Superreplication under Volatility Uncertainty for Measurable Claims

Similar documents
Pathwise Construction of Stochastic Integrals

Random G -Expectations

Optimal Stopping under Adverse Nonlinear Expectation and Related Games

Robust Superhedging with Jumps and Diffusion arxiv: v2 [q-fin.mf] 17 Jul 2015

Arbitrage and Duality in Nondominated Discrete-Time Models

Nonlinear Lévy Processes and their Characteristics

Financial Asset Price Bubbles under Model Uncertainty

Quasi-sure Stochastic Analysis through Aggregation

On the monotonicity principle of optimal Skorokhod embedding problem

Minimal Supersolutions of Backward Stochastic Differential Equations and Robust Hedging

Stochastic Processes II/ Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie III. Lecture Notes

March 16, Abstract. We study the problem of portfolio optimization under the \drawdown constraint" that the

A NOTE ON STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS AS L 2 -CURVES

Risk-Minimality and Orthogonality of Martingales

A Representation of Excessive Functions as Expected Suprema

On the Multi-Dimensional Controller and Stopper Games

OPTIMAL SOLUTIONS TO STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL INCLUSIONS

The Azéma-Yor Embedding in Non-Singular Diffusions

Some SDEs with distributional drift Part I : General calculus. Flandoli, Franco; Russo, Francesco; Wolf, Jochen

1. Stochastic Processes and filtrations

Pseudo-stopping times and the hypothesis (H)

The Skorokhod reflection problem for functions with discontinuities (contractive case)

Lecture 12. F o s, (1.1) F t := s>t

On pathwise stochastic integration

Brownian Motion. 1 Definition Brownian Motion Wiener measure... 3

Citation Osaka Journal of Mathematics. 41(4)

Generalized Gaussian Bridges of Prediction-Invertible Processes

Prof. Erhan Bayraktar (University of Michigan)

A Concise Course on Stochastic Partial Differential Equations

Brownian motion. Samy Tindel. Purdue University. Probability Theory 2 - MA 539

Doléans measures. Appendix C. C.1 Introduction

Convergence at first and second order of some approximations of stochastic integrals

Hyperfinite Construction of G-expectation

is a Borel subset of S Θ for each c R (Bertsekas and Shreve, 1978, Proposition 7.36) This always holds in practical applications.

Part V. 17 Introduction: What are measures and why measurable sets. Lebesgue Integration Theory

An essay on the general theory of stochastic processes

PREDICTABLE REPRESENTATION PROPERTY OF SOME HILBERTIAN MARTINGALES. 1. Introduction.

Stochastic Processes. Winter Term Paolo Di Tella Technische Universität Dresden Institut für Stochastik

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.mf] 10 May 2018

3 (Due ). Let A X consist of points (x, y) such that either x or y is a rational number. Is A measurable? What is its Lebesgue measure?

Lecture 19 L 2 -Stochastic integration

Fundamental Inequalities, Convergence and the Optional Stopping Theorem for Continuous-Time Martingales

Optimal stopping for non-linear expectations Part I

Optimal Skorokhod embedding under finitely-many marginal constraints

On It^o's formula for multidimensional Brownian motion

Stochastic integration. P.J.C. Spreij

Lecture 2. We now introduce some fundamental tools in martingale theory, which are useful in controlling the fluctuation of martingales.

Nonlinear representation, backward SDEs, and application to the Principal-Agent problem

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS

Lecture 17 Brownian motion as a Markov process

16 1 Basic Facts from Functional Analysis and Banach Lattices

The Uniform Integrability of Martingales. On a Question by Alexander Cherny

PARTIAL REGULARITY OF BRENIER SOLUTIONS OF THE MONGE-AMPÈRE EQUATION

Lecture 22 Girsanov s Theorem

Stochastic integral. Introduction. Ito integral. References. Appendices Stochastic Calculus I. Geneviève Gauthier.

Generalized Hypothesis Testing and Maximizing the Success Probability in Financial Markets

Non-arbitrage condition and thin random times

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS JASON MILLER AND VITTORIA SILVESTRI

Proofs for Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators

Additional information and pricing-hedging duality in robust framework

UNCERTAINTY FUNCTIONAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS FOR FINANCE

16.1. Signal Process Observation Process The Filtering Problem Change of Measure

PROBABILITY: LIMIT THEOREMS II, SPRING HOMEWORK PROBLEMS

An introduction to Mathematical Theory of Control

SUMMARY OF RESULTS ON PATH SPACES AND CONVERGENCE IN DISTRIBUTION FOR STOCHASTIC PROCESSES

Rearrangements and polar factorisation of countably degenerate functions G.R. Burton, School of Mathematical Sciences, University of Bath, Claverton D

Applications of Ito s Formula

n E(X t T n = lim X s Tn = X s

1 Brownian Local Time

at time t, in dimension d. The index i varies in a countable set I. We call configuration the family, denoted generically by Φ: U (x i (t) x j (t))

Conditional Full Support for Gaussian Processes with Stationary Increments

On continuous time contract theory

Maximum Process Problems in Optimal Control Theory

Lecture 21 Representations of Martingales

An Almost Sure Approximation for the Predictable Process in the Doob Meyer Decomposition Theorem

Max-min (σ-)additive representation of monotone measures

The Asymptotic Theory of Transaction Costs

On the quantiles of the Brownian motion and their hitting times.

