Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Similar documents
Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 8: Optimal Minimum Wage and Introduction to Capital Taxation

Manolis Galenianos, Philipp Kircher and Gabor Virag Market power and efficiency in a search model

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Directed Search with Multiple Vacancies

Unemployment Insurance and Optimal Taxation in a Search Model of the Labor Market

The Harris-Todaro model

Effi ciency in Search and Matching Models: A Generalized Hosios Condition

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Foundations of the Sticky Wage Approach and a Critical Commentary

Directed Search with Multiple Job Applications. Manolis Galenianos, Philipp A. Kircher

Directed Search on the Job, Heterogeneity, and Aggregate Fluctuations

SELECTION EFFECTS WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS: ONLINE APPENDIX

Online Appendix to Asymmetric Information and Search Frictions: A Neutrality Result

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

Aggregate Demand, Idle Time, and Unemployment

Asymmetric Information and Search Frictions: A Neutrality Result

Labor Economics, Lecture 11: Partial Equilibrium Sequential Search

Job Search Models. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde. University of Pennsylvania. February 12, 2016

Schumpeterian Growth Models

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

Adverse Selection in Competitive Search Equilibrium

Under-Employment and the Trickle-Down of Unemployment - Online Appendix Not for Publication

Comparative Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms

General Equilibrium and Welfare

B Search and Rest Unemployment Fernando Alvarez and Robert Shimer Additional Appendixes not for Publication

5. Externalities and Public Goods. Externalities. Public Goods types. Public Goods

The Basic New Keynesian Model, the Labor Market and Sticky Wages

On the Efficiency of Wage-Setting Mechanisms with Search Frictions and Human Capital Investment

Online Appendix for Investment Hangover and the Great Recession

5. Externalities and Public Goods

Simultaneous Search with Heterogeneous Firms and Ex Post Competition

Should Robots Be Taxed?

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Competitive Equilibrium

Should Robots Be Taxed?

Adverse Selection, Signaling, and Screening in Markets

Optimal Income Taxation: Mirrlees Meets Ramsey

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis V Suggested Solutions for the First Midterm. max

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

Handout: Competitive Equilibrium

Diamond-Mortensen-Pissarides Model

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1

Advanced Economic Growth: Lecture 3, Review of Endogenous Growth: Schumpeterian Models

Second Welfare Theorem

Variable Search Intensity in an Economy with Coordination Unemployment

Competitive Search with Private Information

McCall Model. Prof. Lutz Hendricks. November 22, Econ720

The Labor Market in the New Keynesian Model: Incorporating a Simple DMP Version of the Labor Market and Rediscovering the Shimer Puzzle

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth

Introduction to General Equilibrium: Framework.

Differentiable Welfare Theorems Existence of a Competitive Equilibrium: Preliminaries

Proper Welfare Weights for Social Optimization Problems

UNIVERSITY OF WISCONSIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS MACROECONOMICS THEORY Preliminary Exam August 1, :00 am - 2:00 pm

Competitive Search Equilibrium and Moral Hazard

NASH BARGAINING, ON-THE-JOB SEARCH AND LABOR MARKET EQUILIBRIUM

Optimal Income Taxation and Public-Goods Provision with Preference and Productivity Shocks

Econ 201: Problem Set 3 Answers

Lecture 2: Firms, Jobs and Policy

Frictional Wage Dispersion in Search Models: A Quantitative Assessment

An adaptation of Pissarides (1990) by using random job destruction rate

4. Partial Equilibrium under Imperfect Competition

Efficient Search on the Job and the Business Cycle

Toulouse School of Economics, M2 Macroeconomics 1 Professor Franck Portier. Exam Solution

On-the-Job Search with Match-Specific Amenities

Layo Costs and E ciency with Asymmetric Information

Equilibrium Directed Search with Multiple Applications

Under-Employment and the Trickle-Down of Unemployment Online Appendix Not for Publication

On-The-Job Search and Sorting

General Equilibrium. General Equilibrium, Berardino. Cesi, MSc Tor Vergata

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Problem 1 (30 points)

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy

Notes on General Equilibrium

Lecture 5: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory

Economic Growth: Lectures 9 and 10, Endogenous Technological Change

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

1 The Basic RBC Model

Fixed Term Employment Contracts. in an Equilibrium Search Model

Development Economics

Market Failure: Externalities

Increasingly, economists are asked not just to study or explain or interpret markets, but to design them.

