Optimal investment and contingent claim valuation in illiquid markets

Similar documents
Convex duality in optimal investment and contingent claim valuation in illiquid markets

Conjugate duality in stochastic optimization

Efficient portfolios in financial markets with proportional transaction costs

On the dual problem of utility maximization

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs

Calculating the set of superhedging portfolios in markets with transactions costs by methods of vector optimization

Duality and optimality conditions in stochastic optimization and mathematical finance

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Existence of solutions in non-convex dynamic programming and optimal investment

Robust pricing hedging duality for American options in discrete time financial markets

Duality formulas for robust pricing and hedging in discrete time

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.mf] 10 May 2018

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.rm] 10 Sep 2017

Monetary Risk Measures and Generalized Prices Relevant to Set-Valued Risk Measures

Set-Valued Risk Measures and Bellman s Principle

No-Arbitrage Criteria for Financial Markets with Transaction Costs and Incomplete Information

Additional information and pricing-hedging duality in robust framework

Duality and Utility Maximization

Elements of Stochastic Analysis with application to Finance (52579) Pavel Chigansky

The Canonical Model Space for Law-invariant Convex Risk Measures is L 1

Lectures for the Course on Foundations of Mathematical Finance

Equilibrium with Transaction Costs

QUANTITATIVE FINANCE RESEARCH CENTRE

Duality formulas for robust pricing and hedging in discrete time

A Model of Optimal Portfolio Selection under. Liquidity Risk and Price Impact

Introduction Optimality and Asset Pricing

(6, 4) Is there arbitrage in this market? If so, find all arbitrages. If not, find all pricing kernels.

Time Consistency in Decision Making

Pareto optimal allocations and optimal risk sharing for quasiconvex risk measures

Valuation and Pricing of Electricity Delivery Contracts The Producer s View

On convex risk measures on L p -spaces

UTILITY OPTIMIZATION IN A FINITE SCENARIO SETTING

EXTENSIONS OF CONVEX FUNCTIONALS ON CONVEX CONES

Shadow prices and well-posedness in the problem of optimal investment and consumption with transaction costs

arxiv:submit/ [q-fin.pm] 25 Sep 2011

Sensitivity analysis of the expected utility maximization problem with respect to model perturbations

Coherent risk measures

Coherent Acceptability Measures in Multiperiod Models

A model for a large investor trading at market indifference prices. I: single-period case.

Thomas Knispel Leibniz Universität Hannover

Risk Minimization under Transaction Costs

Pricing, Hedging and Optimally Designing Derivatives via Minimization of Risk Measures 1

On Agents Agreement and Partial-Equilibrium Pricing in Incomplete Markets

Risk Measures in non-dominated Models

RISK MEASURES ON ORLICZ HEART SPACES

Super-replication with proportional transaction cost under model uncertainty

Course Handouts: Pages 1-20 ASSET PRICE BUBBLES AND SPECULATION. Jan Werner

THE ASYMPTOTIC ELASTICITY OF UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND OPTIMAL INVESTMENT IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS 1

arxiv: v6 [q-fin.pm] 25 Jul 2016

Robust Utility Maximization for Complete and Incomplete Market Models

The main purpose of this chapter is to prove the rst and second fundamental theorem of asset pricing in a so called nite market model.

Order book resilience, price manipulation, and the positive portfolio problem

Utility-based proof for the existence of strictly consistent price processes under proportional transaction costs

LEAST-SQUARES APPROXIMATION OF RANDOM VARIABLES BY STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

Uncertainty Per Krusell & D. Krueger Lecture Notes Chapter 6

Discrete-Time Market Models

On Supremal and Maximal Sets with Respect to Random Partial Orders

Coherent Risk Measures. Acceptance Sets. L = {X G : X(ω) < 0, ω Ω}.

Mathematics for Economics and Finance

Super-replication and utility maximization in large financial markets

Robust Superhedging with Jumps and Diffusion arxiv: v2 [q-fin.mf] 17 Jul 2015

Utility Maximization in Incomplete Markets with Random Endowment. Walter Schachermayer Hui Wang

Self-equilibrated Functions in Dual Vector Spaces: a Boundedness Criterion

Convex Stochastic optimization

Optimal Risk Sharing with Different Reference Probabilities

Constrained Portfolio Optimization

Duality in constrained optimal investment and consumption problems: a synopsis 1

Robust Mean-Variance Hedging via G-Expectation

Information and Credit Risk

Convergence of utility indifference prices to the superreplication price in a multiple-priors framework

A problem of portfolio/consumption choice in a. liquidity risk model with random trading times

Christoph Czichowsky, Walter Schachermayer and Junjian Yang Shadow prices for continuous processes

