More on Adaptive Learning and Applications in Monetary Policy. Noah Williams

Similar documents
Learning and Monetary Policy. Lecture 4 Recent Applications of Learning to Monetary Policy

Adaptive Learning and Applications in Monetary Policy. Noah Williams

Recurent Hyperinflations and Learning

Evolution and Intelligent Design

Bayesian Econometrics of Learning Models (lecture notes for the Dynare learning workshop)

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SHOCKS AND GOVERNMENT BELIEFS: THE RISE AND FALL OF AMERICAN INFLATION. Thomas Sargent Noah Williams Tao Zha

Expectations, Learning and Macroeconomic Policy

Learning and Monetary Policy

POLICY GAMES. u t = θ 0 θ 1 π t + ε t. (1) β t (u 2 t + ωπ 2 t ). (3)

POLICY GAMES. u t = θ 0 θ 1 π t + ε t. (1) β t (u 2 t + ωπ 2 t ). (3) π t = g t 1 + ν t. (4) g t = θ 1θ 0 ω + θ 2 1. (5)

Eco504, Part II Spring 2008 C. Sims POLICY GAMES

THE CONQUEST OF SOUTH AMERICAN INFLATION

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ATLANTA

Indeterminacy and Sunspots in Macroeconomics

Identifying the Monetary Policy Shock Christiano et al. (1999)

THE CONQUEST OF SOUTH AMERICAN INFLATION

Signaling Effects of Monetary Policy

Adaptive Learning in Macroeconomics: some methodological issues

Learning in Macroeconomic Models

The Return of the Gibson Paradox

A Discussion of Arouba, Cuba-Borda and Schorfheide: Macroeconomic Dynamics Near the ZLB: A Tale of Two Countries"

PANEL DISCUSSION: THE ROLE OF POTENTIAL OUTPUT IN POLICYMAKING

Macroeconomics II. Dynamic AD-AS model

Dynamic AD-AS model vs. AD-AS model Notes. Dynamic AD-AS model in a few words Notes. Notation to incorporate time-dimension Notes

Fiscal Multipliers in a Nonlinear World

Learning to Live in a Liquidity Trap

Forward Guidance without Common Knowledge

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Taylor Rules and Technology Shocks

Searching for the Output Gap: Economic Variable or Statistical Illusion? Mark W. Longbrake* J. Huston McCulloch

ADVANCED MACROECONOMICS I

Lecture 4 The Centralized Economy: Extensions

Inflation Expectations and Monetary Policy Design: Evidence from the Laboratory

F11. Lecture 7. Inflation and Unemployment M&I 6. Adaptive vs Rational Expectations. M&B 19, p. 24

Douglas Laxton Economic Modeling Division January 30, 2014

Chapter 6. Maximum Likelihood Analysis of Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) Models

New Keynesian Model Walsh Chapter 8

Aspects of Stickiness in Understanding Inflation

MA Macroeconomics 3. Introducing the IS-MP-PC Model

Lecture 7. The Dynamics of Market Equilibrium. ECON 5118 Macroeconomic Theory Winter Kam Yu Department of Economics Lakehead University

Eco504 Spring 2009 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM

Learning to Optimize: Theory and Applications

Optimal Simple And Implementable Monetary and Fiscal Rules

Benefits from U.S. Monetary Policy Experimentation in the Days of Samuelson and Solow and Lucas

Source: US. Bureau of Economic Analysis Shaded areas indicate US recessions research.stlouisfed.org

Nowcasting Norwegian GDP

1.2. Structural VARs

The US Phillips Curve and inflation expectations: A State. Space Markov-Switching explanatory model.

Are Policy Counterfactuals Based on Structural VARs Reliable?

Identifying Aggregate Liquidity Shocks with Monetary Policy Shocks: An Application using UK Data

Forward Guidance without Common Knowledge

Adverse Effects of Monetary Policy Signalling

Perceived productivity and the natural rate of interest

Lecture 8: Aggregate demand and supply dynamics, closed economy case.