LABOR MATCHING MODELS: EFFICIENCY PROPERTIES FEBRUARY 1, 2019

Consumption Externalities and Pigouvian Ranking A Generalized Cobb-Douglas Example

Specialization and Efficiency with Labor-Market Matching

Operating Leverage, Risk Taking and Coordination Failures

PhD Qualifier Examination

A Theory of Partially Directed Search

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Economic Growth: Lecture 7, Overlapping Generations

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A MACROECONOMIC THEORY OF OPTIMAL UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE. Camille Landais Pascal Michaillat Emmanuel Saez

Redistribution and Disability Insurance. Hugo A. Hopenhayn UCLA Juan Carlos Hatchondo University of Rochester

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 6: Partial and General Equilibrium

Firms and returns to scale -1- Firms and returns to scale

Transcription:

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk Mikhail Golosov Yale University and NBER Pricila Maziero University of Pennsylvania Guido Menzio University of Pennsylvania and NBER May 27, 2011

Introduction Search and matching frictions in the labor market are a source of inequality among ex-ante identical workers: 1. Search frictions generate employment inequality, in the sense that, at a given point in time, some workers are employed and some are unemployed. 2. Search frictions generate wage inequality, in the sense that, at a given point in time, some workers are employed at low paying jobs and some are employed at high paying jobs. Search theories of employment and wage inequality: Mortensen (1970), Burdett (1978), Burdett and Mortensen (1998). Empirical assessment of the importance of search inequality: Eckstein and Wolpin (1991) and Postel-Vinay and Robin (2002).

Introduction What is the optimal mechanism to redistribute search inequality? We answer the question in the context of a directed search model of the labor market with homogeneous workers and heterogenous firms which generates both employment and wage inequality.

Introduction What is the optimal mechanism to redistribute search inequality? We answer the question in the context of a directed search model of the labor market with homogeneous workers and heterogenous firms which generates both employment and wage inequality. 1. We prove that the equilibrium of the labor market is inefficient because the marginal productivity of applicants is not equated across different firms and because the marginal utility of consumption is not equated across workers in different states.

Introduction What is the optimal mechanism to redistribute search inequality? We answer the question in the context of a directed search model of the labor market with homogeneous workers and heterogenous firms which generates both employment and wage inequality. 2. We study the optimal insurance mechanism subject to search frictions and informational frictions (i.e. workers private information about their search and firms private information about their productivity): a. we prove that the optimal insurance mechanism mitigates both the productive and the distributive inefficiency of the equilibrium; b. we show that the optimal insurance mechanism is implemented by a positive unemployment benefit, a binding minimum wage and a regressive labor earning tax.

Introduction What is the optimal mechanism to redistribute search inequality? We answer the question in the context of a directed search model of the labor market with homogeneous workers and heterogenous firms which generates both employment and wage inequality. 3. Our theory of labor taxes is Pigovian: a. Labor taxes do not insure workers against wage risk. Wage differentials represent compensation for the different employment risk involved with applying to jobs that attract queues of different length. b. Labor taxes correct an externality that firms impose on one other. The externality is not inherent to the environment (e.g. a matching externality), but it is caused by the introduction of unemployment benefits.

Related literature 1. Our findings on labor earning taxes differ from those obtained by Mirrlees (1971) and Saez (2001) in the context of a frictionless labor market: a. In Mirrlees and Saez, labor tax is redistributive and its shape is designed to induce workers to make the socially optimal choices on how many hours to work. b. In our frictional labor market, labor tax is Pigovian and its shape is designed to induce firms to make the socially optimal choices on how many applicants to attract.

