MEASURING THE SOCIO-ECONOMIC BIPOLARIZATION PHENOMENON

Similar documents
Stochastic Dominance

On Measuring Growth and Inequality. Components of Changes in Poverty. with Application to Thailand

DECOMPOSITION OF NORMALIZATION AXIOM IN THE MEASUREMENT OF POVERTY: A COMMENT. Nanak Kakwani. Nanak Kakwani is a Senior Fellow at WIDER.

CIRPÉE Centre interuniversitaire sur le risque, les politiques économiques et l emploi

Inequality and Envy. Frank Cowell and Udo Ebert. London School of Economics and Universität Oldenburg

Bayesian Assessment of Lorenz and Stochastic Dominance in Income Distributions

Analyzing the health status of the population using ordinal data

On the relationship between objective and subjective inequality indices and the natural rate of subjective inequality

The measurement of welfare change

Variance estimation for Generalized Entropy and Atkinson indices: the complex survey data case

Rethinking Inequality Decomposition: Comment. *London School of Economics. University of Milan and Econpubblica

Robust Non-Parametric Techniques to Estimate the Growth Elasticity of Poverty

Household Heterogeneity and Inequality Measurement

CIRPÉE Centre interuniversitaire sur le risque, les politiques économiques et l emploi

Inequality Measures and the Median:

Unit-consistency and polarization of income distributions

Multifactor Inequality: Substitution Effects for Income Sources in Mexico

The Role of Inequality in Poverty Measurement

Rolf Aaberge and Magne Mogstad

Estimating Income Distributions Using a Mixture of Gamma. Densities

Math 142 Lecture Notes. Section 7.1 Area between curves

THE EXTENDED ATKINSON FAMILY: THE CLASS OF MULTIPLICATIVELY DECOMPOSABLE INEQUALITY MEASURES, AND SOME NEW GRAPHICAL PROCEDURES FOR ANALYSTS

Measurement of Inequality and Social Welfare

! 2005 "# $% & !! "#! ,%-)./*(0/ #1 %! 2*- 3434%*1$ * )#%'(*- % *

Decomposing changes in multidimensional poverty in 10 countries.

Reference Groups and Individual Deprivation

ESTIMATING INCOME INEQUALITY IN CHINA USING GROUPED DATA AND THE GENERALIZED BETA DISTRIBUTION. Monash University, Melbourne

Inequality, poverty and redistribution

Stochastic Dominance in Polarization Work in progress. Please do not quote

Order Statistics and Distributions

The Measurement of Inequality, Concentration, and Diversification.

Discontinuous Transformations and Lorenz Curves

Poverty measures and poverty orderings

An econophysical approach of polynomial distribution applied to income and expenditure

PRESENTATION ON THE TOPIC ON INEQUALITY COMPARISONS PRESENTED BY MAG.SYED ZAFAR SAEED

Legendre-Fenchel transforms in a nutshell

Adjusting the HDI for Inequality: An Overview of Different Approaches, Data Issues, and Interpretations

Inequality Measurement and the Rich: Why inequality increased more than we thought

Inequality decomposition by population subgroups for ordinal data

The integral test and estimates of sums

An econophysical approach of polynomial distribution applied to income and expenditure

Evaluating Dimensional and Distributional Contributions to Multidimensional Poverty

Multidimensional inequality comparisons

Poverty and Distributional Outcomes of Shocks and Policies

A head-count measure of rank mobility and its directional decomposition

Ranking income distributions: a rank-dependent and needs-based approach

Multivariate Distribution Models

Discussion Papers. Satya R. Chakravarty, Conchita D Ambrosio and Pietro Muliere. Target Shortfall Orderings and Indices

( )! ±" and g( x)! ±" ], or ( )! 0 ] as x! c, x! c, x! c, or x! ±". If f!(x) g!(x) "!,

CHAPTER 2 A Function for Size Distribution of Incomes

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Bayesian Estimation of Zenga Curve Using Different Priors In Case of Pareto Distribution