A Note on Robust Representations of Law-Invariant Quasiconvex Functions

Chapter 2: Preliminaries and elements of convex analysis

Dynamic Risk Measures and Nonlinear Expectations with Markov Chain noise

Handout 4: Some Applications of Linear Programming

Minimal Sufficient Conditions for a Primal Optimizer in Nonsmooth Utility Maximization

Financial Asset Price Bubbles under Model Uncertainty

A Simple Computational Approach to the Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing

On duality theory of conic linear problems

OPTIMAL INVESTMENT WITH RANDOM ENDOWMENTS IN INCOMPLETE MARKETS

An Approximation Pricing Algorithm in an. Incomplete Market: A Differential Geometric. Approach

Optimal Arbitrage under Constraints

Minimal Supersolutions of Backward Stochastic Differential Equations and Robust Hedging

Essential Supremum and Essential Maximum with Respect to Random Preference Relations

Some Properties of the Augmented Lagrangian in Cone Constrained Optimization

SET-VALUED SHORTFALL AND DIVERGENCE RISK MEASURES

STRICT LOCAL MARTINGALE DEFLATORS AND PRICING AMERICAN CALL-TYPE OPTIONS. 0. Introduction

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix

Problems in Mathematical Finance Related to Transaction Costs and Model Uncertainty

Time-Consistent Mean-Variance Portfolio Selection in Discrete and Continuous Time

4. Conditional risk measures and their robust representation

Robust preferences and robust portfolio choice

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.mf] 7 Feb 2018

No Arbitrage: On the Work of David Kreps

Liquidity risk and optimal dividend/investment strategies

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Necessary Conditions for the Existence of Utility Maximizing Strategies under Transaction Costs

PATHWISE SUPER-REPLICATION VIA VOVK S OUTER MEASURE

Explicit characterization of the super-replication strategy in financial markets with partial transaction costs

Transcription:

and contingent claim valuation in illiquid markets Teemu Pennanen Department of Mathematics, King s College London 1 / 27

Illiquidity The cost of a market orders depends nonlinearly on the traded amount. There is no numeraire: much of trading consists of exchanging sequences of cash-flows (swaps, insurance contracts, coupon payments, dividends,...) We extend basic results on indifference pricing, arbitrage, optimal portfolios and duality to markets with nonlinear illiquidity effects and general swap contracts. 2 / 27

Outline 1. with nonlinear trading costs and portfolio constraints. In particular, existence of a numeraire is not assumed. 2. problem parameterized by a sequence of cash-flows. 3. Indifference pricing extended to general swap contracts. 4. established under an extended no-arbitrage condition. 5. Dual expressions for the optimal value and swap rates in terms of state price densities that capture uncertainty as well as time-value of money in the absense of a numeraire. 3 / 27

Example 1 (Limit order markets) The cost of a market order is obtained by integrating the order book. 242 241 PRICE 240 239 238 237 236-100000 -50000 0 50000 QUANTITY 4 / 27

Consider a financial market where a finite set J of assets can be traded at t = 0,...,T. Let (Ω,F,(F t ) T,P) be a filtered probability space. The cost (in cash) of buying a portfolio x R J at time t in state ω will be denoted by S t (x,ω). We will assume that S t (,ω) is convex with S t (0,ω) = 0, S t (x, ) is F t -measurable. (In particular, S t is a Carathéodory function and thus, B(R J ) F t -measurable, so ω S t (x t (ω),ω) is F t -measurable when x t is so.) Such a sequence (S t ) will be called a convex cost process. 5 / 27

Example 2 (Liquid markets) If s = (s t ) T is an (F t ) T -adapted R J -valued price process, then the functions S t (x,ω) = s t (ω) x define a convex cost process. Example 3 (Jouini and Kallal, 1995) If (s a t) T and (s b t) T are (F t ) T -adapted with s b s a, then the functions { s a S t (x,ω) = t(ω)x if x 0, s b t(ω)x if x 0 define a convex cost process. 6 / 27

Example 4 (Çetin and Rogers, 2007) If s = (s t ) T is an (F t ) T -adapted process and ψ is a lower semicontinuous convex function on R with ψ(0) = 0, then the functions S t (x,ω) = x 0 +s t (ω)ψ(x 1 ) define a convex cost process. Example 5 (Dolinsky and Soner, 2013) If s = (s t ) T is (F t ) T -adapted and G t (x, ) are F t -measurable functions such that G t (,ω) are finite and convex, then the functions S t (x,ω) = x 0 +s t (ω) x 1 +G t (x 1,ω) define a convex cost process. 7 / 27