Related literature 2. Our paper extends the analysis of Acemoglu and Shimer (1999): a. Acemoglu and Shimer consider a directed search model of the labor market with homogeneous workers and homogeneous firms and show that a small, positive unemployment benefit increases productive efficiency. b. In this paper, we adopt a mechanism design approach and show that the optimal mechanism is implemented by a positive unemployment benefit and, when firms are heterogenous, by a regressive labor earning tax.

Environment Workers Firms Labor market

Environment Workers: i. continuum of homogeneous workers with measure 1; ii. preferences: u(c) with u (c) > 0, u (c) < 0; iii. endowment: one job application and one unit of labor.

Environment Firms: i. continuum of heterogeneous firms with density f(y) over support [y, y]; ii. technology: 1 unit of labor y units of output.

Environment Labor market: Directed search (e.g. Montgomery 1991, Moen 1997, Shimer 1996): 1. firms choose which wage w to offer; 2. workers choose whether to send an application at the cost k and, if so, which wage to seek with it; 3. firms and workers offering and seeking the same wage w come together through a frictional matching process: i. worker matches with a firm w.p. λ(q(w)) where λ < 0, ii. firm matches with a worker w.p. η(q(w)) where η > 0, η < 0.

Environment Information structure: i. workers are anonymous; ii. worker s application is private information; iii. firm s productivity is private information.

Plan of the talk Paper characterizes the optimal insurance mechanism for this economy: 1. Consider the mechanism design problem under full information. We will refer to the solution of this problem as the unconstrained efficient allocation. 2. Consider the competitive search equilibrium of the labor market and compare it with the unconstrained efficient allocation. 3. Consider the mechanism design problem under private information. We will refer to the solution of this problem as the constrained efficient allocation. 4. Show how the constrained efficient allocation can be implemented.

Unconstrained Efficient allocation The planner maximizes the worker s expected utility max q y,c y,b q y [λ(q y )u(c y ) + (1 λ(q y ))u(b)] f(y)dy subject to the resource constraints qy f(y)dy = 1, η(qy )yf(y)dy = q y [λ(q y )c y + (1 λ(q y ))b] f(y)dy. Remark: If the planner can observe worker s applications and firm s productivity, it can assign a queue q y to each firm and consumption c y, b to each worker conditional on their employment state.

Unconstrained Efficient allocation 1. The efficient allocation of applicants, q y, is such that η (q y)y = µ, if y y c µ /η (0), q y = 0, if y y c µ /η (0). 2. The efficient allocation of output c y, b is such that c y = b = 1 m η(q y)yf(y)dy. 3. The multiplier µ on the application resource constraint is such that q yf(y)dy = 1.

Unconstrained Efficient allocation Remarks on the efficient allocation: 1. In the efficient allocation, the marginal productivity of applicants is equalized across different firms. Hence, the efficient allocation maximizes aggregate output. 2. In the efficient allocation, the marginal utility of consumption is equalized across workers. Hence, the efficient allocation maximizes expected utility given aggregate output. 3. The efficient allocation could be decentralized if there was a Walrasian market for job applications in which workers sell and firms purchase applications at the unit price µ.

Competitive search equilibrium A competitive search equilibrium is a {w(y), q(w), c(y), b, S} such that: 1. Profit maximization: 2. Optimal search: w(y) = arg max η(q(w))(y w); λ(q(w)) [u(b + w) u(b)] S and q(w) 0 (with c.s.); 3. Market clearing: q(w(y))f(y)dy 1 and S k (with c.s.); 4. Consumption: c(y) = b + w(y), b = 1 m η(q(w(y))) [y w(y)] f(y)dy.

Competitive search equilibrium 1. The equilibrium allocation of applicants q(y) is such that q(y) = arg max η(q)y p(q S, b)q, q [ ( ) ] S p(q S, b) = λ(q) u 1 λ(q) + u(b) b. 2. The equilibrium allocation of consumption is such that ( ) S c(y) b = u 1 λ(q(y)) + u(b). 3. The equilibrium value of searching is such that q(w(y))f(y)dy = 1.