Minimal Sufficient Conditions for a Primal Optimizer in Nonsmooth Utility Maximization

FOUNDATIONS OF MARTINGALE THEORY AND STOCHASTIC CALCULUS FROM A FINANCE PERSPECTIVE

Martingale Representation Theorem for the G-expectation

Jointly measurable and progressively measurable stochastic processes

Independence of some multiple Poisson stochastic integrals with variable-sign kernels

PROGRESSIVE ENLARGEMENTS OF FILTRATIONS AND SEMIMARTINGALE DECOMPOSITIONS

Stochastic Processes

STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS WITH EXTRA PROPERTIES H. JEROME KEISLER. Department of Mathematics. University of Wisconsin.

Total Expected Discounted Reward MDPs: Existence of Optimal Policies

LECTURE 2: LOCAL TIME FOR BROWNIAN MOTION

Part III. 10 Topological Space Basics. Topological Spaces

The Codimension of the Zeros of a Stable Process in Random Scenery

Wiener Measure and Brownian Motion

3 Integration and Expectation

A D VA N C E D P R O B A B I L - I T Y

STAT 331. Martingale Central Limit Theorem and Related Results

Super-replication with proportional transaction cost under model uncertainty

STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS DRIVEN BY PROCESSES WITH INDEPENDENT INCREMENTS

Pathwise volatility in a long-memory pricing model: estimation and asymptotic behavior

ON THE MEASURABILITY OF FUNCTIONS WITH RESPECT TO CERTAIN CLASSES OF MEASURES

OPTIONAL DECOMPOSITION FOR CONTINUOUS SEMIMARTINGALES UNDER ARBITRARY FILTRATIONS. Introduction

Convergence of Banach valued stochastic processes of Pettis and McShane integrable functions

Transcription:

Superreplication under Volatility Uncertainty for Measurable Claims Ariel Neufeld Marcel Nutz April 14, 213 Abstract We establish the duality formula for the superreplication price in a setting of volatility uncertainty which includes the example of random G-expectation. In contrast to previous results, the contingent claim is not assumed to be quasi-continuous. Keywords Volatility uncertainty; Superreplication; Nonlinear expectation AMS 2 Subject Classication 93E2; 91B3; 91B28 1 Introduction This paper is concerned with superreplication-pricing in a setting of volatility uncertainty. We see the canonical process B on the space Ω of continuous paths as the stock price process and formalize this uncertainty via a set P of (non-equivalent) martingale laws on Ω. Given a contingent claim ξ measurable at time T >, we are interested in determining the minimal initial capital x R for which there exists a trading strategy H whose terminal gain x + T H u db u exceeds ξ P -a.s., simultaneously for all P P. The aim is to show that under suitable assumptions, this minimal capital is given by x = sup P P E P [ξ]. We prove this duality formula for Borelmeasurable (and, more generally, upper semianalytic) claims ξ and a model P where the possible values of the volatility are determined by a set-valued process. Such a model of a random G-expectation was rst introduced in [9], as an extension of the G-expectation of [15, 16]. Dept. of Mathematics, ETH Zurich, ariel.neufeld@math.ethz.ch. A. Neufeld gratefully acknowledges nancial support by Swiss National Science Foundation Grant PDFMP2-137147/1. Dept. of Mathematics, Columbia University, New York, mnutz@math.columbia.edu. Part of this research was carried out while M. Nutz was visiting the Forschungsinstitut für Mathematik at ETH Zurich, and he would like to thank Martin Schweizer, Mete Soner and Josef Teichmann for their hospitality. He is also indebted to Bruno Bouchard and Jianfeng Zhang for fruitful discussions. Financial support by NSF Grant DMS-128985 is gratefully acknowledged. 1

The duality formula under volatility uncertainty has been established for several cases and through dierent approaches: [6] used ideas from capacity theory, [17, 21, 24] used an approximation by Markovian control problems, and [23, 12] used a method discussed below. See also [18] for a followup on our results, related to optimal martingale transportation. The main dierence between our results and the previous ones is that we do not impose continuity assumptions on the claim ξ (as a functional of the stock price). Thus, on the one hand, our result extends the duality formula to traded claims such as digital options or options on realized variance, which are not quasi-continuous (cf. [6]), and cases where the regularity is not known, like an American option evaluated at an optimal exercise time (cf. [14]). On the other hand, our result conrms the general robustness of the duality. The main diculty in our endeavor is to construct the superreplicating strategy H. We adopt the approach of [23] and [12], which can be outlined as follows: (i) Construct the conditional (nonlinear) expectation E t (ξ) related to P and show the tower property E s (E t (ξ)) = E s (ξ) for s t. (ii) Check that the right limit Y t := E t+ (ξ) exists and denes a supermartingale under each P P (in a suitable ltration). (iii) For every P P, show that the martingale part in the DoobMeyer decomposition of Y is of the form H P db. Using that H P can be expressed via the quadratic (co)variation processes of Y and B, deduce that there exists a universal process H coinciding with H P under each P, and check that H is the desired strategy. Step (iii) can be accomplished by ensuring that each P P has the predictable representation property. To this endand for some details of Step (ii) that we shall skip for the moment[23] introduced the set of Brownian martingale laws with positive volatility, which we shall denote by P S : if P is chosen as a subset of P S, then every P P has the representation property (cf. Lemma 4.1) and Step (iii) is feasible. Step (i) is the main reason why previous results required continuity assumptions on ξ. Recently, it was shown in [13] that the theory of analytic sets can be used to carry out Step (i) when ξ is merely Borel-measurable (or only upper semianalytic), provided that the set of measures satises a condition of measurability and invariance, called Condition (A) below (cf. Proposition 2.2). It was also shown in [13] that this condition is satised for a model of random G-expectation where the measures are chosen from the set of all (not necessarily Brownian) martingale laws. Thus, to follow the approach outlined above, we formulate a similar model using elements of P S and show that Condition (A) is again satised. This essentially boils down to proving that the set P S itself satises Condition (A), which is our 2

