Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

Similar documents
Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. November 2010

Gali (2008), Chapter 3

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

The Basic New Keynesian Model. Jordi Galí. June 2008

The New Keynesian Model

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Stagnation Traps. Gianluca Benigno and Luca Fornaro

The Real Business Cycle Model

Lecture 3, November 30: The Basic New Keynesian Model (Galí, Chapter 3)

Topic 9. Monetary policy. Notes.

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

Monetary Economics. Lecture 15: unemployment in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

1. Constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) or Dixit-Stiglitz aggregators. Consider the following function J: J(x) = a(j)x(j) ρ dj

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #4 Solutions

Problem 1 (30 points)

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8

Imperfect Information and Optimal Monetary Policy

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

The Return of the Wage Phillips Curve

The Smets-Wouters Model

Inference. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Macroeconomics Theory II

The Basic New Keynesian Model, the Labor Market and Sticky Wages

Government The government faces an exogenous sequence {g t } t=0

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital. Lawrence J. Christiano

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Small Open Economy RBC Model Uribe, Chapter 4

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Monetary Models with Nominal Rigidities. Jordi Galí Universitat Pompeu Fabra April 2018

New Keynesian Macroeconomics

Advanced Macroeconomics

Permanent Income Hypothesis Intro to the Ramsey Model

Simple New Keynesian Model without Capital

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

Learning and Global Dynamics

Lecture 6, January 7 and 15: Sticky Wages and Prices (Galí, Chapter 6)

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

New Keynesian DSGE Models: Building Blocks

Resolving the Missing Deflation Puzzle. June 7, 2018

WORKING PAPER NO INTEREST RATE VERSUS MONEY SUPPLY INSTRUMENTS: ON THE IMPLEMENTATION OF MARKOV-PERFECT OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

1 The Basic RBC Model

Foundations for the New Keynesian Model. Lawrence J. Christiano

Solving a Dynamic (Stochastic) General Equilibrium Model under the Discrete Time Framework

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max

Indeterminacy with No-Income-Effect Preferences and Sector-Specific Externalities

Equilibrium Conditions for the Simple New Keynesian Model

DSGE-Models. Calibration and Introduction to Dynare. Institute of Econometrics and Economic Statistics

Demand Shocks, Monetary Policy, and the Optimal Use of Dispersed Information

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Public Economics The Macroeconomic Perspective Chapter 2: The Ramsey Model. Burkhard Heer University of Augsburg, Germany

ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Foundations of the Sticky Wage Approach and a Critical Commentary

Monetary Economics Notes

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Advanced Macroeconomics

Assessing the Fed s Performance through the Effect of Technology Shocks: New Evidence

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle

Chapter 11 The Stochastic Growth Model and Aggregate Fluctuations

Deviant Behavior in Monetary Economics

Graduate Macroeconomics - Econ 551

A Dynamic Model of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Equilibrium Conditions and Algorithm for Numerical Solution of Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2017) HANK Model.

Dynamics of Sticky Information and Sticky Price Models in a New Keynesian DSGE Framework

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations?

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Lecture 15. Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model. Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2017 Last updated: July 3, 2017

Optimal Inflation Stabilization in a Medium-Scale Macroeconomic Model

Deep Habits, Nominal Rigidities and Interest Rate Rules

Aggregate Supply. Econ 208. April 3, Lecture 16. Econ 208 (Lecture 16) Aggregate Supply April 3, / 12

Time-varying Consumption Tax, Productive Government Spending, and Aggregate Instability.

1. Money in the utility function (start)

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

Real Business Cycle Model (RBC)

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

The Natural Rate of Interest and its Usefulness for Monetary Policy

Dynamics of Firms and Trade in General Equilibrium. Robert Dekle, Hyeok Jeong and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki USC, Seoul National University and Princeton

Bayesian Estimation of DSGE Models: Lessons from Second-order Approximations

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory

Advanced Macroeconomics II. Real Business Cycle Models. Jordi Galí. Universitat Pompeu Fabra Spring 2018

Monetary Policy with Heterogeneous Agents: Insights from TANK models

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

Monetary Policy with Heterogeneous Agents: Insights from Tank Models

Lecture 2. (1) Aggregation (2) Permanent Income Hypothesis. Erick Sager. September 14, 2015

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013

Economic Growth: Lectures 5-7, Neoclassical Growth

Transcription:

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models December 4, 2007

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models Random shocks to generate trajectories that look like the observed national accounts. Rational expectations; representative agents; often calibration and solution by numerical techniques. 1. The classical or real business cycle model 2. The new keynesian model Basic building blocks.