Competitive search equilibrium Proposition 1 (Inefficiency of equilibrium) 1. The equilibrium allocation of applicants is inefficient: There is a y 0 (yc, y) such that q(y) > q (y) for y [yc, y 0 ), q(y) < q (y) for y (y 0, y]. 2. The equilibrium allocation of output is inefficient: c(y) b > c (y) b = 0 for y [y c, y].

Competitive search equilibrium Comments on proposition 1: 1. The marginal productivity of applicants is inefficiently small at low productivity firms and inefficiently large at high productivity firms. Hence, the equilibrium allocation does not maximize aggregate output. 2. The marginal utility of consumption is not equalized across workers in different employment states. Hence, the equilibrium allocation does not maximize expected utility (given aggregate output). 3. The equilibrium is inefficient because the worker s application is rewarded only if it is successful. Hence, workers face an income risk associated with the application process and need to be compensated for it by firms. Since the risk premium is increasing in the queue length, productive firms choose to attract an inefficiently small number of applicants.

Competitive search equilibrium Sketch of the proof of proposition 1: The unconstrained efficient queue q (y) solves max η(q)y µ q. The associated first order condition is η (q (y))y = µ, which implies q (y) = η (q (y))y η (q (y)).

Competitive search equilibrium Sketch of the proof of proposition 1: The equilibrium queue q(y) solves q(y) = arg max η(q)y p(q)q, q [ ( ) S p(q) = λ(q) u 1 λ(q) + u(b) The associated first order condition is which implies q (y) = η (q(y))y = p (q(y))q(y) + p(q(y)), ] b. η (q(y))y η (q(y)) + 2p (q(y)) + p (q(y))q(y).

Competitive search equilibrium Sketch of the proof of proposition 1: The unconstrained efficient and equilibrium queues are such that q (y) = η (q (y))y η (q (y)), q η (q(y))y (y) = η (q(y)) + 2p (q(y)) + p (q(y))q(y). 1. Using these derivatives, we show that q (y) = q(y) = q (y) > q (y). 2. There is at most one y 0 s.t. q (y 0 ) = q(y 0 ). 3. Since q and q integrate to 1, there is a y 0 s.t. q (y 0 ) = q(y 0 ).

Constrained Efficient allocation The optimal mechanism maximizes the worker s expected utility max q y,c y,b,s,w y q y [λ(q y )u(c y ) + (1 λ(q y ))u(b)] f(y)dy

Constrained Efficient allocation The optimal mechanism maximizes the worker s expected utility max q y,c y,b,s,w y q y [λ(q y )u(c y ) + (1 λ(q y ))u(b)] f(y)dy subject to 1. the incentive compatibility constraint for workers k S, λ(q y ) [u(c y ) u(b)] S and q y 0,

Constrained Efficient allocation The optimal mechanism maximizes the worker s expected utility max q y,c y,b,s,w y q y [λ(q y )u(c y ) + (1 λ(q y ))u(b)] f(y)dy subject to 2. the incentive compatibility constraint for firms η(q y ) [y W y ] η(q y ) [ y W y ] all y [y, y],

Constrained Efficient allocation The optimal mechanism maximizes the worker s expected utility max q y,c y,b,s,w y q y [λ(q y )u(c y ) + (1 λ(q y ))u(b)] f(y)dy subject to 3. the resource constraints qy f(y)dy = 1, η(qy )yf(y)dy = q y [λ(q y )c y + (1 λ(q y ))b] f(y)dy.

Constrained Efficient allocation 1. The optimal allocation of applicants ˆq y is such that η (ˆq y )y = λ(ˆq y )ĉ y + (1 λ(ˆq y ))ˆb [ ] λ u(ĉ y ) u(ˆb) (ˆq y )ˆq y u (ĉ y (ĉ y ) ˆb) + ˆµ 1. ˆµ 2 2. The optimal value of searching Ŝ is Ŝ = k. 3. The optimal consumption ˆb, ĉ y is such that ( ) Ŝ ĉ y = u 1 λ(ˆq y ) + u(ˆb).