Counting and Multidimensional Poverty Measurement

INEQUALITY, WELFARE AND ORDER STATISTICS

Measuring the shape of degree distributions

Statistics 100A Homework 5 Solutions

CS434a/541a: Pattern Recognition Prof. Olga Veksler. Lecture 1

Chapter 4. Continuous Random Variables 4.1 PDF

Measuring relative equality of concentration between different. income/wealth distributions

1 Review of di erential calculus

Lecture 11: Probability, Order Statistics and Sampling

Selection of small area estimation method for Poverty Mapping: A Conceptual Framework

By W.E. Diewert, January, CHAPTER 5: The Theory of the Cost of Living Index: The Many Consumer Case

Random variables. DS GA 1002 Probability and Statistics for Data Science.

Introduction to Information Entropy Adapted from Papoulis (1991)

September Math Course: First Order Derivative

Survey nonresponse and the distribution of income

Legendre-Fenchel transforms in a nutshell

GINI DECOMPOSITION BY GENDER: TURKISH CASE. Ezgi Kaya* and Umit Senesen Bellaterra Barcelona, Spain Macka Istanbul, Turkey

2 Functions of random variables

Arrovian Social Choice with Non -Welfare Attributes

Construction Modelling of Input-Output Coefficients Matrices in an Axiomatic Context: Some Further Considerations.

1 Joint and marginal distributions

Multi-dimensional Human Development Measures : Trade-offs and Inequality

arxiv: v1 [econ.th] 15 Nov 2018

Tests for Richness and Poorness: A Stochastic Dominance Analysis of Income Distributions in Hong Kong

CSCI-6971 Lecture Notes: Monte Carlo integration

Bread and Social Justice: Measurement of Inequality and Social Welfare Using Anthropometrics

ACE 562 Fall Lecture 2: Probability, Random Variables and Distributions. by Professor Scott H. Irwin

ECE 4400:693 - Information Theory

Poverty statistics in Mongolia

ON THE TRUNCATED COMPOSITE WEIBULL-PARETO MODEL

Multidimensional Poverty Measurement and Analysis

Defence Spending and Economic Growth: Re-examining the Issue of Causality for Pakistan and India

An explicit dynamic model of segregation

3 Continuous Random Variables

Poverty, Inequality and Growth: Empirical Issues

Consistent Comparison of Pro-Poor Growth

Definition: If y = f(x), then. f(x + x) f(x) y = f (x) = lim. Rules and formulas: 1. If f(x) = C (a constant function), then f (x) = 0.

APPLICATION OF THE COUNTRY PRODUCT DUMMY METHOD TO CONSTRUCT SPATIAL AND TEMPORAL PRICE INDICES FOR SRI LANKA

Determining Changes in Welfare Distributions at the Micro-level: Updating Poverty Maps By Chris Elbers, Jean O. Lanjouw, and Peter Lanjouw 1

Extensions to the Concentration Index: Inequality Aversion and the Health Achievement Index

Smooth simultaneous confidence bands for cumulative distribution functions

Working Paper Series. Pareto-Lognormal Income Distributions: Inequality and Poverty Measures, Estimation and Performance

EC212: Introduction to Econometrics Review Materials (Wooldridge, Appendix)

Comparing latent inequality with ordinal health data

Estimating Poverty Measures using Truncated Distributions and its Applications

An Introduction to Relative Distribution Methods

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Probability. Lecture Notes. Adolfo J. Rumbos

Transcription:

