ECON 4160, Autumn term 2017 Lecture 9

Similar documents
ECON 4160, Spring term 2015 Lecture 7

ECON 4160: Econometrics-Modelling and Systems Estimation Lecture 9: Multiple equation models II

A primer on Structural VARs

The regression model with one stochastic regressor (part II)

Dynamic Regression Models (Lect 15)

Time Series Analysis for Macroeconomics and Finance

Structural VAR Models and Applications

Financial Econometrics

ECON 4160, Lecture 11 and 12

ECON 4160, Autumn term Lecture 1

B y t = γ 0 + Γ 1 y t + ε t B(L) y t = γ 0 + ε t ε t iid (0, D) D is diagonal

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

Forecasting. Simultaneous equations bias (Lect 16)

Estimating and Identifying Vector Autoregressions Under Diagonality and Block Exogeneity Restrictions

ECON 4160, Spring term Lecture 12

Title. Description. var intro Introduction to vector autoregressive models

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 4. VARs With Long-Run Restrictions

Lecture 7a: Vector Autoregression (VAR)

The linear regression model: functional form and structural breaks

Class 4: VAR. Macroeconometrics - Fall October 11, Jacek Suda, Banque de France

Bayesian Graphical Models for Structural Vector AutoregressiveMarch Processes 21, / 1

Lecture 7a: Vector Autoregression (VAR)

Simultaneous equation model (structural form)

Structural VARs II. February 17, 2016

ECON 3150/4150, Spring term Lecture 6

Identifying Causal Effects in Time Series Models

Structural Vector Autoregressions with Markov Switching. Markku Lanne University of Helsinki. Helmut Lütkepohl European University Institute, Florence

Lecture: Simultaneous Equation Model (Wooldridge s Book Chapter 16)

VAR Model. (k-variate) VAR(p) model (in the Reduced Form): Y t-2. Y t-1 = A + B 1. Y t + B 2. Y t-p. + ε t. + + B p. where:

Identifying SVARs with Sign Restrictions and Heteroskedasticity

TOPICS IN ADVANCED ECONOMETRICS: SVAR MODELS PART I LESSON 2. Luca Fanelli. University of Bologna.

ECON 3150/4150, Spring term Lecture 7

Econometría 2: Análisis de series de Tiempo

Factor models. March 13, 2017

Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme?

Structural-VAR II. Dean Fantazzini. Dipartimento di Economia Politica e Metodi Quantitativi. University of Pavia

The regression model with one fixed regressor cont d

Assessing Structural VAR s

Generalized Impulse Response Analysis: General or Extreme?

Assessing Structural VAR s

Short Questions (Do two out of three) 15 points each

Closed economy macro dynamics: AD-AS model and RBC model.

ECON 4160: Econometrics-Modelling and Systems Estimation Lecture 7: Single equation models

Assessing Structural VAR s

GMM, HAC estimators, & Standard Errors for Business Cycle Statistics

Factor models. May 11, 2012

Assessing Structural VAR s

Simultaneous Equation Models

Prelim Examination. Friday August 11, Time limit: 150 minutes

Simultaneous Equations and Weak Instruments under Conditionally Heteroscedastic Disturbances

Assessing Structural VAR s

Assessing Structural VAR s

08 Endogenous Right-Hand-Side Variables. Andrius Buteikis,

Final Exam. Economics 835: Econometrics. Fall 2010

1. Shocks. This version: February 15, Nr. 1

Multivariate forecasting with VAR models

Lecture 6: Dynamic panel models 1

1 Class Organization. 2 Introduction

Visualizing VAR s: Regularization and Network Tools for High-Dimensional Financial Econometrics

Economics 472. Lecture 10. where we will refer to y t as a m-vector of endogenous variables, x t as a q-vector of exogenous variables,

Inference Based on SVARs Identified with Sign and Zero Restrictions: Theory and Applications

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Decomposing the Effects of Monetary Policy Using an External Instruments SVAR

The Estimation of Simultaneous Equation Models under Conditional Heteroscedasticity

Computational Macroeconomics. Prof. Dr. Maik Wolters Friedrich Schiller University Jena