Constrained Efficient allocation 1. The optimal allocation of applicants ˆq y is such that η (ˆq y )y = λ(ˆq y )ĉ y + (1 λ(ˆq y ))ˆb [ ] λ u(ĉ y ) u(ˆb) (ˆq y )ˆq y u (ĉ y (ĉ y ) ˆb) + ˆµ 1. ˆµ 2 2. The optimal value of searching Ŝ is Ŝ = k. 4. The multipliers ˆµ 1, ˆµ 2 are such that ˆqy f(y)dy = 1, η(ˆqy )yf(y)dy = [ ] ˆq y λ(ˆq y )ĉ y + (1 λ(ˆq y ))ˆb f(y)dy.

Constrained Efficient allocation Proposition 2 (Properties of the constrained efficient allocation) 1. There is a y 1 (ŷ c, y) such that There is a y 2 (y c, y) such that ˆq(y) < q(y) for y [ŷ c, y 1 ), ˆq(y) > q(y) for y (y 1, y]. ˆq(y) > q (y) for y [yc, y 2 ), ˆq(y) < q (y) for y (y 2, y]. Hence, in the constrained efficient allocation, aggregate output is greater than in equilibrium, but lower than in the full information allocation.

Constrained Efficient allocation Proposition 2 (Properties of the constrained efficient allocation) 2. Let L be defined as L(c, b, q) = u(λ(q)c + (1 λ(q))b) [λ(q)u(c) + (1 λ(q))u(b)]. For all q > 0, we have L(ĉ(q), ˆb, q) < L(c(q), b, q) L(ĉ(q), ˆb, q) > L(c (q), b, q) = 0. Hence, in the constrained efficient allocation, attaining the same q requires a smaller loss in expected utility than in equilibrium, but a higher loss than in the full information allocation.

Constrained Efficient allocation Intuition for proposition 2: 1. The mechanism sets the value of searching Ŝ to k, the lowest value compatible with the workers incentive to send a job application. 2. Since Ŝ < S, the mechanism reduces the income risk faced by a worker who joins a queue of length q and, hence, it reduces the utility loss of assigning q applicants to a firm. 3. Since the utility loss of assigning q applicants to a firm is smaller than in equilibrium, the mechanism can increase the number of applicants assigned to high productivity firms.

Constrained Efficient allocation Sketch of the proof of proposition 2: The optimal queue ˆq(y) solves ˆq(y) = arg max η(q)y p(q Ŝ, ˆb)q (ˆµ 1 /ˆµ 2 )q, q [ ( ) ] p(q Ŝ, ˆb) Ŝ = λ(q) u 1 λ(q) + u(ˆb) ˆb. The associated first order condition is η (ˆq(y))y = p (ˆq(y) Ŝ, ˆb)ˆq(y) + p(ˆq(y) Ŝ, ˆb) + ˆµ 1 /ˆµ 2, which implies ˆq (y) = η (ˆq(y))y η (ˆq(y)) + 2p (ˆq(y) Ŝ, ˆb). + p (ˆq(y) Ŝ, ˆb)ˆq(y)

Constrained Efficient allocation Sketch of the proof of proposition 2: The equilibrium queue q(y) solves q(y) = arg max η(q)y p(q S, b)q, q [ ( ) ] S p(q S, b) = λ(q) u 1 λ(q) + u(b) b. The associated first order condition is which implies q (y) = η (q(y))y = p (q(y) S, b)q(y) + p(q(y) S, b), η (q(y))y η (q(y)) + 2p (q(y) S, b) + p (q(y) S, b)q(y).

Constrained Efficient allocation Sketch of the proof of proposition 2: The optimal and equilibrium queues are such that ˆq (y) = η (ˆq(y))y η (ˆq(y)) + 2ˆp (ˆq(y) Ŝ, ˆb), + ˆp (ˆq(y) Ŝ, ˆb)ˆq(y) q (y) = η (q(y))y η (q(y)) + 2p (q(y) S, b) + p (q(y) S, b)q(y). 1. Using these derivatives, we show that ˆq(y) = q(y) = ˆq (y) > q (y). 2. There is at most one y 1 s.t. ˆq(y 1 ) = q(y 1 ). 3. Since ˆq and q integrate to 1, there is a y 1 s.t. ˆq(y 1 ) = q(y 1 ).

