Quality Standards really innocuous?

Negotiation: Strategic Approach

Dynamic Common Agency

Lecture Slides - Part 4

University of Warwick, Department of Economics Spring Final Exam. Answer TWO questions. All questions carry equal weight. Time allowed 2 hours.

On the Non-Symmetric Nash and Kalai Smorodinsky Bargaining Solutions. Yigal Gerchak

Informed Principal in Private-Value Environments

SUBPART MULTIYEAR CONTRACTING (Revised December 19, 2006)

Intermediate public economics 6 Public goods Hiroaki Sakamoto

Monopoly Regulation in the Presence of Consumer Demand-Reduction

Advanced Macroeconomics

The Value of Rents and The Likelihood of Conflicts

Game Theory. Lecture Notes By Y. Narahari. Department of Computer Science and Automation Indian Institute of Science Bangalore, India July 2012

Price setting on a network

Valuations and Dynamics of Negotiations

Lecture Notes: Industrial Organization Joe Chen 1. The Structure Conduct Performance (SCP) paradigm:

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016

Nash-in-Nash Tariff Bargaining with and without MFN

Efficient Exploitation Of Waste Heat: Coordination Management For A Waste Heat Utilization Project From Economic Perspectives

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

Indescribable Contingencies versus Unawareness and Incomplete Contracting

Foreign Direct Investment, Labour Unions, and Self-interested Governments

Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides Model

Durable goods monopolist

Internalizing Global Value Chains: A Firm-Level Analysis

Controlling versus enabling Online appendix

x ax 1 2 bx2 a bx =0 x = a b. Hence, a consumer s willingness-to-pay as a function of liters on sale, 1 2 a 2 2b, if l> a. (1)

Moral Hazard: Part 1. April 9, 2018

Introduction to Game Theory

Transcription:

Why Do Firms Conduct Bi-Sourcing? 1 Julan Du Chinese University of Hong Kong Yi Lu University of Hong Kong Zhigang Tao University of Hong Kong Abstract In acquiring the same intermediate inputs, a firm often conducts bi-sourcing, i.e., simultaneously buying from external suppliers and self-producing in an internal manufacturer. We show that the firm achieves a better bargaining position in bisourcing than in outsourcing through cross threat effect, which enhances profitability. Key words: Bi-sourcing, Outsourcing, Cross Threat. JEL Classification: D21, D23 1 Corresponding author: Julan Du, Department of Economics, Chinese University of Hong Kong, Shatin, N.T., Hong Kong. Tel: 852-2609-8008, Fax: 852-2603-5805, Email: julandu@cuhk.edu.hk. We would like to thank Thomas Hout, David D. Li, Ping Lin, Ivan Png, Larry Qiu, Michael Riordan, Thomas Ross and participants in the 2005 Summer Workshop on Industrial Organization and Management Strategy at Tsinghua University for their helpful comments.

I.Introduction To produce outputs, a firm typically adopts outsourcing in acquiring intermediate inputs, i.e., buying components from external suppliers. However, in reality, a firm often chooses to acquire the same component by both buying from external suppliers and self-producing in an internal component manufacturer owned by the firm. We call it bi-sourcing as it contains both outsourcing and insourcing. For example, Nokia purchases a large proportion of key electronic components such as semiconductors and microprocessors from a global network of suppliers. At the same time, Nokia operates about ten manufacturing plants in nine countries to produce these components. Why do firms conduct bi-sourcing? In outsourcing, the external component supplier keeps ownership and control over assets for upstream production. According to the property rights theory (Grossman and Hart, 1986), this can stimulate the incentive of the external supplier to improve productivity; however, it also generates the potential holdup problem in arm s-length trading relationship as the external supplier may threaten not to fulfill the contract obligations so as to capture a larger share of total surplus. Bi-sourcing can mitigate the holdup problem to a substantial extent. In negotiating with the external supplier, the firm can use the backup option of the internal supplier to minimize the holdup problem. Once holdup problem occurs, the components from the internal supplier can help avoid a halt to the production process. At the same time, bi-sourcing can keep to a large degree the incentive of external supplier to improve productivity. The presence of an external supplier can further mitigate the internal supplier s problem of lack of incentive. As a result, the firm enjoys a better bargaining position in bi-sourcing than in outsourcing. This stimulates the firm to supply headquarter services, which in turn promotes the component supply and total output through the complementarity effect. Thus, bi-sourcing achieves a higher profitability than outsourcing does. In our example, Nokia finds that outsourcing allows it to secure inputs produced with the state-of-the-art technology, but it also involves the risk that the timely delivery of quality components may not be guaranteed. Bi-sourcing allows Nokia to strike a balance between the quality and the security of component supply. II.Model Setup A firm with headquarter H combines headquarter services (h) withcompo- nent inputs (m) toproducefinal goods. The production generates revenue function R = f(h, m) that has the following characteristics: (1) f 0, 2 f < 0; f 2 m 0, 2 f m < 0; (2) f(0,.) = 0, f(., 0) = 0;and (3) 2 f 2 m > 0, 3 f m < 0, 3 f 2 2 m < 0. Condition (3) indicates the complementarity between the two inputs h and m, but the degree of complementarity decreases in both inputs. Meanwhile, each unit of both inputs requires one unit of labor to produce. For simplicity, the wage rate is normalized to 1. Moreover, the investments in m and h are completely specific to the trading relationship so that they have no value outside the relationship. There are three periods in the model. At time 0, H chooses between outsourcing and bi-sourcing. Ex ante 1