main technical result (Theorem 2.4). Using this fact, we can go through the approach outlined above and establish our duality result (Theorem 2.3 and Corollary 2.6). As an aside of independent interest, Theorem 2.4 yields a rigorous proof for a dynamic programming principle with a fairly general reward functional (cf. Remark 2.7). The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we rst describe our setup and notation in detail and we recall the relevant facts from [13]; then, we state our main results. Theorem 2.4 is proved in Section 3, and Section 4 concludes with the proof of Theorem 2.3. 2 Results 2.1 Notation We x the dimension d N and let Ω = {ω C([, ); R d ) : ω = } be the canonical space of continuous paths equipped with the topology of locally uniform convergence. Moreover, let F = B(Ω) be its Borel σ-algebra. We denote by B := (B t ) t the canonical process B t (ω) = ω t, by P the Wiener measure and by F := (F t ) t the (raw) ltration generated by B. Furthermore, we denote by P(Ω) the set of all probability measures on Ω, equipped with the topology of weak convergence. We recall that a subset of a Polish space is called analytic if it is the image of a Borel subset of another Polish space under a Borel map. Moreover, an R- valued function f is called upper semianalytic if {f > c} is analytic for each c R; in particular, any Borel-measurable function is upper semianalytic. (See [1, Chapter 7] for background.) Finally, the universal completion of a σ-eld A is given by A := P A P, where A P denotes the completion with respect to P and the intersection is taken over all probability measures on A. Throughout this paper, stopping time will refer to a nite F-stopping time. Let τ be a stopping time. Then the concatenation of ω, ω Ω at τ is the path (ω τ ω) u := ω u 1 [,τ(ω)) (u) + ( ω τ(ω) + ω u τ(ω) ) 1[τ(ω), ) (u), u. For any probability measure P P(Ω), there is a regular conditional probability distribution {Pτ ω } ω Ω given F τ satisfying { ω Ω : ω = ω on [, τ(ω)] } = 1 for all ω Ω; P ω τ cf. [25, p. 34]. We then dene P τ,ω P(Ω) by P τ,ω (A) := P ω τ (ω τ A), A F, where ω τ A := {ω τ ω : ω A}. Given a function ξ on Ω and ω Ω, we also dene the function ξ τ,ω on Ω by ξ τ,ω ( ω) := ξ(ω τ ω), ω Ω. Then, we have E P τ,ω [ξ τ,ω ] = E P [ξ F τ ](ω) for P -a.e. ω Ω. 3

2.2 Preliminaries We formalize volatility uncertainty via a set of local martingale laws with dierent volatilities. To this end, we denote by S the set of all symmetric d d-matrices and by S > its subset of strictly positive denite matrices. The set P S P(Ω) consists of all local martingale laws of the form ( ) 1 P α = P αs 1/2 db s, (2.1) where α ranges over all F-progressively measurable processes with values in S > satisfying T α s ds < P -a.s. for every T R +. (We denote by the Euclidean norm in any dimension.) In other words, these are all laws of stochastic integrals of a Brownian motion, where the integrand is strictly positive and adapted to the Brownian motion. The set P S was introduced in [23] and its elements have several nice properties; in particular, they have the predictable representation property which plays an important role in the proof of the duality result below (see also Section 4). We intend to model uncertainty via a subset P P(Ω) (below, each P P will be a possible scenario for the volatility). However, for technical reasons, we make a detour and consider an entire family of subsets of P(Ω), indexed by (s, ω) R + Ω, whose elements at s = coincide with P. As illustrated in Example 2.1 below, this family is of purely auxiliary nature. Let {P(s, ω)} (s,ω) R+ Ω be a family of subsets of P(Ω), adapted in the sense that P(s, ω) = P(s, ω) if ω [,s] = ω [,s], and dene P(τ, ω) := P(τ(ω), ω) for any stopping time τ. Note that the set P(, ω) is independent of ω as all paths start at the origin. Thus, we can dene P := P(, ω). Before giving the example, let us state a condition on {P(s, ω)} whose purpose will be to construct the conditional sublinear expectation related to P. Condition (A). Let s R +, let τ be a stopping time such that τ s, let ω Ω and P P(s, ω). Set θ := τ s, ω s. (A1) The graph {(P, ω) : ω Ω, P P(τ, ω)} P(Ω) Ω is analytic. (A2) We have P θ,ω P(τ, ω s ω) for P -a.e. ω Ω. (A3) If ν : Ω P(Ω) is an F θ -measurable kernel and ν(ω) P(τ, ω s ω) for P -a.e. ω Ω, then the measure dened by P (A) = (1 A ) θ,ω (ω ) ν(dω ; ω) P (dω), A F (2.2) is an element of P(s, ω). 4