We allow for portfolio constraints requiring that the portfolio held over (t,t+1] in state ω has to belong to a set D t (ω) R J. We assume that D t (ω) are closed and convex with 0 D t (ω). {ω Ω D t (ω) U } F t for every open U R J. 8 / 27

Models where D t (ω) is independent of (t,ω) have been studied e.g. in [Cvitanić and Karatzas, 1992] and [Jouini and Kallal, 1995]. In [Napp, 2003], D t (ω) = {x R d M t (ω)x K}, where K R L is a closed convex cone and M t is an F t -measurable matrix. General constraints have been studied in [Evstigneev, Schürger and Taksar, 2004], [Rokhlin, 2005] and [Czichowsky and Schweizer, 2012]. 9 / 27

Let c M := {(c t ) T c t L 0 (Ω,F t,p)} and consider the problem T minimize V t (S t ( x t )+c t ) over x N D N D = {(x t ) T x t L 0 (Ω,F t,p;r J ), x t D t, x T = 0}, V t : L 0 R are convex, nondecreasing and V t (0) = 0. Example 6 If V t = δ L 0 for t < T, the problem can be written minimize V T (S T ( x T )+c T ) over x N D subject to S t ( x t )+c t 0, t = 0,...,T 1. 10 / 27

Example 7 (Markets with a numeraire) When S t (x,ω) = x 0 + S t ( x,ω) and D t (ω) = R D t (ω), the problem can be written as ( T minimize V T S t ( x t )+ T c t ) over x N D. When S t ( x,ω) = s t (ω) x, T S t ( x t ) = T s t x t = T 1 x t s t+1. 11 / 27

We denote the optimal value function by T ϕ(c) = inf V t (S t ( x t )+c t ). x N D When V t = δ L 0 for t = 0,...,T, we have ϕ = δ C where C = {c M x N D : S t ( x t )+c t 0 t}. is the set of claims that can be superhedged for free. In the classical linear model, T T 1 C = {c M x N D : c t x t s t+1 }. We always have, ϕ(c) = inf d C T V t(c t d t ). 12 / 27

Lemma 8 The value function ϕ is convex and ϕ( c+c) ϕ( c) c M, c C. where C = {c M c+αc C c C, α > 0}. In particular, ϕ is constant with respect to the linear space C ( C ). If S t are positively homogeneous and D t are conical, then C is a cone and C = C. 13 / 27

In a swap contract, an agent receives a sequence p M of premiums and delivers a sequence c M of claims. Examples: Swaps with a fixed leg : p = (1,...,1), random c. In credit derivatives (CDS, CDO,...) and other insurance contracts both p and c are random. Traditionally in mathematical finance: p = (1,0,...,0) and c = (0,...,0,c T ). Claims and premiums live in the same space M = {(c t ) T c t L 0 (Ω,F t,p;r)}. 14 / 27

If we already have liabilities c M, then π( c,p;c) := inf{α R ϕ( c+c αp) ϕ( c)} gives the least swap rate that would allow us to enter a swap contract without worsening our financial position. Similarly, π b ( c,p;c) := sup{α R ϕ( c c+αp) ϕ( c)} = π( c,p; c) gives the greatest swap rate we would need on the opposite side of the trade. When p = (1,0,...,0) and c = (0,...,0,c T ), we get a nonlinear version of the indifference price of [Hodges and Neuberger, 1989]. 15 / 27

Define the super- and subhedging swap rates, π sup (c) = inf{α c αp C }, π inf (c) = sup{α αp c C }. In the classical model with p = (1,0,...,0), we recover the usual super- and subhedging costs. Theorem 9 If π( c,p;0) 0, then π inf (c) π b ( c,p;c) π( c,p;c) π sup (c) with equalities if c αp C ( C ) for some α R. Agents with identical views P, preferences V and financial position c have no reason to trade with each other. Prices are independent of such subjective factors when c αp C ( C ) for some α R. 16 / 27

Example 10 (Linear models) When S t (x) = s t x and D t = R J, we have c αp C ( C ) if there is an x N D such that s t x t +c t = αp t. The converse holds under the no-arbitrage condition C M + = {0}. Example 11 (The classical model) When D t = R J, S t (x) = x 0 + s t x and p = (1,0,...,0), we have c αp C ( C ) if T c t is attainable in the sense that T c t = α+ T 1 x t s t+1 for some α R and x N D. The converse holds under the no-arbitrage condition. 17 / 27

Given a market model (S,D), let S t (x,ω) = sup α>0 S t (αx,ω) α and D t (ω) = α>0αd t (ω). If S is sublinear and D is conical, then S = S and D = D Theorem 12 Assume that V t (c t ) = Ev t (c t ), where v t are bounded from below. If the cone L := {x N D S t ( x t ) 0} is a linear space, then ϕ is proper and lower semicontinuous in L 0 and the infimum is attained for every c M. 18 / 27