Dynamic Factor Models and Factor Augmented Vector Autoregressions. Lawrence J. Christiano

Econometric Methods and Applications II Chapter 2: Simultaneous equations. Econometric Methods and Applications II, Chapter 2, Slide 1

MFx Macroeconomic Forecasting

Stock Prices, News, and Economic Fluctuations: Comment

Nonperforming Loans and Rules of Monetary Policy

Spatial Regression. 13. Spatial Panels (1) Luc Anselin. Copyright 2017 by Luc Anselin, All Rights Reserved

(I AL BL 2 )z t = (I CL)ζ t, where

When Do Wold Orderings and Long-Run Recursive Identifying Restrictions Yield Identical Results?

COMMENT ON DEL NEGRO, SCHORFHEIDE, SMETS AND WOUTERS COMMENT ON DEL NEGRO, SCHORFHEIDE, SMETS AND WOUTERS

Web Appendix for The Dynamics of Reciprocity, Accountability, and Credibility

ECO 310: Empirical Industrial Organization Lecture 2 - Estimation of Demand and Supply

Lecture 1: Information and Structural VARs

LECTURE 3 The Effects of Monetary Changes: Statistical Identification. September 5, 2018

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case.

Macroeconometric modelling

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

Simultaneous Equation Models Learning Objectives Introduction Introduction (2) Introduction (3) Solving the Model structural equations

1 Teaching notes on structural VARs.

Notes on Time Series Modeling

E 31501/4150 Properties of OLS estimators (Monte Carlo Analysis)

Switching Regime Estimation

Formulating, Estimating, and Solving Dynamic Equilibrium Models: an Introduction. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

Lecture 7: Dynamic panel models 2

Identification in Structural VAR models with different volatility regimes

Single-Equation GMM: Endogeneity Bias

ECON 3150/4150 spring term 2014: Exercise set for the first seminar and DIY exercises for the first few weeks of the course

Gaussian Mixture Approximations of Impulse Responses and the Non-Linear Effects of Monetary Shocks

Dealing With Endogeneity

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

A. Recursively orthogonalized. VARs

Identification of Economic Shocks by Inequality Constraints in Bayesian Structural Vector Autoregression

ECONOMETRIC THEORY. MODULE XVII Lecture - 43 Simultaneous Equations Models

News Shocks, Information Flows and SVARs

New Introduction to Multiple Time Series Analysis

Modern Macroeconomics and Regional Economic Modeling

Vector Autoregression Analysis: Estimation and Interpretation

Transcription:

ECON 4160, Autumn term 2017 Lecture 9 Structural VAR (SVAR) Ragnar Nymoen Department of Economics 26 Oct 2017 1 / 14

Parameter of interest: impulse responses I Consider again a partial market equilibrium example, as in Lecture 8, and with first order dynamics: Q t + b 12 P t = b 10 + φ 11 Q t 1 + φ 12 P t 1 + ɛ 1t, (1) b 12 > 0, φ 11 = 0, φ 12 = 0 (demand) b 21 Q 1t + P t = b 20 + φ 21 Q t 1 + φ 22 P t 1 + ɛ 2t, (2) b 12 < 0, φ 21 = 0, φ 22 = 0 (supply) with symmetric, but not diagonal covariance matrix Ω (hence ω 12 = 0 in general). This SEM is not identified on the O/R conditions. Hence there are no consistent estimators for any of the structural coeffi cients. 2 / 14

Parameter of interest: impulse responses II But assume that we do not mind that, because our interest is how the two endogenous variables respond dynamically to random shocks (also called impulses). Those response functions can be found from the reduced form,the VAR(1): ( Qt P t ) = ( ϕ10 ϕ 20 and are partial derivatives: ) ( ϕ11 ϕ + 12 ϕ 21 ϕ 22 ) ( Q1t 1 P 2t 1 ) ( ε1t + ε 2t ) (3) Q t+h and P t+h, h = 0, 1, 2,..., j = 1, 2. of the solutions for Q t and P t. 3 / 14

