ECON4515 Finance theory 1 Diderik Lund, 5 May Perold: The CAPM

Similar documents
ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON4510 Finance Theory Lecture 2

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Adding Production to the Theory

Monetary Economics: Solutions Problem Set 1

1 Bewley Economies with Aggregate Uncertainty

1. Using the model and notations covered in class, the expected returns are:

ECON4510 Finance Theory Lecture 1

Chapter 4. Applications/Variations

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics Second Edition

Information Choice in Macroeconomics and Finance.

Advanced Macroeconomics

Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics B. J. Heijdra & F. van der Ploeg Chapter 6: The Government Budget Deficit

Speculation and the Bond Market: An Empirical No-arbitrage Framework

Final Examination with Answers: Economics 210A

Notes on Recursive Utility. Consider the setting of consumption in infinite time under uncertainty as in

Political Cycles and Stock Returns. Pietro Veronesi

4- Current Method of Explaining Business Cycles: DSGE Models. Basic Economic Models

Circling the Square: Experiments in Regression

The Consumer, the Firm, and an Economy

FINM6900 Finance Theory Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium for Multiple Risky Assets

1. Money in the utility function (start)

EC487 Advanced Microeconomics, Part I: Lecture 5

Department of Agricultural Economics. PhD Qualifier Examination. May 2009

General Equilibrium and Welfare

Competitive Equilibrium

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Department of Economics, University of California, Davis Ecn 200C Micro Theory Professor Giacomo Bonanno ANSWERS TO PRACTICE PROBLEMS 18

The Real Business Cycle Model

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Question 1. (p p) (x(p, w ) x(p, w)) 0. with strict inequality if x(p, w) x(p, w ).

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Comprehensive Exam. Macro Spring 2014 Retake. August 22, 2014

Practice Questions for Mid-Term I. Question 1: Consider the Cobb-Douglas production function in intensive form:

Second Welfare Theorem

2 Functions and Their

Consumption. Consider a consumer with utility. v(c τ )e ρ(τ t) dτ.

Asset Pricing. Chapter IX. The Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model. June 20, 2006

ECO 310: Empirical Industrial Organization Lecture 2 - Estimation of Demand and Supply

Dynamic Optimization: An Introduction

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Microeconomics, Block I Part 2

Equilibrium in a Production Economy

Neoclassical Business Cycle Model

KIER DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

The Hansen Singleton analysis

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis, Lecture 6

Microeconomic theory focuses on a small number of concepts. The most fundamental concept is the notion of opportunity cost.

Capital Structure and Investment Dynamics with Fire Sales

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Microeconomics 1. Graduate School of Management and Economics. Dr. S.

LECTURE 6. Introduction to Econometrics. Hypothesis testing & Goodness of fit

Entrance Examination for M. A. Economics, Series 01. Time. 3 hours Maximum marks. 100

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics

Proper Welfare Weights for Social Optimization Problems

Economics 210B Due: September 16, Problem Set 10. s.t. k t+1 = R(k t c t ) for all t 0, and k 0 given, lim. and

Using regression to study economic relationships is called econometrics. econo = of or pertaining to the economy. metrics = measurement

Economics 501B Final Exam Fall 2017 Solutions

In the Ramsey model we maximized the utility U = u[c(t)]e nt e t dt. Now

Lecture 13. Simple Linear Regression

Getting to page 31 in Galí (2008)

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013

Errata for Campbell, Financial Decisions and Markets, 01/02/2019.

(a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Solutions to Macro Final 2006

University of California Berkeley

Assignment #5. 1 Keynesian Cross. Econ 302: Intermediate Macroeconomics. December 2, 2009

Microeconomic Theory I Midterm October 2017

Lecture 3: Growth with Overlapping Generations (Acemoglu 2009, Chapter 9, adapted from Zilibotti)

Macroeconomic Theory and Analysis Suggested Solution for Midterm 1

The Lucas Imperfect Information Model

A Summary of Economic Methodology

1 Overlapping Generations

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Slides to accompany 13. Markets and Efficient Risk-Bearing: Examples and Extensions

Ramsey Cass Koopmans Model (1): Setup of the Model and Competitive Equilibrium Path

Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems

Redistributive Taxation in a Partial-Insurance Economy

problem. max Both k (0) and h (0) are given at time 0. (a) Write down the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman (HJB) Equation in the dynamic programming