Description of consumer s behavior Discrete time, infinite horizon. Nominal riskless bonds of one period maturity, no bankruptcy, incomplete markets Non storable consumption good Endogenous labor supply Important notation: upper case letters are for levels; lower case letters for the natural logarithms

Description of consumer s behavior The household has a competitive behavior: s/he considers prices, wages and interest rates as given. Budget constraints: maxe 0 β t U(C t, L t ) t=0 P t C t + Q t B t = W t L t + B t 1 + lump sum transfers net of taxes End of game: In practice we shall take lim B T 0 T U(C, L) = C 1 σ 1 σ L1+φ 1 + φ

First order conditions or in logarithms U L U C = C σ L φ = W P w t p t = σc t + φl t labor supply and a straightforward computation yields Q t U C,t P t = βe t U C,t+1 P t+1 Euler equation (1)

Transformation of Euler equation Definitions: nominal interest rate i t = ln Q t discount rate ρ = ln β inflation rate π t = ln(p t+1 /P t ) (expected) real interest rate r t = i t E t π t+1 Approximation in a neighborhood of a perfect foresight constant growth path at rate γ: γ = ln(c t+1 /C t ) = c t+1 c t. Along the constant growth path, the Euler equation is i = ρ + π + σγ

Log linearization of Euler equation The Euler equation can be rewritten as: E t exp[ σ c t+1 π t+1 ρ + i t ] = 1 A first order Taylor expansion in a small neighborhood of the reference trajectory gives exp[ σ c t+1 π t+1 ρ + i t ] 1 σ c t+1 π t+1 ρ + i t, so that, at a first order approximation i t = ρ + E t π t+1 + σe t c t+1, or Euler equation (2) c t = E t c t+1 1 σ [i t E t π t+1 ρ]

Firms Exogenous stochastic technical progress, no capital (or fixed capital stock) Competitive representative firm with production function or in logarithm Y t = A t N 1 α t y t = a t + (1 α)n t Maximization of profit P t Y t W t N t in each period, given prices and wages W t P t = (1 α)a t N α t which yields the labor demand schedule in logarithm w t p t = a t αn t + ln(1 α) labor demand

Production and costs The cost of producing Y is Ψ t (Y ) = W t ( Y A t ) 1/(1 α). The real marginal cost is (the wage argument is implicitly in the index t) MC t (Y, P) = Ψ t(y ) P = W t P ( ) 1 Y 1/(1 α) 1 1 α A t Y = W t P 1 N(Y ) α 1 α A t Here N(Y ) stands for the quantity of labor required to produce Y.

Marginal costs In logarithm: mc t (n, p) = w t p ln(1 α) a t + αn. The labor demand schedule is defined by the first order condition that price is equal to marginal cost, that is real marginal cost equals 1, or the logarithm of real marginal cost is equal to zero.

Equilibrium allocation Equalizing labor supply with labor demand, and good demand with production yields w t p t = a t αn t + ln(1 α) = σy t + φn t, where y t = a t + (1 α)n t. A tedious straightforward computation gives 1 σ n t = σ(1 α) + φ + α a ln(1 α) t + σ(1 α) + φ + α y t = 1 + φ σ(1 α) + φ + α a (1 α) ln(1 α) t + σ(1 α) + φ + α Employment and output are determined independently of nominal quantities (dichotomy).

Real interest rate The Euler equation gives the real interest rate that supports the allocation: r t = i t E t π t+1 = ρ + σe t y t+1, so that 1 + φ r t = ρ + σ σ(1 α) + φ + α E t a t+1 The real interest rate is determined by the real path of consumption (or output) together with the impatience of the agents.