Parameter of interest: impulse responses III Since only reduced form coeffi cients are used in the expressions for Q t+h, the responses are consistently estimated by OLS. But in another important sense the VAR impulse responses are not identified: We cannot identify the shock (impulses) as demand-shocks or supply shocks, because ε 1t and ε 2t are composite errors: ɛ 1t ε 1t = b 12ɛ 2t 1 b 12 b 21 1 b 12 b 21 (4) ε 2t = b 21ɛ 1t ɛ 2t + 1 b 12 b 21 1 b 12 b 21 (5) 4 / 14

Parameter of interest: impulse responses IV Hence, we cannot say whether for example Q t+h is due to an impulse to demand (ɛ 1t changes) or to supply (ɛ 2t changes), without making further assumptions. 5 / 14

Cholesky decomposition I The most popular way of identifying impulse responses, is known by the technical name Cholesky decompostion. In our example, applying a Cholesky decompostion amounts to imposing a restriction: b 21 = 0 (lower triangularization), or b 12 = 0 (upper triangularization). Setting b 21 = 0, implies for the VAR error-terms: ε 1t = b21 =0 ɛ 1t b 12 ɛ 2t (6) ε 2t = b21 =0 ɛ 2t (7) 6 / 14

Cholesky decomposition II and we can see that two of the VAR impulse responses Q t+h ε 2t and P t+h ε 2t, h = 0, 1,... are the dynamic responses with respect to a supply-shock. They are identified. Now consider the two remaining responses: Q t+h and P t+h, h = 0, 1,... in the light of (6). For Q t (the instantaneous response) we get: Q t ε 2t = 1 b 12 7 / 14

Cholesky decomposition III where ε 2t = ω 12 /ω2 2. Hence, if we impose a second restriction: ω 12 = 0 (8) the responses with respect to changes in ε 1t are identified as responses to a demand shock. 8 / 14

Formulating a SVAR as a recursive model I From Lecture 8, we have that the two restrictions on the SEM: b 21 = 0 and ω 12 = 0 (9) defines a recursive model, which we can write as Q t = φ 0 + φ 1 Q t 1 + β 0 P t + β 1 P t 1 + ɛ 1t (10) P t = ϕ 20 b 20 + ϕ 21 φ 21 Q t 1 + ϕ 22 φ 22 P t 1 + ε 2t ɛ 2t (11) where we have chosen parameter symbols to remind ourselves that the first equation is interpreted as the conditional model equation for Q t given P t and the second is the marginal model equation for P t. 9 / 14

Formulating a SVAR as a recursive model II The conditional + marginal interpretation means that Cov(ɛ 1t, ε 2t ) = ω 12 = 0, and so provides us with a practical way of implementing the required ω 12 = 0 condition. OLS on (10) gives for ˆβ 0,OLS : plim( ˆβ 0,OLS ) = Cov(ε 1t,ε 2t ) Var(ε 2t ) σ 12 σ 2 2 DIY: Use (4) and (5) to show that for a recursive model (remember (9)) we have: σ 12 = b 12 ω 2 2 (12) σ 2 2 = ω 2 2 (13) 10 / 14

Formulating a SVAR as a recursive model III Therefore showing identification. plim( ˆβ 0,OLS ) = b 12 11 / 14

Example using the program I Formulate and estimate the VAR(1) for the fish-data with stormy, mixed and hol as exogenous variables Let the program calculate 12 impulse responses, choosing first the Standard deviation radio button and then Orthogonalized radio button. Formulate (10) and (11) as SEM in the program and estimate by OLS on each equation ( forcing ω 12 = 0). Let the program calculate 12 impulse responses, choose the Standard deviation radio button. Compare with VAR impulse responses. 12 / 14

Recursive model and SVAR I Using the Cholesky decompostion to formulate a SVAR is the same as choosing a recursive model. And a recursive model is a SVAR. A recursive model can also be interpreted as consisting of conditional and marginal model equations. Notice that the SVAR (recursive) identifying assumptions only involve the contemporaneous coeffi cient matrix (and the Ω matrix). Not the autoregressive matrix of the SEM These can be used to test overidentifying restrictions Or indeed to formulate other exact identification schemes, which we do not go into here 13 / 14

Recursive model and SVAR II In summary: for unclear reasons, SVARs are sometimes presented as more different from SEMs than they are. 14 / 14