Implementation of the Constrained Efficient allocation Proposition 3. The constrained efficient allocation can be implemented in a labor market with the following policies: 1. the minimum wage e = ŷ c, 2. the unemployment benefit B u = ˆµ 1 /ˆµ 2 > 0 3. the increasing and concave labor earning tax T e (e(q)) = ˆµ 1 1 λ(q) 0. ˆµ 2 λ(q)

Implementation of the Constrained Efficient allocation Intuition for proposition 3: 1. In equilibrium, the value of searching S plays two roles: a. S guarantees that demand and supply of applicants are equal. b. S determines the income risk that workers face when joining a queue of length q. 2. The mechanism sets Ŝ = k so as to minimize the worker s income risk. This can be accomplished with a positive B u. 3. However, for Ŝ = k, there is no guarantee that demand and supply of applicants will be equal. Indeed, for Ŝ = k, there is excess demand. In order to lower demand, it is necessary to increase the price firms pay for applicants without increasing Ŝ. This is accomplished with a positive, increasing and concave T e.

Implementation of the Constrained Efficient allocation Sketch of the proof of proposition 3: The constrained efficient queue ˆq(y) solves max η(q)[y w(q)] (ˆµ 1 /ˆµ 2 )q s.t. λ(q)[u(b + w(q)) u(b)] = k. If the policy (B u, T e ) implements the constrained efficient allocation, ˆq(y) must also solve max η(q)[y w(q) B u T (q)] s.t. λ(q)[u(b + w(q)) u(b)] = k, T (q) T e (e(q)), e(q) w(q) + B u + T (q).

Implementation of the Constrained Efficient allocation Sketch of the proof of proposition 3: If the policy (B u, T e ) implements the constrained efficient allocation, T (q) must be such that η(q) [B u + T (q)] = (ˆµ 1 /ˆµ 2 )q T (q) = ˆµ 1 ˆµ 2 1 λ(q) B u

Implementation of the Constrained Efficient allocation Sketch of the proof of proposition 3: In order to recover the labor earning tax T e, note that T (q) = (ˆµ 1 /ˆµ 2 )/λ(q) B u, T e (e(q)) = T (q), e(q) = w(q) + B u + T (q). Since the previous equations must hold for all q, we have T (q) = T e(e(q)) [w (q) + T (q)] [ = T ˆµ e(e(q)) λ (q) 2 λ(q) 2 λ (q) λ(q) 2 ˆµ 1 T e(e(q)) = ˆµ 1 ˆµ 2 [ ˆµ1 ˆµ 2 + k u (ĉ(q)) ] k u (ĉ(q)) λ (q) ˆµ 1 ] λ(q) 2 ˆµ 2 1.

Implementation of the Constrained Efficient allocation Sketch of the proof of proposition 3: In order to find the optimal unemployment benefit B u, note that q y [λ(q y )T (q y ) (1 λ(q y ))B u ] f(y)dy = 0. Using the optimality condition for T (q), we can rewrite this as [ ] ] ˆµ1 1 q y [λ(q y ) ˆµ 2 λ(q y ) B u (1 λ(q y ))B u f(y)dy = 0, which implies B u = ˆµ 1 ˆµ 2 > 0.

Conclusion 1. When labor market is subject to search frictions, decentralizing the constrained efficient allocation would require setting up a competitive market for search inputs requires a great deal of information (e.g. which workers did actually search and how hard they searched..) 2. In some special cases, a market for labor is equivalent to a market for search inputs: a. risk neutrality, bargaining and Mortensen rule (Mortensen 1982) b. risk neutrality and posting (Moen 1997, Shimer 1996) 3. Apart from those special cases, a labor market is not equivalent to a market for search inputs. Then, labor market policies (unemployment benefits and labor taxes) are needed to achieve constrained efficiency.