2 MEASURING THE SOCIO-ECONOMIC BIPOLARIZATION PHENOMENON Abstract Ştefan ŞTEFĂNESCU * The present paper emphasizes the differences between the Gini concentration coefficient [3] and a new bipolarization index proposed by [2], [2]. In practice, the Gini index is applied frequently to determine the poverty degree of the persons of a given population P. Although the pauperization and the polarization social phenomena are often very strong related, we shall prove that the bipolarization level of the individuals of P cannot be always accurately estimated by applying the classical Gini measure. Therefore, for evaluating the intensity of a polarization event is not adequate to use the Gini-type coefficients based on the Lorenz order. Keywords: Gini coefficient, bipolarization index, Lorenz order, antithetic variables, bounded exponential distributions. JEL Classification: C43, C46, C5, C52.. THE FORMULATION OF THE PROBLEM In the literature, the Gini indicator γ * ( W ), γ * ( W ), was designated to estimate the concentration degree of the "small" values produced by the variable W, W > ([], [2], [6], [9], [3], [5], [6], [9], [25]). Thus, if the random variable W characterizes the income values of the individuals of the population P, the Gini index γ * ( W ) measures the poverty level in P. On the contrary, the coefficient * ( W ), * ( W ), proposed in [2], [2], expresses the bipolarization degree for the values of the random variable W. In the papers [7], [] or [26] other new measures of the polarization phenomenon are analyzed. By using many practical examples, the specialized literature ([]-[27]) emphasizes often the presence of a strong interdependence between the socio-economic pauperization of the individuals in P and the bipolarization effect. Based on this dependence relation it is frequently accredited in practice the wrong idea that Gini's concentration coefficient * Associate Professor, Ph.D., Faculty of Mathematics and Informatics, University of Bucharest, e- mail : stefanst@fmi.unibuc.ro. Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting /28 49

Institute of Economic Forecasting γ * ( W ) could also be used to estimate the intensity of the income polarization phenomenon of the persons of the population P. In the present paper we intend to invalidate such a methodological approach, which could impose unsuitable conclusions and inadequate decisions (see also the opinions mentioned in [4] and [26]). Pragmatically, taking into consideration a family of distributions for the random variable W, we shall attempt to reveal essential behavioral differences between both indicators, γ * ( W ) and * ( W ). Such a result is in accordance with the fundamental sociological research since the polarization action of the individuals of P is not always identical with the poverty concentration phenomenon in P (see also [2], [6], [8], [9], [3]-[7], [23]-[25]). 2. THE BOUNDED EXPONENTIAL DISTRIBUTION Let the parameter R. Definition. The random variable (r.v.) X with the support [, ] is exponentially distributed, X ~ Exp(), if its probability density function (p.d.f.) f( x; ) has the form: x e /( e ) ; for f( x; ), x () ; for We get the following cumulative function (c.d.f.) Fx ( ; ) for X ~ Exp(), x ( e )/( e ) ; when Fx ( ; ) x ; when, x (2) We shall designate by U([, ]) the uniform distribution on the interval [, ]. Remark. The distribution U([, ]) belongs to the distribution family Exp(), R, since Exp() U([, ]). Proposition. If > (respectively < ) then the p.d.f. f( x; ) is a strict increasing (decreasing ) function. Proof. Indeed the derivative function f( x; ), f( x; ) 2 e x x e is strictly positive (negative) for > (respectively < ). Depending on the real values of the parameter, the graphics G, G2 give the shape of the p.d.f.-s f( x; ). Proposition 2. For any x and R we have the equality 5 Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting /28

Fx ( ; ) + F( x; ) 3) Proof. Taking into consideration the variants, and respectively, and applying the formula (2) we deduce the relation (3). When q and R we define the expression ( ) ln + q( e ) / ; for Qq ( ; ) (4) q ; for Proposition 3. For every fixed R the expression Qq ( ; ), q, is just the inverse of the c.d.f. Fx ( ; ), x. Proof. In the case this property is true since, for an arbitrary x, we have Qq ( ; ) q Fx ( ; ) x. After a direct calculation, when we obtain the relations : qe ( ) FQq ( ( ; ); ) + q e x ln( e ) QFx ( ( ; ); ) x with x. In the following, we shall denote by µ ( ) the expectation value of the r.v. X ~ Exp(), that is µ ( ) Mean( X ), R. Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting /28 5

Institute of Economic Forecasting Proposition 4. For any R we have ( e e + )/( e ); for µ ( ) /2 ; for Proof. When we deduce: If then integrating by parts we get: + + µ( ) xf( x; ) dx xdx 2 x e µ ( ) xf( x; ) dx xe /( e ) dx e Proposition 5. The following equality is true for an arbitrary R, µ ( ) + µ ( ) (6) Proof. Indeed µ ( ) + µ ( ) 2 + 2 In the case it results µ ( ) + µ ( ) + e e + e e (5) 52 Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting /28