Conditions (A1)(A3) will ensure that the conditional expectation is measurable and satises the tower property (see Proposition 2.2 below), which is the dynamic programming principle in this context (see [1] for background). We remark that (A2) and (A3) imply that the family {P(s, ω)} is essentially determined by the set P. As mentioned above, in applications, P will be the primary object and we shall simply write down a corresponding family {P(s, ω)} such that P = P(, ω) and such that Condition (A) is satised. To illustrate this, let us state a model where the possible values of the volatility are described by a set-valued process D and which will be the main application of our results. This model was rst introduced in [9] and further studied in [13]; it generalizes the G-expectation of [15, 16] which corresponds to the case where D is a (deterministic) compact convex set. Example 2.1 (Random G-Expectation). We consider a set-valued process D : Ω R + 2 S ; i.e., D t (ω) is a set of matrices for each (t, ω). We assume that D is progressively graph-measurable: for every t R +, { (ω, s, A) Ω [, t] S : A Ds (ω) } F t B([, t]) B(S), where B([, t]) and B(S) denote the Borel σ-elds of S and [, t]. We want a set P consisting of all P P S under which the volatility takes values in D P -a.s. To this end, we introduce the auxiliary family {P(s, ω)}: given (s, ω) R + Ω, we dene P(s, ω) to be the collection of all P P S such that d B u du ( ω) D u+s(ω s ω) for P du-a.e. ( ω, u) Ω R +. (2.3) In particular, P := P(, ω) then consists, as desired, of all P P S such that d B u /du D u holds P du-a.e. We shall see in Corollary 2.6 that Condition (A) is satised in this example. The following is the main result of [13]; it is stated with the conventions sup = and E P [ξ] := if E P [ξ + ] = E P [ξ ] = +, and ess sup P denotes the essential supremum under P. Proposition 2.2. Suppose that {P(s, ω)} satises Condition (A) and that P =. Let σ τ be stopping times and let ξ : Ω R be an upper semianalytic function. Then the function E τ (ξ)(ω) := sup E P [ξ τ,ω ], P P(τ,ω) is F τ -measurable and upper semianalytic. Moreover, ω Ω E σ (ξ)(ω) = E σ (E τ (ξ))(ω) for all ω Ω. (2.4) Furthermore, with P(σ; P ) = {P P : P = P on F σ }, we have E σ (ξ) = ess sup P P P(σ;P ) E P [E τ (ξ) F σ ] P -a.s. for all P P. (2.5) 5

2.3 Main Results Some more notation is needed to state our duality result. In what follows, the set P determined by the family {P(s, ω)} will be a subset of P S. We shall use a nite time horizon T R + and the ltration G = (G t ) t T, where G t := F t N P ; here Ft is the universal completion of F t and N P is the collection of sets which are (F T, P )-null for all P P. Let H be a G-predictable process taking values in R d and such that T H u d B u H u < P -a.s. for all P P. Then H is called an admissible trading strategy if 1 H db is a P -supermartingale for all P P; as usual, this is to rule out doubling strategies. We denote by H the set of all admissible trading strategies. Theorem 2.3. Suppose {P(s, ω)} satises Condition (A) and = P P S. Moreover, let ξ : Ω R be an upper semianalytic, G T -measurable function such that sup P P E P [ ξ ] <. Then sup E P [ξ] P P { T } = min x R : H H with x + H u db u ξ P -a.s. for all P P. The assumption that P P S will be essential for our proof, which is stated in Section 4. In order to have nontrivial examples where the previous theorem applies, it is essential to know that the set P S (seen as a constant family P(s, ω) P S ) satises itself Condition (A). This fact is our main technical result. Theorem 2.4. The set P S satises Condition (A). The proof is stated Section 3. It is easy to see that if two families satisfy Condition (A), then so does their intersection. In particular, we have: Corollary 2.5. If {P(s, ω)} satises Condition (A), so does {P(s, ω) P S }. The following is the main application of our results. Corollary 2.6. The family {P(s, ω)} related to the random G-expectation (as dened in Example 2.1) satises Condition (A). In particular, the duality result of Theorem 2.3 applies in this case. 1 Here H db is, with some abuse of notation, the usual Itô integral under the xed measure P. We remark that we could also dene the integral simultaneously under all P P by the construction of [1]. This would yield a cosmetically nicer result, but we shall avoid the additional set-theoretic subtleties as this is not central to our approach. 6