investments in input production are made at date 1, and m is supplied and combined with h at date 2. There is ex ante uncertainty about component type so that it is infeasible to make an effective long-term contract. As investments in input production are irreversible and noncontractible, the parties negotiate about the component type and price at date 2 from scratch. III.Single Outsourcing For simplicity, we consider one external supplier for the outsourcing scenario and call it single outsourcing. 1 At date 1, the headquarter (H) signs a contract with an external supplier M 1 to purchase intermediate goods m 1,andcombines it with h to produce final goods and generate revenue R 1 = f(h, m 1 ).Atdate2, they bargain over the distribution of the surplus from the trading relationship by following the generalized Nash bargaining procedure. In bilateral negotiation, H and M 1 have bargaining power of β 1 and 1 β 1 respectively. Given that trading is efficient, Nash bargaining leads to that H gets β 1 R 1 and M 1 gets (1 β 1 )R 1.H and M 1 choose h and m 1 to maximize β 1 R 1 h and (1 β 1 )R 1 m 1 respectively. IV.Bi Sourcing In bi-sourcing, the headquarter (H) purchases the intermediate inputs from both the external (M 1 )andinternal(m 2 ) suppliers. Let R = f(h, m), R 1 = f(h, m 1 ) and R 2 = f(h, m 2 ) denote the total revenues when both M 1 and M 2, only M 1, and only M 2 provide component inputs, respectively, where m = m 1 + m 2. Following the property rights literature, we assume that ex post bargaining occurs both under outsourcing and under insourcing, that is, H negotiates with the external and internal component suppliers (M 1 and M 2 ) respectively. The bargaining power distribution between H and M 1 remains thesameasbefore,whileh and M 2 have bargaining power of β 2 and 1 β 2 respectively. Following Antras and Helpman (2004), we assume that H has a higher bargaining power with respect to M 2 than with respect to M 1, i.e., β 2 >β 1. This is a realistic assumption: as long as a component supplier does not have some unique production capability that can hardly be replaced, H tends to have stronger bargaining power when she owns the supplier and enjoys the residual control rights or authority. At the beginning of date 1, H announces the bargaining procedure, i.e., whether she will negotiate first with M 2 and then M 1 or the other way around. We consider the former case first. Using the backward deduction approach, we first look at the bargaining game between H and M 1. Before that negotiation is started, H has already finished the negotiation with M 2, securing a component supply of m 2 and paying P 2 to M 2. Consequently, in negotiating with M 1, H expects to obtain R P 1 P 2 if the trading is carried out but gets the disagreement option value R 2 P 2 if negotiation breaks down, whereas M 1 obtains a transfer payment P 1 from H if trading is conducted and zero otherwise. As trading is efficient, Nash bargaining determines the division of social surplus 1 Having two external component suppliers with differential bargaining power makes no qualitative difference to our results as long as the firm has a larger bargaining power relative to the internal supplier than the external supplier due to ownership and authority. 2