3. GINI'S MEASURE We shall designate by Lu ( ; ), u, R, the classical Lorenz curve attached to the random variable X ~ Exp(), [3], [27]. Proposition 6. The function Lu ( ; ), u, R has the expression: ( + ue ( )) ln( + ue ( )) ue ( ) ; for Lu ( ; ) e e + (7) 2 u ; for Proof. Respecting the previous notations, the Lorenz curve Lu ( ; ) is given by the following formula (see [3]), u h ( u; ) Lu ( ; ) Qq ( ; ) dq / Qq ( ; ) dq h (; ) u where h ( u; ) Q( q; ) dq. If we establish the specific form of the function h( u; ) we shall deduce after a straightforward calculus the expression (7). So, we deduce: u u 2 u h ( u; ) Q( q; ) dq q dq 2 When it results: u u ln( + q( e ) h ( u; ) Q( q;) dq dq ( + ue ( )) ln( + ue ( )) ue ( ) e e + To simplify the notation, we shall denote by γ ( ), R, the Gini coefficient associated to the r.v. X ~ Exp(), more exactly γ ( ) γ ( X ). Proposition 7. The Gini coefficient γ ( ), R, has the form: 2 e 2e / 2( e e + )( e ) ; for γ( ) / 3 ; for Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting /28 53 * (8)

Institute of Economic Forecasting Proof. Based on the Lorenz curve, the indicator Gini has the expression ( [3] ): γ( ) 2 Lu ( ; ) du Using the explicit form (7) for the Lorenz curve we deduce: 2 γ ( ) 2 Lu ( ; ) du 2u du 3 Moreover, in the case we get: γ( ) 2 Lu ( ; ) du 2 ( + ue ( )) ln( + ue ( )) ue ( ) du e e + + 2 2 2 2 2 2 e e ( e ) e 2e 2( e e + )( e ) 2( e e + )( e ) Proposition 8. If, then: γ( ) e (9) γ( ) e e + Proof. Indeed, applying Proposition 7 it results: 2 γ ( ) e 2 e γ( ) ( )( ). 2( e e + )( e ) e 2 2 e e + e e + 2e e e + 4. A BIPOLARIZATION INDEX In the papers [2] and [2] we proposed the indicator ( W ) to measure the bipolarization level for any r.v. W which has a bounded support [ a, b ]. The main idea for designing the index ( W ) was to define an appropriate partition { I I }, 2 of the domain[ a, b ], I { x a x µ } I2 { x µ < x b} and, at the same time, to establish the suitable separation threshold µ between the two disjointed groups I and I 2. In [2], [2] we considered the average of the r.v. W as a cut point, that is µ Mean( W). 54 Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting /28

The indicator ( W ) will measure the distance between the "poles" µ and µ 2 of the groups I and I 2, taking also into consideration the "weights" p, respectively p, of these groups. More exactly: µ Mean( W I) µ wg( w) dw p a µ Mean( W I ) 2 2 b wg( w) p dw µ µ p Pr( W µ ) g( w) dw p Pr( W > µ ) g( w) dw a µ where g( w), a w b, is the p.d.f. of the r.v. W. Definition 2 ([2], [2]). The bipolarization indicator * ( W ) of the r.v. W is given by the expression: 4p( p)( µ 2 µ ) * ( W ) () b a In the following, we shall analyze the behavior of the polarization index ( ), R, where ( ) ( X ) * with X ~ Exp(). To simplify the calculus, we shall use the function δ ( x ; ), x, R, defined by x ( x ) e / ( e ) ; for δ( x ; ) 2 () x / 2 ; for Proposition 9. The expression δ ( x ; ), x, is a primitive of the function xf( x; ). Proof. Indeed, keeping the previous notations and taking into consideration the distinct cases and respectively, after a straightforward calculation we get: δ( x ; ) xf( x; ) (2) x Proposition. For every and x the equality: x e δ( x; ) δ( x; ) is true (3) e Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting /28 55 b