Price indeterminacy, or the path of assets Rational expectations (or expectations are chosen to rationalize the equilibrium path) In the absence of stochastic shocks, there would be no motive to hold nominal assets in the long run (the aggregate stock of assets would have to be zero, and the general price level would be indeterminate). Possible precautionary motive when there are shocks: check that in the absence of bank interventions (Q t = 1 or i t = 0), there is an equilibrium with positive B 0.

How to have unemployment and a non neutral monetary policy, at least in the short run Equilibria with quantity rationing, with slow adjustment of nominal wages and prices (Walras tatonnement). Who sets prices? The only one with true unemployment. Confusion between real and nominal shocks may give scope for monetary policy. Equilibria with monopolistic competition (local monopoly power), underemployment compared with perfect competition. Some nominal inertia is added: Delayed arrival of information Menu costs in changing prices : the new keynesian model

Variety of goods: households Continuum of goods, designated with an index i which takes its valued in the interval [0, 1]. where Budget constraints: 1 0 maxe 0 β t U(C t, L t ) ( 1 C t = 0 t=0 ) ε/(ε 1) C t (i) 1 1/ε di P t (i)c t (i)di + Q t B t = W t L t + B t 1 + lump sum transfers

Allocation of total consumption among varieties Define ( 1 P t = 0 ) 1/(1 ε) P t (i) 1 ε di The choice among varieties follows from max 1 0 C t (i) 1 1/ε di subject to First order condition 1 0 P t (i)c t (i)di = Z C t (i) 1/ε = λp t (i)

Aggregation Define ( 1 P t = 0 ) 1/(1 ε) P t (i) 1 ε di We want to show that with this definition, whatever the individual prices, 1. P t C t = 1 2. The demand for good i satisfies 0 P t (i)c t (i)di = Z ε P t (i) C t (i) = C t P t

Allocation among varieties: aggregattion works Manipulating the FOC and the identities defining the aggregates: Z = λ ε 1 Z = λ 1 1 0 0 P t (i) 1 ε di = λ ε P 1 ε t C t (i) 1 1/ε di = λ 1 C 1 1/ε t Raising the first equation to the power 1/ε and multiplying with the second eliminates λ and gives the aggregate budget constraint that we are looking for. This in turn yields C 1/ε t = λp t, which gives the expression for the individual demand as a function of overall consumption abd the price ratio.

Households: concluded subject to maxe 0 β t U(C t, L t ) t=0 P t C t + Q t B t = W t L t + B t 1 + lump sum transfers First order conditions yield w t p t = σc t + φl t c t = E t c t+1 1 σ [i t E t π t+1 ρ].

Firms One firm per variety, all with identical production functions Y t (i) = A t N t (i) 1 α Common aggregate productivity shock. Firms are local monopolists who take the aggregates (C t, P t ) as given, and face identical isoelastic demand schedules. They choose optimally their price, given the possible rigidities.

Equilibrium with flexible prices Profit of the local monopolist is P(i)C(i) WN(i) = C(i) 1 1/ε W C 1/ε The first order condition yields ε 1 ε C(i) 1/ε P ( ) 1 C(i) 1 α A. P C 1/ε = 1 ( ) 1 C(i) 1 α W 1 α 1 A C(i). At the equilibrium, all agents produce the same quantity and choose the same price, so that taking logs ( ) ε 1 w t p t = y t n t + ln(1 α) + ln ε i.e. ( ) ε 1 w t p t = a t αn t + ln(1 α) + ln ε

Equilibrium with flexible prices: concluded The only difference with the classical labor demand schedule demand comes from the markup term (ε 1)/ε: firms reduce their output and labor demand to increase their profits. The dichotomy still is present and there are no real effects of monetary policy.