by transfer payment P1 =(1 β 1 )(R R 2 ). Correspondingly, H obtains R 2 P 2 + β 1 (R R 2 ) and M 1 gets (1 β 1 )(R R 2 ). Next we move back to the initial stage bargaining between H and M 2.With full knowledge and rational expectations, H and M 2 bargain over R P1. If trade with M 2 takes place, H secures R P1 P 2 and M 2 obtains P 2.Ifthere is no trade with M 2, H can at least reap β 1 R 1 from single outsourcing with M 1, while M 2 gets nothing. The Nash bargaining yields P2 =(1 β 2 )(R P1 β 1 R 1 ), which can be rewritten as P2 =(1 β 2 )[β 1 R +(1 β 1 )R 2 β 1 R 1 ].Asaresult,H, M 1 and M 2 obtain profits of π H = R P1 P2 h = β 1 β 2 R + β 1 (1 β 2 )R 1 + β 2 (1 β 1 )R 2 h, π M1 =(1 β 1 )(R R 2 ) m 1, and π M2 =(1 β 2 )[β 1 R +(1 β 1 )R 2 β 1 R 1 ] m 2, respectively. The whole problem becomes H, M 1 and M 2 choosing h, m 1 and m 2 atdate1tomaximize π H,π M1, and π M2, respectively. Interestingly, we find that the sequence of bargaining does matter: Proposition 1: For bi-sourcing to be sustainable, H must negotiate with the softer party ( M 2 ) earlier than the tougher one ( M 1 ); otherwise the bi-sourcing scenario would be reduced to single outsourcing. We know that the component supplier who is negotiated later contributes to the total revenue on top of the inputs made by the supplier that is negotiated earlier. Given the concavity of the production revenue function, the late mover always contributes less to total revenue for a given amount of inputs and in turn claims a lower marginal revenue than the early mover does. If H negotiates with M 2 later than M 1, M 2 always encounters a lower marginal revenue than M 1 does. Since M 1,asthefirst mover, equates its marginal revenue with the constant marginal cost in equilibrium, M 2 will have a marginal revenue that is always lower than the marginal cost, which will depress her incentive to make investments and reduce bi-sourcing to single outsourcing. V.Choice between Bi sourcing and Single Outsourcing Finally, the headquarter H chooses between bi-sourcing and single outsourcingatdate0.itturnsoutthatbi-sourcingismoreefficient. Proposition 2: Bi-sourcing generates more profits than single outsourcing does. In bi-sourcing, H can obtain cross threat effect in negotiating with M 1 and M 2.WithM 2 as a backup, H can diminish the holdup problem of M 1.Moreover, with M 1 as an outside option, H can also force M 2 to make relationshipspecific investments. Consequently, H achieves a better bargaining position in bi-sourcing than in single outsourcing, and her supply of h also increases. As h and m are strategic complements, this in return stimulates the component provision by M 1 and M 2, which further enhances the total profits. VI. Conclusion In this paper, we provide one explanation for the superiority of bi-sourcing: the cross threat in negotiation in bi-sourcing helps the firm to mitigate the holdup problem of outsourcing, keeps the incentive of both internal and external suppliers and improves economic efficiency. 3

Appendix [Sketch of Proof to Proposition 1] As the bargaining structure is symmetric, if H negotiates with M 1 earlier than M 2,wecanwriteoutthefirst f(h,m) order conditions for H, M 1 and h M 2 as β 1 β 2 + β 1 (1 i β 2 ) f(h,m1) + β 2 (1 β 1 ) f(h,m2) f(h,m) =1, (1 β 1 ) β 2 m 1 +(1 β 2 ) f(h,m1) m 1 =1, and (1 β 2 ) f(h,m) f(h,m) m 2 =1respectively. As β 2 m 1 +(1 β 2 ) f(h,m 1) m 1 > f(h,m) m 2 and 1 β 1 > 1 β 2, the last two equations cannot be satisfied simultaneously. Since M 1 moves first to choose the optimal investment, the late mover M 2 always faces the situation of (1 β 2 ) f(h,m) m 2 < 1. Thusm 2 =0. It is easy to show that if H negotiates with M 2 earlier than M 1, the three first order conditions can be satisfied simultaneously. QED. [Sketch of Proof to Proposition 2] In single outsourcing, the first order f(h,m conditions for H and M 1 are β 1) 1 =1and (1 β 1 ) f(h,m1) m 1 =1respectively. The former equation generates the headquarter s reaction fuction to the component supplier as h S = h S (m; β 1 ), while the latter equation generates the supplier s reaction function to the headquarter as m S = m S (h; β 1 ). In bi-sourcing, when H negotiates with M 2 earlier than with M 1,thefirst f(h,m) order conditions for H, M 2 and M 1 are β 1 β 2 + β 1 (1 β 2 ) f(h,m 1) h i + β 2 (1 β 1 ) f(h,m 2) f(h,m) =1, (1 β 2 ) β 1 m 2 +(1 β 1 ) f(h,m 2) m 2 =1, and (1 β 1 ) f(h,m 1+m 2 ) m 1 =1, respectively. Rewrite the equation for H as T f(h,m) = f(h,m)/. From 1,where T = β 1 β 2 + β 1 (1 β 2 ) f(h,m1)/ f(h,m)/ + β 2(1 β 1 ) f(h,m2)/ the first order conditions for H and M 1, we can obtain the reaction functions of the headquarter and the two component suppliers as h B = h B (m; T ) and m B = m B (h; β 1 ) respectively. The component suppliers reaction functions coincide under bi-sourcing and single outsourcing, i.e., m S = m B = g(h; β 1 ), while the headquarter s reaction functions differ only in the exogenous variable, i.e. h = h(m; i), i = T for bi-sourcing and i = β 1 for single outsourcing. It is easy to show that the reaction functions h(m; i) and g(h; β 1 ) are increasing and concave in m and h respectively, and h(m; i) is increasing in the exogenous variable i. Since f(h,m1) + f(h,m2) > f(h,m) holds by assumption, we have T > β 1. The intersection point of the two reaction functions under bi-sourcing lies northeast to that under single outsourcing, which means at the second-best equilibrium we have h B >h S, and m B >m S. This finally leads to higher revenue and profits under bi-sourcing than under single outsourcing. QED. Reference Antras, Pol and Elhanan Helpman (2004) Global Sourcing, Journal of Political Economy, 112: 552-580. Grossman, Sanford J. and Oliver D. Hart (1986) The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration", Journal of Political Economy, 94:691-719. 4