Wooldridge, Introductory Econometrics, 3d ed. Chapter 16: Simultaneous equations models. An obvious reason for the endogeneity of explanatory

Advanced Microeconomic Analysis Solutions to Midterm Exam

Discussion Papers in Economics

Financial Econometrics Lecture 6: Testing the CAPM model

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

Economic Growth: Lecture 13, Stochastic Growth

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

Lecture 1: Labour Economics and Wage-Setting Theory

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set I

Solow Growth Model. Michael Bar. February 28, Introduction Some facts about modern growth Questions... 4

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: Solving Models with Rational Expectations

Lecture 6. Xavier Gabaix. March 11, 2004

Bi-Variate Functions - ACTIVITES

Markowitz Efficient Portfolio Frontier as Least-Norm Analytic Solution to Underdetermined Equations

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix

Graduate Macroeconomics 2 Problem set Solutions

Topic 2. Consumption/Saving and Productivity shocks

First Welfare Theorem

Multivariate GARCH models.

Economic Growth: Lecture 8, Overlapping Generations

Transcription:

Perold: The CAPM Perold starts with a historical background, the development of portfolio theory and the CAPM. Points out that until 1950 there was no theory to describe the equilibrium determination of asset prices. Then started a theoretical development for about 15 years. After the CAPM was established in the mid-1960 s, subsequent development has been related to that model: Extending it, testing it, and (see Fama and French) rejecting it. The central role of the CAPM during these forty years is one good reason to learn about it. Other reasons to learn about the CAPM: Starting from a simple assumption of mean-variance preferences, the model derives a formula for the pricing of assets which can be applied by practitioners and tested by econometricians. The pricing formula is linear, in a sense which is necessary for capital market equilibrium: The price of a linear combination of assets is equal to the same linear combination of the separate prices of those assets. The model contains the very general lesson that when there are diversification possibilities, the required expected rate of return for each asset does not depend on the asset s own risk, but its contribution to portfolio risk, measured by a covariance. 1

Perold: The CAPM, continued Observe: The linearity must hold because the agents are free to make such linear combinations themselves. Equilibrium prices cannot be determined by variance, since the price would then increase each time two assets were combined into a portfolio so that variance was reduced. Observe: The linearity holds when the risk deduction in the price is determined by a covariance, but would not hold if it were determined by, e.g., a variance. Observe: The linearity will also be satisfied by Fama and French s three-factor model, p. 38 in their article. Perold s derivation of the CAPM equation, pp. 9 17 This is an alternative derivation to the one in D&D, p. 142, which was also used in the lectures (28 Jan., p. 1). Perold s derivation uses exactly the same assumptions and ends up with the same equation. Thus no need to learn Perold s method in addition to the one we used previously. But notice the concept Sharpe ratio, which is much used. Equal to the slope in the (σ, µ) diagram of the line through (0, r f ) and the location (σ j, µ j ) in the diagram of some asset or portfolio. In the standard CAPM, the maximal attainable Sharpe ratio is equal to the slope of the Capital Market Line. 2

Other topics from Perold If the CAPM does not describe the world correctly, it may help in showing what could be gained from behavior closer to the model s predictions. In particular (pp. 18 19) Perold suggests much could be gained from better international diversification. If there were no obstacles to international diversification, the model predicts that all investors would hold the same combination of risky assets. This is definitely not true for the world. Explanations could be tax discrimination or information problems. 3

Fama and French (2004) Paper contains some econometric arguments which are too advanced for this course. Since not all of you have masters courses in econometrics, we cannot require that you understand and reproduce the econometric arguments. However, you should know in more general terms what are their viewpoints on the empirical validity of the CAPM. Main viewpoint is that the model has serious problems in passing empirical tests. 4

F&F on the Roll critique F&F acknowledge the Roll critique, that there are important problems with the methods used to test the CAPM. Although it is difficult to know which empirical data to use for the market portfolio, F&F state that they are more pragmatic (than Roll) (p. 41). My interpretation: They observe that the model is being used by many with some particular choice(s) of market portfolio(s). Thus they say it is interesting to test whether the model works with those empirical specifications that people actually use. Example: People may estimate the β for some industry, say production of furniture (or automobiles or cement or... ). The estimate is based on some choice of market portfolio. Then they will use that β to determine the required expected rate of return for projects in the industry. This will be used to make investment decisions. F&F say (see, e.g., the second paragraph in their conclusion) that if one uses such a procedure, one may use a wrong required expected rate of return, because the model does not conform with data, using that specific market portfolio. 5