Price rigidities Calvo: each firm has probability (1 θ) to be allowed to reset its price in any period, independently of the time since last adjustment. The set of firms that do not change price has average price level P t 1. All the other (identical) firms choose an identical product price P t. The aggregation formula gives: P 1 ε t = θpt 1 1 ε 1 ε + (1 θ)p t Log linearizing around the zero inflation steady state yields (recall that Π t = P t /P t 1, π t = ln Π t ): π t = (1 θ)(p t p t 1 )

Optimal price setting The firm chooses the price level P which maximizes its expected discounted profits during the period where it will stay unchanged: max θ τ E t Q t,t+τ [P Y t+τ t Ψ t+τ (Y t+τ t )] τ=0 Here Q t,t+τ is the discount factor for nominal transfers between periods t and t + τ; Y t+τ t is the output at date t + τ of a firm whose price has been fixed at date t; from the consumer demand Y t+τ t = C t+τ (P /P t+τ ) ε ; Ψ t+τ (Y ) = W t+τ N t+τ = W t+τ (Y /A t+τ ) 1/(1 α is the cost of producing Y at date t + τ.

First order condition The first order condition for the optimal price is (using the equality Y / P = εy /P ): or θ τ E t Q t,t+τ [ (ε 1)Y t+τ t + εψ t+τ τ=0 θ τ E t Q t,t+τ Y t+τ t [ 1 + τ=0 Using the real marginal cost concept τ=0 ε ε 1 Ψ t+τ Y t+τ t P ] = 0 1 P ] = 0 θ τ E t Q t,t+τ Y t+τ t [ 1 + ε ε 1 MC(Y t+τ t, P )] = 0

Linearization close to a zero inflation steady state Along a zero inflation steady state, output and prices are constant, Q t,t+τ = β τ, and the first order condition implies MC(Y, P) = ε 1 ε Linearizing the first order condition yields = MC < 1 or (βθ) τ E t [ 1 + ε ε 1 MC t+τ (Y t+τ t, P )] = 0, τ=0 (βθ) τ E t [mc t+τ (Y t+τ t, P ) mc] = 0. τ=0

From individual marginal cost to aggregate marginal cost Individual marginal cost at date t + τ for a firm who last changed its price at t is mc t+τ (Y t+τ t, P t ). The macroeconomic aggregate marginal cost is defined as mc t+τ (Y t+τ, P t+τ ) = mc t+τ. mc t+τ (Y t+τ t, P t ) = mc t+τ p t + p t+τ + α 1 α [y t+τ t y t+τ ] Substituting production for prices using the price elasticity ε mc t+τ (Y t+τ t, P t ) = mc t+τ p t + p t+τ αε 1 α [p t p t+τ ] mc t+τ (Y t+τ t, P t ) = mc t+τ 1 α + αε 1 α [p t p t+τ ]

The first order condition revisited (βθ) τ E t [mc t+τ (Y t+τ t, P ) mc] = 0, τ=0 is equivalent in macroeconomic terms to { (βθ) τ E t mc t+τ mc 1 α + αε } 1 α [p t p t+τ ] = 0 τ=0 Writing the same expression for date t + 1, taking its expectation from date t, multiplying it by βθ and adding to the current equality, eliminates all the t + τ terms for τ > 1: mc t mc 1 α + αε 1 α [p t p t ]+(βθ) (βθ) τ 1 α + αε 1 α [E tpt+1 p t ] = 0 τ=0

Inflation and expected marginal costs Rearranging 1 α (1 βθ) 1 α + αε [mc t mc] (pt p t ) + βθ(e t pt+1 p t ) = 0. Recalling the Calvo relationship between inflation and the newly posted price, π t = p t p t 1 = (1 θ)(p t p t 1 ), one can eliminate the p s: i.e. 1 α (1 βθ) 1 α + αε [mc t mc] π t 1 θ + π t + βθ E tπ t+1 1 θ = 0 π t = βe t π t+1 + π t = (1 βθ)(1 θ) θ (1 βθ)(1 θ) θ 1 α 1 α + αε 1 α 1 α + αε [mc t mc]. β τ E t [mc t+τ mc]. τ=0

The output gap Recall that the expression for the marginal cost is mc t = w t p t ln(1 α) a t + αn t. The labor supply of the household satisfies w t p t = σy t + φn t Eliminating the real wage and employment y t = a t + (1 α)n t, or mc t = σy t ln(1 α) a t + α + φ 1 α (y t a t ), mc t = ( σ + α + φ ) y t α + φ 1 α 1 α a t ln(1 α) The natural level of output yt n is defined as the one that would prevail under flexibles prices, i. the value of production such that mc t = mc. The output gap ỹ t is the difference between output y t and its natural level yt n.