Institute of Economic Forecasting Proof. If then x ( x) ( x ) e ( ( x) + ) e x e δ( x; ) δ( x; ) ( e ) ( e ) e Proposition. Respecting the previous notations, the bipolarization indicator ( ) R, has the form: ( ) 4F ( µ ( ); ) δ( ; ) δ( ; ) 4 δ ( µ ( ); ) δ( ; ) (4) Proof. We shall apply the formula () for W X with X ~ Exp(), that is a b µ µ ( ) p F( µ ( ); ) gx ( ) f( x; ) Using Proposition 9, it results that: µ ( ) ( ) ( X) 4p xf( x; ) dx4( p) xf( x; ) dx * µ ( ) µ ( ) 4p x f( x; ) dx 4 x f( x; ) dx 4F( µ ( ); ) δ( ; ) δ( ; ) 4 δ ( µ ( ); ) δ( ; ) Proposition 2. The bipolarization ( ) is a symmetrical function, that is ( ) ( ), R (5) Proof. For any fixed it is sufficient to prove the relation ( ) ( ). Indeed, by applying Propositions 2, 5, and we obtain in order 4F ( ) 4( ) F( µ ( ); ) (( δ( ; ) δ( ; ) ) ( δ( ; ) δ( ; ))) ( δ( ; ) δ( ; ) ) ( δ ( µ ( ); ) δ ( µ ( ); ) ) ( ) ( ) ( µ ( ); ) δ( ; ) δ( ; ) δ ( µ ( ); ) δ( ; ) 4F( µ ( ); ) δ( ; ) δ( ; ) + 4 δ ( µ ( ); ) δ( ; ) 4 + + + 4 4 µ ( ) 4 4 (( ) ( )) + 4e F( µ ( ); ) δ( ; ) δ( ; ) δ( ; ) δ( ; ) e e µ ( ) e 4 + 4 4e F( µ ( ); ) e e e e µ ( ) e 4F( µ ( ); ) 4 4F( µ ( ); ) 4F( µ ( ); ) e, 56 Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting /28

5. COMPARING THE INDICES γ( ) AND () Proposition 3. All the functions f( x; ), Fx ( ; ), µ ( ), γ ( ), δ( x ; ), Qq ( ; ), Lu ( ; ), ( ) are continuous, depending on the variable, R. Proof. Having in mind the particular form of the mentioned functions, it remains to show that the continuity property is maintained in the point, too. So, let h 2 ( ) be one of the expressions f( x; ), Fx ( ; ), µ ( ), γ ( ), δ( x ; ), Qq ( ; ), Lu ( ; ). Applying a direct derivative calculus based on the l'hospital rule it results that: lim h2 ( ) h2 ( ) In addition, the continuity of the function ( ) results easily by analyzing the particular form of the expression (4). Proposition 4. The following equalities are true: γ ( ) γ ( ) γ ( ) 2 3 ( ) ( ) ( ) (6) 2 Proof. Using the formula (8), we get γ ( ) / 3 and, in addition: 2 e 2e γ( ) γ( ) lim lim ( + )( ) 2 e e e 2 2 2 γ( ) lim γ( ) lim Applying Propositions and 2, we have successively ( ) 4F ( µ ( ); ) δ( ; ) δ( ; ) 4 δ ( µ ( ); ) δ ( ; ) 2e e lim 2( + e )( e ) 2( ) 2 4 4 2 2 4F( / 2); ) / 2 4 / 2 / 2 ( ) ( ) lim 4F( µ ( ); ) δ( ; ) δ( ; ) 4 δµ ( ( ); ) δ( ; ) ( δ δ ) ( δ µ δ ) lim 4 ( ; ) ( ; ) 4 ( ( ); ) ( ; ) Proposition 5. If X ~ Exp() and Y X then it results that Y ~ Exp(-). Proof. Obviously, if then we have X ~ U([, ]) and Y ~ U([, ]). Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting /28 57