Proof. Let M a P(Ω) be the set of all local martingale laws on Ω under which the quadratic variation of B is absolutely continuous with respect to the Lebesgue measure; then P S M a. Moreover, let P(s, ω) be the set of all P M a such that (2.3) holds. Then, clearly, P(s, ω) = P(s, ω) P S, and since we know from [13, Theorem 4.3] that { P(s, ω)} satises Condition (A), Corollary 2.5 shows that {P(s, ω)} again satises Condition (A). Remark 2.7. In view of (2.4), Theorem 2.4 yields the dynamic programming principle for the optimal control problem sup α E P [ξ(x α )] with a very general reward functional ξ, where X α = α1/2 s db s. We remark that the arguments in the proof of Theorem 2.4 could be extended to other control problems; for instance, the situation where the state process X α is dened as the solution of a stochastic functional/dierential equation as in [11]. 3 Proof of Theorem 2.4 In this section, we prove that P S (i.e., the constant family P(s, ω) P S ) satises Condition (A). Up to some minor dierences in notation, property (A2) was already shown in [23, Lemma 4.1], so we focus on (A1) and (A3). Let us x some more notation. We denote by E[ ] the expectation under the Wiener measure P ; more generally, any notion related to Ω that implicitly refers to a measure will be understood to refer to P. Unless otherwise stated, any topological space is endowed with its Borel σ-eld. As usual, L (Ω; R) denotes the set of equivalence classes of random variables on Ω, endowed with the topology of convergence in measure. Moreover, we denote by Ω = Ω R + the product space; here the measure is P dt by default, where dt is the Lebesgue measure. The basic space in this section is L ( Ω; S), the set of equivalence classes of S-valued processes that are product-measurable. We endow L ( Ω; S) (and its subspaces) with the topology of local convergence in measure; that is, the metric d(, ) = [ 2 k d k (, ) k ] 1 + d k (, ), where d k(x, Y ) = E 1 X s Y s ds. k N (3.1) As a result, X n X in L ( Ω; S) if and only if lim n E[ T 1 Xn s X s ds] = for all T R +. 3.1 Proof of (A1) The aim of this subsection is to show that P S P(Ω) is analytic. To this end, we shall show that P S P(Ω) is the image of a Borel space (i.e., a Borel subset of a Polish space) under a Borel map; this implies the claim by [1, Proposition 7.4, p. 165]. Indeed, let L prog( Ω; S) L ( Ω; S) be the subset 7

of F-progressively measurable processes and L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) = Moreover, we denote by { α L prog( Ω; S > ) : Φ : L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) P(Ω), T α s ds < P -a.s. for all T R + }. ( ) 1 α P α = P αs 1/2 db s (3.2) the map which associates to α the corresponding law. Then P S is the image P S = Φ(L 1 loc ( Ω; S > )); therefore, the claimed property (A1) follows from the two subsequent lemmas. Lemma 3.1. The space L prog( Ω; S) is Polish and L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) L prog( Ω; S) is Borel. Proof. We start by noting that L ( Ω; S) is Polish. Indeed, as R + and Ω are separable metric spaces, we have that L 2 (Ω [, T ]; S) is separable for all T N (e.g., [7, Section 6.15, p. 92]). A density argument and the denition (3.1) then show that L ( Ω; S) is again separable. On the other hand, the completeness of S is inherited by L ( Ω; S); see, e.g., [3, Corollary 3]. Since L prog( Ω; S) L ( Ω; S) is closed, it is again a Polish space. Next, we show that L 1 loc ( Ω; S) is a Borel subset of L prog( Ω; S). We rst observe that L 1 loc ( Ω; S) = {α L prog( Ω; [ ( T ) S) : P arctan α s ds π ] } =. 2 T N Therefore, it suces to show that for xed T N, ( T ) α P [arctan α s ds π ] 2 is Borel. Indeed, this is the composition of the function L (Ω; R) R, f P [f π/2], which is upper semicontinuous by the Portmanteau theorem and thus Borel, with the map ( T ) L prog( Ω; S) L (Ω; R), α arctan α s ds. The latter is Borel because it is, by monotone convergence, the pointwise limit of the maps ( T ) α arctan n α s ds, 8

which are continuous for xed n N due to the elementary estimate [ E 1 ( T arctan ) ( T n α s ds arctan [ T E ) ] n α s ds ] n α s α s ds. This completes the proof that L 1 loc ( Ω; S) is a Borel subset of L prog( Ω; S). To deduce the same property for L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ), note that L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) = { [ α L 1 loc ( Ω; S) : μ T α S S > ] = }, T N where μ T is the product measure μ T (A) = E[ T 1 A ds]. As S > S is open, α μ T [α S S > ] is upper semicontinuous and we conclude that L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) is again Borel. Lemma 3.2. The map Φ : L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) P(Ω) dened in (3.2) is Borel. Proof. Consider rst, for xed n N, the mapping Φ n dened by ( ) 1 Φ n (α) = P π n (αs 1/2 ) db s, where π n is the projection onto the ball of radius n around the origin in S. It follows from a direct extension of the dominated convergence theorem for stochastic integrals [19, Theorem IV.32, p. 176] that α π n (αs 1/2 ) db s is continuous for the topology of uniform convergence on compacts in probability (ucp), and hence that Φ n is continuous for the topology of weak convergence. In particular, Φ n is Borel. On the other hand, a second application of dominated convergence shows that π n (αs 1/2 ) db s α 1/2 s db s ucp as n for all α L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) and hence that Φ(α) = lim n Φ n (α) in P(Ω) for all α. Therefore, Φ is again Borel. 3.2 Proof of (A3) Given a stopping time τ, a measure P P S and an F τ -measurable kernel ν : Ω P(Ω) with ν(ω) P S for P -a.e. ω Ω, our aim is to show that P (A) := (1 A ) τ,ω (ω ) ν(ω, dω ) P (dω), A F 9