The New Keynesian Phillips curve It follows from expressing the marginal cost in terms of the output gap: ( (1 βθ)(1 θ) 1 α π t = βe t π t+1 + σ + α + φ ) ỹ t. θ 1 α + αε 1 α }{{} k

The dynamic IS equation From the intertemporal first order condition of the consumer s program: y t = E t y t+1 1 σ [i t E t π t+1 ρ]. Define the natural rate of interest ρ n t as the rate that would prevail on the reference constant price trajectory: y n t = E t y n t+1 1 σ [r n t ρ]. The difference between these two equalities gives the dynamic IS equation ỹ t = E t ỹ t+1 1 σ [i t E t π t+1 r n t ].

The equilibrium Two equations to determine the output gap and the inflation rate. One needs to make precise the monetary policy to determine the nominal interest rate i t and close the model.

Equilibrium under an interest rate rule Assume i t = ρ t + φ π π t + φ y ỹ t + v t The coefficients of inflation and the output gap are non negative. The constant term is chosen so as to allow a zero inflation rate. The random term v t is exogenous with zero mean. Substituting into the dynamic IS equation gives ( 1 + φ ) y ỹ t + φ π σ σ π t = E t ỹ t+1 + 1 σ [E tπ t+1 + rt n ρ v t ]

The system of equilibrium equations In matrix form, the Phillips curve and IS equations become ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( k 1 ỹt 0 β Et ỹ = t+1 0 + σ + φ y φ π π t σ 1 E t π t+1 rt n ρ v t ) This yields ỹt π t 1 = σ+φ y +kφ π φ π 1 σ + φ y k 0 β σ 1 E tỹ t+1 E t π t+1 + 0 rt n ρ v t ỹt π t 1 = σ+φ y +kφ π σ 1 βφ π σk β(σ + φ y ) + k E tỹ t+1 E t π t+1 + 1 k (r t n ρ vt)

The matrix eigenvalues The eigenvalues are the roots of characteristic polynomial f (λ) = λ 2 Sλ + P The sum of the roots S is equal to the trace S = σ + β(σ + φ y ) + k σ + φ y + kφ π while their product is equal to the determinant βσ P = σ + φ y + kφ π

Position of the eigenvalues relative to the unit circle The determinant is smaller than 1: by assumption the coefficients of the interest rate rule are non negative and k is non negative. If the roots are complex, they are both inside the unit circle. If they are real, at least one of them is inside the unit circle. A necessary and sufficient condition for both roots to be inside the unit circle then is P( 1) > 0, P(1) > 0. Now P( 1) = 1+S+P > 0, P(1) = 1 S+P = (1 β)φ y + k(φ π 1) σ + φ y + kφ π A necessary and sufficient condition for both roots to be inside the unit circle is (1 β)φ y + k(φ π 1) > 0

The rational expectations equilibrium: monetary shocks Suppose v t is AR(1) v t = ρ v v t 1 + ε v t One looks for a linear solution in v t, ỹ t = ψ y v t π t = ψ π v t where the unknowns are the coefficients psi y and ψ π. E t ỹ t+1 = ψ y ρ v v t E t π t+1 = ψ π ρ v v t

Finding the rational expectations equilibrium Substituting into the IS and Phillips curves yield two equations in the two unknowns ψ π = βρ v ψ π + kψ y ψ y = ρ v ψ y 1 σ (φ πψ π + φ y psi y + 1 ψ π ρ v A similar computation can be done for the impact of technology shocks, supposing a AR(1) structure for technical progress a t = ρ a a t 1 + ε a t

Calibration β = 0.99 Period: quarter σ = 1 log utility φ = 1 unit Frisch elasticity of labor supply θ = 2/3average price duration of three quarters ρ v = 0.5 ρ a = 0.9 Greenspan time φ π = 1.5, φ y = 0.5/4

Figure 3.1: Effects of a Monetary Policy Shock (Interest Rate Rule))

Figure 3.2: Effects of a Technology Shock (Interest Rate Rule)