Institute of Economic Forecasting In case that it is sufficient to show that the equality gy ( ; ) f( y; ) is valid for any y where g( y; ) is just the p.d.f. of the r.v. Y. Indeed, using the transformation y x, x, we get, in order: x y g( y; ) f( x; ) f( y; ) e ( ) /( e ) f( y; ) y Remark 2. The r.v. Y X is the antithetic of the variable X. If the variable X defines the income distribution of the individuals of the population P, then Y will characterize the income of the same persons when their status changes, namely the "rich" individuals become "poor" and vice versa. In fact, the antithetic type operation inverts the "rich" with the "poor" persons. Remark 3. From Proposition and the graphics G and G2 it results that at the same time with the increase in the values of the number of "poor" people is diminished in P (the probability to have individuals in P with "small income" decreases). Taking into consideration the theoretical significance of Gini's coefficient ([], [2], [6], [2], [3], [5]), we deduce that γ ( ) must be a non-increasing function. This aspect is in accordance with the interpretation of the graphic G3 or with Table values. Remark 4. The augmentation of the values implies a reduction in the percent of "small" values produced by the r.v. X ~ Exp() (to interpret the graphics G, G2 and Propositions, 4). But this fact does not necessarily impose a monotony property for the bipolarization coefficient ( ) (see, for example, the graphic G3 or Table ). In practice, reducing the percentage of the "poorest" individuals in P does not substantially affect a strong bipolarization phenomenon. This perception is also confirmed by the graphic G3 and by the Table values, too. Remark 5. If the income X of the individuals of P has an exponential Exp() distribution, then the sign of the parameter is changed by inverting the socio-economic 58 Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting /28

status of the people in P (Proposition 5). Logically, the application of an antithetic transformation does not affect the bipolarization level in P. This intuitive perception is theoretically sustained by the relation ( ) ( ) (see Proposition 2 and the symmetrical shape of the function ( ) in graphic G3). Usually we have γ ( ) γ ( ) (Proposition 8, graphic G3, Table ), since the concentration Gini index cannot measure, except for some particular situations, a polarization phenomenon. Table The values of the indices γ(), () depending on (the formulas (8), (4)) - -7-5 -4-3 2 5 9 8 γ().5.5.5.5.5.26.36.56.62.7 ().5.2.29.37.49.74.98.47.63.83 7 6 5 4 3 2 -.5 -.25. γ().82.97.7.44.79.224.277.36.347.333 ().28.24.279.328.384.44.483.496.499.5.25.5 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 γ().39.35.277.224.79.44.7.97.82.7 ().499.496.483.44.384.328.279.24.28.83 9 5 2 3 4 5 7 γ().62.56.36.26.7.3..7.5 ().63.47.98.74.49.37.29.2.5 6. CONCLUDING REMARKS In practice, the pauperization and the socio-economic phenomena of bipolarization are generally strongly interconnected, but they are not identical. The classical Gini coefficient γ * ( X ) measures the "concentration" poverty level in the population P and the index * ( X ), proposed in the papers [2], [2], shows a bipolarization property of the X values. The results presented in the previous sections confirm that both coefficients, γ * ( X ) and * ( X ), are suitable measures for different aspects of the social reality (compare, in the graphic G3, the shape of the functionsγ ( ), ( ) or analyse the monotony of the values in Table ). An Exp(), R, family of distributions was selected to model the income variation in the individuals of the population P. Moreover, the indicators γ ( ), ( ) vary in a continuous manner (Proposition 3). This property permits us to simulate adequately the income dynamics in P. Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting /28 59