denes an element of P S. That is, we need to show that P = P α for some α L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ). In the case where ν has only countably many values, this can be accomplished by explicitly writing down an appropriate process α, as was shown already in [23]. The present setup requires general kernels and a measurable selection proof. Roughly speaking, up to time τ, α is given by the integrand α determining P, whereas after τ, it is given by the integrand of ν(ω), for a suitable ω. In Step 1 below, we state precisely the requirement for α; in Step 2, we construct a measurable selector for the integrand of ν(ω); nally, in Step 3, we show how to construct the required process α from this selector. Step 1. Let α L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) be such that P = P α, let X α := α1/2 s db s, and let τ := τ X α. Suppose we have found ˆα L prog( Ω; S) such that ˆα ω := ˆα + τ(ω) (ω τ ) L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) and P ˆαω = ν(x α (ω)) for P -a.e. ω Ω. Then P = P α for α dened by α s (ω) = α s (ω)1 [, τ(ω)] (s) + ˆα s (ω)1 ( τ(ω), ) (s). Indeed, we clearly have α L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ). Moreover, we note that τ is again a stopping time by Galmarino's test [4, Theorem IV.1, p. 149]. To see that P = P α, it suces to show that E P [ ψ ( B t1,..., B tn )] = E P [ ψ ( X α t1,..., X α t n )] for all n N, < t 1 < t 2 < < t n <, and any bounded continuous function ψ : R n R. Recall that B has stationary and independent increments under the Wiener measure P. For P -a.e. ω Ω such that t := τ(ω) [t j, t j+1 ), we have E P [ ψ ( X α t 1,..., X α t n ) F τ ] (ω) = E P [ ψ ( Xt α 1 (ω t B),..., X t α n (ω t [ ( B))] tj+1 = E P ψ Xt α 1 (ω),..., Xt α j (ω), X α t (ω) + ˆα s 1/2 (ω t B) db s t,..., t tn )] X α t (ω) + ˆα s 1/2 (ω t B) db s t and thus, by the denition of α ω, E P [ ψ ( Xt α 1,..., Xt α ) ] n F τ (ω) = E P [ αω ψ ( Xt α 1 (ω),..., Xt α j (ω), X α t (ω) + B t j+1 t,..., Xα t (ω) + B )] t n t = ψ ( Xt α 1 (ω),..., Xt α j (ω), X α t (ω) + B t j+1 t (ω ),..., t X α t (ω) + B t n t (ω ) ) ν ( X α (ω), dω ). 1

Integrating both sides with respect to P (dω) and noting that t [t j, t j+1 ) implies t := τ(ω) [t j, t j+1 ) P -a.s., we conclude that E P [ ψ ( Xt α 1,..., Xt α )] n = ψ ( Xt α 1 (ω),..., Xt α j (ω), X α t (ω) + B t j+1 t (ω ),..., = = X α t (ω) + B t n t (ω ) ) ν(x α (ω), dω ) P (dω) ψ ( B t1 (ω),..., B tj (ω), B t (ω) + B tj+1 t(ω ),..., B t (ω) + B tn t(ω ) ) ν(ω, dω ) P (dω) ψ τ,ω( ) B t1,..., B tn (ω ) ν(ω, dω ) P (dω) = E P [ ψ ( B t1,..., B tn )]. This completes the rst step of the proof. Step 2. We show that there exists an F τ -measurable function φ : Ω L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) such that P φ(ω) = ν(ω) for P -a.e. ω Ω. To this end, consider the set A = { (ω, α) Ω L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) : ν(ω) = P α}. We have seen in Lemma 3.1 that L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) is a Borel space. On the other hand, we have from Lemma 3.2 that α P α is Borel, and ν is Borel by assumption. Hence, A is a Borel subset of Ω L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ). As a result, we can use the Jankovvon Neumann theorem [1, Proposition 7.49, p. 182] to obtain an analytically measurable map φ from the Ω-projection of A to L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) whose graph is contained in A; that is, φ : {ω Ω : ν(ω) P S } L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) such that P φ( ) = ν( ). Since φ is, in particular, universally measurable, and since ν( ) P S P -a.s., we can alter φ on a P -nullset to obtain a Borel-measurable map φ : Ω L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) such that P φ( ) = ν( ) P -a.s. Finally, we can replace φ by ω φ(ω τ(ω) ), then we have the required F τ -measurability as a consequence of Galmarino's test. Moreover, since A F τ B(L 1 loc ( Ω; S > )) due to the F τ -measurability of ν, Galmarino's test also shows that we still have P φ( ) = ν( ) P -a.s., which completes the second step of the proof. Step 3. It remains to construct ˆα L prog( Ω; S) as postulated in Step 1. While the map φ constructed in Step 2 will eventually yield the processes ˆα ω 11

dened in Step 1, we note that φ is a map into a space of processes and so we still have to glue its values into an actual process. This is simple when there are only countably many values; therefore, following a construction of [2], we use an approximation argument. Since L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) is separable (always for the metric introduced in (3.1)), we can construct for any n N a countable Borel partition (A n,k ) k 1 of L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) such that the diameter of A n,k is smaller than 1/n. Moreover, we x γ n,k A n,k for k 1. Then, φ n (ω) := k 1 γ n,k 1 A n,k(φ(ω)) satises sup d(φ n (ω), φ(ω)) 1 ω Ω n ; (3.3) that is, φ n converges uniformly to φ, as an L 1 loc ( Ω; S > )-valued map. Let α and τ = τ X α be as in Step 1. Moreover, for any stopping time σ, denote ω σ := ω +σ(ω) ω σ(ω), ω Ω. Then, for xed n, the process (ω, s) ˆα n s (ω) := 1 [ τ(ω), ) (s)[φ n (X α (ω))] s τ(ω) (ω τ(ω) ) 1 [ τ(ω), ) (s) k 1 γ n,k s τ(ω) (ω τ(ω) )1 A n,k(φ(x α (ω))) is well dened P -a.s., and in fact an element of the Polish space L prog( Ω; S). We show that (ˆα n ) is a Cauchy sequence and that the limit ˆα yields the desired process. Fix T R + and m, n N, then (3.3) implies that Ω T 1 [φm (ω)] s (ω ) [φ n (ω)] s (ω ) ds P (dω ) c T ( 1 m + 1 n ) (3.4) for all ω Ω, where c T is an unimportant constant coming from the denition of d in (3.1). In particular, Ω Ω T 1 [φ m (X α (ω))] s (ω ) [φ n (X α (ω))] s (ω ) ds P (dω ) P (dω) ( 1 c T m + 1 ). (3.5) n Since P is the Wiener measure, we have the formula g(ω τ(ω), ω τ ) P (dω) = g(ω τ(ω), ω ) P (dω ) P (dω) Ω Ω Ω 12