F&F s three-factor model According to the CAPM, no other variable should affect differences in expected returns than the covariance with the return on the market portfolio. (Assets with the same covariance will have the same E( r j ), according to the model. Differences in other variables between these assets cannot then affect the E( r j ).) In empirical tests, many researchers have tried to find if other factors can explain differences. Use different regression techniques, enter new explanatory variables. F&F (pp. 38 41) have the most influential results so far: Three factors. Beside the market factor, they enter two additional factor in the regression. One is the difference in the return on portfolios of small and big stocks. The other is the difference in the return on portfolios of stocks with high and low B/M ratios (see p. 10 of lecture 21 April). Will not go further into explanations and further testing of these. But problem (F&F p. 39): No theory underlying the inclusion of these variables. No idea whether they will continue to be significant. 6

One possible reason why B/M matters is that there may be some irrational pricing. If we allow for the possibility that the market sometimes underprice or overprice an asset, then a high price today will predict lower expected rate of return over the next period, and vice versa. This will imply that every variable which includes the market price itself, will be significant in explaining expected rates of return. 7

Seminar exercise 4 for 29 30 April One future period with only two possible states of the world, s = 1, 2, with probabilities Pr(S = s) = π s, so that π 2 = 1 π 1. Only two individuals, i = 1, 2, who maximize expected utility and are risk averse. Each individual, i, has an endowment of income Y is in state s for s = 1, 2. All four Y is 0. Before the state of the world is known, they can trade in claims to the income in these two states. Competitive equilibrium. Individual i will consume c is in state s. The budget constraint of individual i is Ŷ i p 1 Y i1 + Y i2 = p 1 c i1 + c i2, where Ŷi is just a definition of the budget. This can be rewritten in terms of net trades: p 1 (Y i1 c i1 ) = (c i2 Y i2 ). By selling claims to some of the income in one state it is possible to buy claims to consumption exceeding the income in the other state. Observe that compared to the model in p. 12 of the lecture of 28 April, there is no endowment (wealth, income) or consumption in period zero in the present model. But the market allows for the same kind of trading (in both models) between states in period one (the future time period). 8

4(a) Write down the optimalization problem for individual i, and find the firstorder conditions for a maximum, without specifying the shape of the utility function. Why can we assume that the second-order conditions are satisfied? Answer The problem is to maximize expected utility given the budget constraint, max c i1,c i2 π 1 U i (c i1 ) + π 2 U i (c i2 ), s.t. p 1 Y i1 + Y i2 = p 1 c i1 + c i2. Substitute in for c i2 from the budget constraint and find max c i1 π 1 U i (c i1 ) + π 2 U i (Y i2 + p 1 (Y i1 c i1 )), which has f.o.c. (chain rule, dc i2 /dc i1 is p 1 / ): π 1 U i(c i1 ) π 2 U i(c i2 ) = p 1 (Observe that a similar f.o.c. can be derived from the f.o.c. in p. 12 of the lecture (28 Apr) since there, u (u 0 ) must be equal to π θ U (c θ )/q θ for both θ = 1 and θ = 2.) The s.o.c. is that which is OK since U < 0. π 1 U i (c i1 ) + π 2 U i (c i2 ) p 2 1 < 0 9

(I am sorry for the typos in the original version of 4(b) and (c). It was corrected in a message 29 April.) 4(b) Assume both individuals have a utility function of the form U i (c is ) e α ic is, where α i is an individual-specific, positive constant. Show that under the assumption that there is an interior solution, the optimal c i1 can be written as Answer c i1 = Ŷ i α i ln ( ) π 2 p 1 π 1 p 1 + We have U i(c is ) α i e α ic is. Plug this into the f.o.c.: π 1 α i e α ic i1 = p 1 π 2 α i e α ic i2 Rewrite several times in order to arrive at the required expression: e α i(c i2 c i1 ) = p 1π 2 π 1, ln p 1π 2 = α i (c i2 c i1 ) = α i (Ŷi (p 1 + )c i1 ) π 1 This can easily be transformed into the required expression. Observe that c i1 will be greater if Ŷ i is greater and lower if p 1 is increased while p 1 + is kept constant. These are reasonable effects. The effect of α i depends on whether the logarithm is positive or negative. But in any case risk aversion (α) counteracts (i.e., dampens) the effect of the logarithm term. If p 1 π 2 > π 1, it means that state 2 is the more attractive, the logarithm would be positive, reducing c i1. A higher risk aversion would dampen this effect on c i1. 10