Example 13 In the classical perfectly liquid market model L = {x N s t x t 0, x T = 0}, so the linearity condition coincides with the no-arbitrage condition. When v t = δ R, we have ϕ = δ C so we recover the key lemma from [Schachermayer, 1992]. Example 14 In unconstrained models with proportional transactions costs, the linearity condition becomes the robust no-arbitrage condition introduced by [Schachermayer, 2004] (for claims with physical delivery). 19 / 27

Example 15 If S t (x,ω) > 0 for x / R J, we have L = {0}. Example 16 In [Çetin and Rogers, 2007] with S t (x,ω) = x 0 +s t (ω)ψ(x 1 ) one has S t (x,ω) = x 0 +s t (ω)ψ (x 1 ). When infψ = 0 and supψ = we have ψ = δ R, so the condition in Example 15 holds. Example 17 If S t (,ω) = s t (ω) x for a componentwise strictly positive price process s and D t (ω) R J + (infinite short selling is prohibited), we have L = {0}. 20 / 27

Proposition 18 Assume that ϕ is proper and lower semicontinuous. Then, for every c domϕ and p M, the conditions sup α>0 ϕ(αp) > ϕ(0), π( c,p;0) >, π( c,p;c) > for all c M, are equivalent and imply that π( c,p; ) is proper and lower semicontinuous on M and that the infimum π( c,p;c) = inf{α ϕ( c+c αp) ϕ( c)} is attained for every c M. 21 / 27

Let M p = {c M c t L p (Ω,F t,p;r)}. The bilinear form T c,y := E c t y t puts M 1 and M in separating duality. The conjugate of a function f on M 1 is defined by f (y) = sup c M 1 { c,y f(c)}. If f is proper, convex and lower semicontinuous, then f(y) = sup y M { c,y f (y)}. 22 / 27

Lemma 19 The conjugate of ϕ can be expressed in terms of the support function σ C (y) = sup c C c,y of C as T ϕ (y) = E vt(y t )+σ C (y). Theorem 20 If ϕ is lower semicontinuous, we have { } T ϕ(c) = sup c,y σ C (y) E vt(y t ). y M In particular, when C is a cone, { } T ϕ(c) = sup c,y E vt(y t ), y C where C := {y M c,y 0 c C M 1 } is the polar cone of C. 23 / 27

Lemma 21 If S t (x, ) are integrable, then for y M +, { T } T 1 σ C (y) = inf E(y t S t ) (v t )+ Eσ Dt (E[ v t+1 F t ]), v N 1 while σ C 1(y) = + for y / M +. The infimum is attained. Example 22 If S t (ω,x) = s t (ω) x and D t (ω) is a cone, C = {y M E[ (y t+1 s t+1 ) F t ] D t}. Example 23 If S t (ω,x) = sup{s x s [s b t(ω),s a t(ω)]} and D t (ω) = R J, then C = {y M ys is a martingale for some s [s b,s a ]}. Example 24 In the classical model, C consists of positive multiples of martingale densities. 24 / 27

Theorem 25 Let c M 1, A( c) = {c ϕ( c+c) ϕ( c)} and assume that ϕ is proper and lower semicontinuous. Then 1. sup α>0 ϕ(αp) > ϕ(0), 2. π( c,p;0) >, 3. π( c,p;c) > for all c M, 4. p,y = 1 for some y domσ A( c) are equivalent and imply that π( c,p;c) = sup y M { c,y σa( c) (y) p,y = 1 }. Moreover, if infϕ < ϕ( c), then σ A( c) = σ B( c) +σ C, where B( c) = {c M 1 V( c+c) ϕ( c)}. 25 / 27

Example 26 In the classical model, with p = (1,0,...,0) and v t = δ R for t < T, we get { π( c,p;c) = sup c,y σa( c) (y) p,y = 1 } y M { ) } = sup Q Q T ( E Q dq ( c t +c t ) σ B( c) E t dp T = sup sup Q Q α>0e Q{ ( c t +c t ) α [ v T( dq dp /α) ϕ( c) ] }, where Q is the set of absolutely continuous martingale measures; see [Biagini, Frittelli, Grasselli, 2011] for a continuous time version. 26 / 27

Summary Financial contracts often involve sequences of cash-flows. The adequacy of swap rates/prices is subjective (views, risk preferences, the current financial position). Much of classical asset pricing theory can be extended to convex models of illiquid markets. In the absence of numeraire, martingale measures have to be replaced by more general dual variables that capture uncertainty as well as time value of money. 27 / 27