for any bounded, progressively measurable functional g on Ω Ω. As φ is F τ -measurable, we conclude from (3.5) that T ( 1 1 ˆα s m (ω) ˆα s n (ω) ds P (dω) c T m + 1 ). (3.6) n Ω This implies that (ˆα n ) is Cauchy for the metric d. Let ˆα L prog( Ω; S) be the limit. Then, using again the same formula, we obtain that φ n (X α (ω)) = ˆα n + τ(ω) (ω τ ) ˆα + τ(ω) (ω τ ) ˆα ω with respect to d, for P -a.e. ω Ω, after passing to a subsequence. On the other hand, by (3.3), we also have φ n (X α (ω)) φ(x α (ω)) for P -a.e. ω Ω. Hence, ˆα ω = φ(x α (ω)) for P -a.e. ω Ω. In view of Step 2, we have φ(x α (ω)) L 1 loc ( Ω; S > ) and P φ(xα (ω)) = ν(x α (ω)) for P -a.e. ω Ω. Hence, ˆα satises all requirements from Step 1 and the proof is complete. 4 Proof of Theorem 2.3 We note that one inequality in Theorem 2.3 is trivial: if x R and there exists H H such that x + T H db ξ, the supermartingale property stated in the denition of H implies that x E P [ξ] for all P P. Hence, our aim in this section is to show that there exists H H such that sup E P [ξ] + P P T H u db u ξ P -a.s. for all P P. (4.1) The line of argument (see also the Introduction) is similar as in [23] or [12]; hence, we shall be brief. We rst recall the following known result (e.g., [8, Theorem 1.5], [22, Lemma 8.2], [12, Lemma 4.4]) about the P -augmentation F P of F; it is the main motivation to work with P S as the basic set of scenarios. We denote by G + = {G t+ } t T the minimal right-continuous ltration containing G. Lemma 4.1. Let P P S. Then F P is right-continuous and in particular contains G +. Moreover, P has the predictable representation property; i.e., for any right-continuous (F P, P )-local martingale M there exists an F P - predictable process H such that M = M + H db, P -a.s. We recall our assumption that sup P P E P [ ξ ] < and that ξ is G T - measurable. We also recall from Proposition 2.2 that the random variable E t (ξ)(ω) := sup E P [ξ t,ω ] P P(t,ω) 13

is G t -measurable for all t R +. Moreover, we note that E T (ξ) = ξ P -a.s. for all P P. Indeed, for any xed P P, Lemma 4.1 implies that we can nd an F T -measurable function ξ which is equal to ξ outside a P -nullset N F T, and now the denition of E T (ξ) and Galmarino's test show that E T (ξ) = E T (ξ ) = ξ = ξ outside N. Step 1. We x t and show that sup P P E P [ E t (ξ) ] <. Note that ξ need not be upper semianalytic, so that the claim does not follows directly from (2.4). Hence, we make a small detour and rst observe that P is stable in the following sense: if P P, Λ F t and P 1, P 2 P(t; P ) (notation from Proposition 2.2), the measure P dened by P (A) := E P [ P 1 (A F t )1 Λ + P 2 (A F t )1 Λ c], A F is again an element of P. Indeed, this follows from (A2) and (A3) as P (A) = (1 A ) t,ω (ω ) ν(ω, dω ) P (dω) for the kernel ν(ω, dω ) = P t,ω 1 (dω ) 1 Λ (ω) + P t,ω 2 (dω ) 1 Λ c(ω). Following a standard argument, this stability implies that for any P P, there exist P n P(t; P ) such that E Pn [ ξ F t ] ess sup P E P [ ξ F t ] P P(t;P ) P -a.s. Since (2.5), applied with τ = T, yields that [ ] [ ] E P [ E t (ξ) ] = E P ess sup P E P [ξ F t ] E P ess sup P E P [ ξ F t ], P P(t;P ) P P(t;P ) monotone convergence then allows us to conclude that E P [ E t (ξ) ] lim n EPn [ ξ ] sup E P [ ξ ] <. P P Step 2. We show that the right limit Y t := E t+ (ξ) denes a (G +, P )- supermartingale for all P P. Indeed, Step 1 and (2.5) show that E t (ξ) is an (F, P )-supermartingale for all P P. The standard modication theorem for supermartingales [5, Theorem VI.2] then yields that Y is well dened P -a.s. and that Y is a (G +, P )-supermartingale for all P P, where the second conclusion uses Lemma 4.1. We omit the details; they are similar as in the proof of [12, Proposition 4.5]. For later use, let us also establish the inequality Y sup E P [ξ] P -a.s. for all P P. (4.2) P P 14