4(c) Define α 1/ (1/α 1 + 1/α 2 ), and define Y s (with only one subscript, without hat) as Y s Y 1s + Y 2s. Show that in equilibrium the relative price is given as Answer p = p 1 = π 1 π 2 e α(y 2 Y 1 ) While the two individuals regard the prices p 1, as given, we are asked to look for a competitive equilibrium. The prices are then endogenous, and there are two additional equations, supply equals demand, for both states. For state 1 this means (using the Y 1 defined in the text): Y 1 = Y 11 + Y 21 = c 11 + c 21. There is a similar equation for state 2. However, by Walras law (see any microeconomics textbook, e.g., Varian) that equation is superfluous, as it is implied by the three others, i.e., supply = demand for state 1 plus the two budget constraints. Altogether we have five equations, those three plus the two first-order conditions, to determine p1/p2, c 11, c 12, c 21, c 22. The solution is found by inserting the two demand expressions and reformulating: = 1 p 1 + Y 1 = Ŷ 1 α 1 ln ( ) π 2 p 1 π 1 + p 1 + Ŷ 2 α 2 ln ( ) π 2 p 1 π 1 p 1 + p 1 Y 11 + Y 12 + p 1 Y 21 + Y 22 1 α 1 + 1 α 2 ln π 2p 1 π 1 11

Introduce now α 1/ (1/α 1 + 1/α 2 ), a kind of aggregate measure of risk aversion, and find Y 1 = 1 p 1 p 1 Y 1 + Y 2 1 + 1 α ln π 2p 1 π 1. This implies Y 2 Y 1 = 1 α ln π 2p 1, π 1 which implies e α(y 2 Y 1 ) = π 2p 1, π 1 which gives the required expression for the relative price, p 1 = π 1 e α(y 2 Y 1 ). π 2 4(d) Give an economic interpretation of how the equilibrium relative price depends on π 1 /π 2, on Y 2 Y 1, and on α 1 and α 2. Answer If state 1 becomes more probable, there will be a higher willingness to pay for c i1, thus a higher p 1 (since no additional supply is available). If Y 2 Y 1 increases, consumption in state 1 becomes more scarce relative to consumption in state 2, and p 1 will increase. The effect of a higher α magnifies the effect of Y 2 Y 1 through risk aversion: The extra willingness to pay for consumption in the state with less total consumption is higher if risk aversion is high. 12

4(e) Assume now Y 1 = Y 2. What is now the formulae for the relative price and the optimal consumptions? Give an economic interpretation of this case. Answer We find p 1 = π 1 π 2 and c i1 = Ŷi/(p 1 + ), and the same in state 2, c i2 = Ŷi/(p 1 + ). So in this case the sum of the individuals endowments are the same in both states, which makes it possible to achieve full insurance, i.e., both consumers can obtain risk free consumption. Indeed, this is also the market solution. 4(f) Assume now that in addition to the future period discussed above, there is a period we may call today. Consider two investment projects which require the same outlay today. The first gives an income x in the future period, the same irrespective of which state is realized. The second gives an income z in state 1, but nothing in state 2. What do the equilibrium prices from (c) above tell us about (i) the agents rankings of these two projects, and (ii) the agents willingness today to pay for the projects (i.e., what are the maximum outlays today that would lead the agents to accept the projects)? Answer As usual we assume that the market prices can be used to find the values of the projects, i.e., that they are small in relation to the total economy. So we use the relative price p 1 / from part (c). The gross value of project 1 in the market, without deduction for the outlay, is p 1 x + x = x + x p 1 13 = x + 1 p 1.

The gross value of project 2 is Project 1 is preferred if x p 1 z + 0 = z p1. + 1 > z p1. p 1 So even if we do not know, knowledge of p 1 / is sufficient to decide. However, there is no information in the market about the willingness to pay today for these projects. The outlay is the same, so we may rank them, but we cannot compare to the outlay and decide whether the net value is positive. This is because the model has no market for consumption today, only an exchange between consumption in different states in the future. This is different from p. 12 of 28 April. 14