Institute of Economic Forecasting In the last years, in Romania it is perceptible the presence of a strong economic bipolarization trend. This aspect could not be practically emphasized by using only the classical Gini measure. Therefore, it is insufficient to describe the socio-economic reality, in time and in space, based exclusively on the poverty concentration coefficientγ * ( X ). A parallel study concerning the variation in the bipolarization indicator * ( X ) or any other polarization indices is absolutely necessary, too (see [7], [], [26]). The present paper proved that, in general, it is inadequate to use the Gini coefficient γ * ( X ) for measuring the bipolarization degree inside the population P (Remarks 2-3; graphic G3). Thus, we recommend applying also the * ( X ) indicator to emphasize a grouping phenomenon in P (Remarks 4-5). In fact, the Gini index γ * ( X ) estimates only the "poverty level" for a given population. References C. D'Ambrosio, (2), Household characteristics and the distribution of income in Italy - An application of social distance measures, The Review of Income and Wealth, 47 (): 43-64. A.B. Atkinson, (97), On the measurement of inequality, Journal of Economic Theory, 2: 244-263. F. Bourguignon, (979), Decomposable income inequality measures, Econometrica, 47: 9-92. Alain Chateauneuf, Thibault Gajdos and Pierre-Henry Wilthien, (22), The principle of strong diminishing transfer, Journal of Economic Theory, 3: 3-333. F.A. Cowell, (98), On the structure of additive inequality measures, Review of Economic Studies, 47: 52-53. F.A. Cowell, S.P. Jenkins, (995), How much inequality can we explain? A methodology and an application to the United States, The Economic Journal, 5: 42-43. Joan Esteban, Debraj Ray, (994), On the measurement of polarization, Econometrica, 62 (4): 89-852. Joan Esteban, Debraj Ray, (999), Conflict and distribution, Journal of Economic Theory, 87: 379-45. J. Foster, A.K. Sen, (997), On economic inequality, Clarendon Press, Oxford. J. Gastwirth, (975), The estimation of a family of measures of economic inequality, Journal of Econometrics, 3: 6-7. Carlos Gradin, (December 2), Polarization by sub-populations in Spain, 973-99, Review of Income and Wealth, 46 (4): 457-474. 6 Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting /28

N.C. Kakwani, (993), Statistical inference in the measurement of poverty, Review of Economics and Statistics, 75 (3): 632-639. Christian Kleiber and Samuel Kotz, (23), Statistical size distributions in economics and actuarial sciences, John Wiley & Sons - Interscience, New Jersey. J.O. Lanjouw and P. Lanjouw, (2), How to compare apples and oranges - Poverty measurement based on different definitions of consumption, Review of Income and Wealth, 47 (): 25-42. G. Pyatt, (976), On the interpretation and disaggregation of Gini coefficient, The Economic Journal, 86: 243-255. Friedrich Schmid, (993), A general class of poverty measures, Statistical Papers, 34: 89-2. A.F. Shorrocks, (98), The class additively decomposable inequality measures, Econometrica, 48: 63-625. A.F. Shorrocks, (984), Inequality decomposition by population subgroups, Econometrica, 52:369-385. Poliana Ştefanescu, Ştefan Ştefanescu, (2), Extending the Gini index to measure inequality and poverty, Economic Computation and Economic Cybernetics Studies and Research, 35 (-4) : 45-54. Poliana Ştefanescu, Ştefan Ştefanescu, (26), The polarization index for bounded exponential distributions, Economic Computation and Economic Cybernetics Studies and Research, 4 (3-4): 2-28. Poliana Ştefanescu, Ştefan Ştefanescu, (26), The properties of a polarization index for bounded exponential distributions, UPB - Scientific Bulletin, Series A: Applied Mathematics and Physics, 68 (4): 9-2. Bernd Wilfling, (996), Lorenz ordering of power function order statistics, Statistics & Probability Letters, 3: 33-39. M. Wolfson, (994), When inequalities diverge, American Economic Review, 84 (2): 353-358. M. Wolfson, (997), Divergent inequalities - Theory and empirical results, The Review of Income and Wealth, 43 (4): 4-422. S. Yitzhaki, (994), Economic distance and overlapping of distributions, Journal of Econometrics, 6: 47-59. X. Zhang, R. Kanbur, (2), What difference do polarization measures make? - An application to China, Journal of Development Studies, 37: 85-98. Claudio Zoli, (999), Intersecting generalized Lorenz curves and the Gini index, Social Choice and Welfare, 6: 83-96. Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting /28 6