Indeed, let P P. Then [5, Theorem VI.2] shows that E P [Y F ] E (ξ) P -a.s., where, of course, we have E P [Y F ] = E P [Y ] P -a.s. since F = {, Ω}. However, as Y is G + -measurable and G + is P -a.s. trivial by Lemma 4.1, we also have that Y = E P [Y ] P -a.s. In view of the denition of E (ξ), the inequality (4.2) follows. Step 3. Next, we construct the process H H. In view of Step 2, we can x P P and consider the DoobMeyer decomposition Y = Y + M P K P under P, in the ltration F P. By Lemma 4.1, the local martingale M P can be represented as an integral, M P = H P db, for some F P -predictable integrand H P. The crucial observation (due to [23]) is that this process can be described via d Y, B = H P d B, and that, as the quadratic covariation processes can be constructed pathwise by Bichteler's integral [2, Theorem 7.14], this relation allows to dene a process H such that H = H P P dt-a.e. for all P P. More precisely, since Y, B is continuous, it is not only adapted to G +, but also to G, and hence we see by going through the arguments in the proof of [12, Proposition 4.11] that H can be obtained as a G-predictable process in our setting. To conclude that H H, note that for every P P, the local martingale H db is P -a.s. bounded from below by the martingale E P [ξ G]; hence, on the compact [, T ], it is a supermartingale as a consequence of Fatou's lemma. Summing up, we have found H H such that Y + T H u db u Y T = E T + (ξ) = ξ P -a.s. for all P P, and in view of (4.2), this implies (4.1). References [1] D. P. Bertsekas and S. E. Shreve. Stochastic Optimal Control. The Discrete- Time Case. Academic Press, New York, 1978. [2] K. Bichteler. Stochastic integration and L p -theory of semimartingales. Ann. Probab., 9(1):4989, 1981. [3] D. M. Chung. On the local convergence in measure. Bull. Korean Math. Soc., 18(2):5153, 1981/82. [4] C. Dellacherie and P. A. Meyer. Probabilities and Potential A. North Holland, Amsterdam, 1978. [5] C. Dellacherie and P. A. Meyer. Probabilities and Potential B. North Holland, Amsterdam, 1982. [6] L. Denis and C. Martini. A theoretical framework for the pricing of contingent claims in the presence of model uncertainty. Ann. Appl. Probab., 16(2):827 852, 26. 15

[7] J. L. Doob. Measure theory, volume 143 of Graduate Texts in Mathematics. Springer-Verlag, New York, 1994. [8] J. Jacod and M. Yor. Étude des solutions extrémales et représentation intégrale des solutions pour certains problèmes de martingales. Z. Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie und Verw. Gebiete, 38(2):83125, 1977. [9] M. Nutz. Random G-expectations. To appear in Ann. Appl. Probab., 21. [1] M. Nutz. Pathwise construction of stochastic integrals. Electron. Commun. Probab., 17(24):17, 212. [11] M. Nutz. A quasi-sure approach to the control of non-markovian stochastic dierential equations. Electron. J. Probab., 17(23):123, 212. [12] M. Nutz and H. M. Soner. Superhedging and dynamic risk measures under volatility uncertainty. SIAM J. Control Optim., 5(4):265289, 212. [13] M. Nutz and R. van Handel. Constructing sublinear expectations on path space. To appear in Stochastic Process. Appl., 212. [14] M. Nutz and J. Zhang. Optimal stopping under adverse nonlinear expectation and related games. Preprint arxiv:1212.214v1, 212. [15] S. Peng. G-expectation, G-Brownian motion and related stochastic calculus of Itô type. In Stochastic Analysis and Applications, volume 2 of Abel Symp., pages 541567, Springer, Berlin, 27. [16] S. Peng. Multi-dimensional G-Brownian motion and related stochastic calculus under G-expectation. Stochastic Process. Appl., 118(12):22232253, 28. [17] S. Peng. Nonlinear expectations and stochastic calculus under uncertainty. Preprint arxiv:12.4546v1, 21. [18] D. Possamai, G. Royer, and N. Touzi. On the robust superhedging of measurable claims. Preprint arxiv:132.185v1, 213. [19] P. Protter. Stochastic Integration and Dierential Equations. Springer, New York, 2nd edition, version 2.1, 25. [2] H. M. Soner and N. Touzi. Dynamic programming for stochastic target problems and geometric ows. J. Eur. Math. Soc. (JEMS), 4(3):21236, 22. [21] H. M. Soner, N. Touzi, and J. Zhang. Martingale representation theorem for the G-expectation. Stochastic Process. Appl., 121(2):265287, 211. [22] H. M. Soner, N. Touzi, and J. Zhang. Quasi-sure stochastic analysis through aggregation. Electron. J. Probab., 16(2):18441879, 211. [23] H. M. Soner, N. Touzi, and J. Zhang. Dual formulation of second order target problems. Ann. Appl. Probab., 23(1):38347, 213. [24] Y. Song. Some properties on G-evaluation and its applications to G-martingale decomposition. Sci. China Math., 54(2):2873, 211. [25] D. Stroock and S. R. S. Varadhan. Multidimensional Diusion Processes. Springer, New York, 1979. 16