Toulouse School of Economics, Macroeconomics II Franck Portier. Homework 1 Solutions. Problem I An AD-AS Model

Learning and Global Dynamics

INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT: THE PHILLIPS CURVE. Dongpeng Liu Department of Economics Nanjing University

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2013

Modelling Czech and Slovak labour markets: A DSGE model with labour frictions

MA Macroeconomics 4. Analysing the IS-MP-PC Model

Expectations and Monetary Policy

The New Keynesian Model: Introduction

Learning and the Evolution of the Fed s Inflation Target

Strong Contagion with Weak Spillovers

1. Money in the utility function (start)

The Lucas Imperfect Information Model

Generalized Stochastic Gradient Learning

A Dynamic Model of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Discussion Global Dynamics at the Zero Lower Bound

Point, Interval, and Density Forecast Evaluation of Linear versus Nonlinear DSGE Models

Lessons of the long quiet ELB

Dynamics and Monetary Policy in a Fair Wage Model of the Business Cycle

Econ 5110 Solutions to the Practice Questions for the Midterm Exam

A Summary of Economic Methodology

The Return of the Wage Phillips Curve

Animal Spirits, Fundamental Factors and Business Cycle Fluctuations

Monetary Policy and Heterogeneous Expectations

Identification of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve: Problems and Consequences

THE CASE OF THE DISAPPEARING PHILLIPS CURVE

Behavioural & Experimental Macroeconomics: Some Recent Findings

Estimating Unobservable Inflation Expectations in the New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Model uncertainty and endogenous volatility

Ergodicity and Non-Ergodicity in Economics

A Bayesian DSGE Model with Infinite-Horizon Learning: Do Mechanical Sources of Persistence Become Superfluous?

Escape Dynamics in Learning Models

Can News be a Major Source of Aggregate Fluctuations?

On Determinacy and Learnability in a New Keynesian Model with Unemployment

Bayesian Econometrics - Computer section

Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models. December 4, 2007

An Anatomy of the Business Cycle Data

A Modern Equilibrium Model. Jesús Fernández-Villaverde University of Pennsylvania

The Dornbusch overshooting model

Fundamental Disagreement

Indeterminacy and Learning: An Analysis of Monetary Policy in the Great Inflation

Estimating and Accounting for the Output Gap with Large Bayesian Vector Autoregressions

Monetary Policy and Unemployment: A New Keynesian Perspective

Topic 9. Monetary policy. Notes.

GCOE Discussion Paper Series

The New Keynesian Model

Transcription:

More on Adaptive Learning and Applications in Monetary Policy Noah University of Wisconsin - Madison Econ 899

Beyond E-Stability: Perpetual Learning Orphanides and J. (2005). Lucas-type aggregate supply curve for inflation π t : π t+1 = φπ e t+1 + (1 φ)π t + αy t+1 + e t+1, Output gap y t+1 is set by monetary policy up to white noise control error y t+1 = x t + u t+1. Policy objective function L = (1 ω)var(y) + ωvar(π π ) gives rule x t = θ(π t π ). where under RE θ = θ P (ω, φ, α).

Perpetual Learning Under RE inflation satisfies π t = c 0 + c 1 π t 1 + v t. Under learning private agents estimate coefficients by constant gain (or discounted) least squares. Older data dated discounted at rate (1 ε). Discounting of data natural if agents are concerned to track structural shifts. There is empirical support for constant gain learning. With constant gain, LS estimates fluctuate randomly around ( c 0, c 1 ): there is perpetual learning and π e t+1 = c 0,t + c 1,t π t.

Perpetual Learning Results Perpetual learning increases inflation persistence. Naive application of RE policy leads to inefficient policy. Incorporating learning into policy response can lead to major improvement. Efficient policy is more hawkish, i.e. under learning policy should increase θ to reduce persistence. This helps guide expectations. Following a sequence of unanticipated inflation shocks, inflation doves (i.e. policy-makers with low θ) can do very poorly, as expectations become detached from RE. If agents know π and only estimate the AR(1) parameter the policy trade-off is more favorable.

Learning and inflation persistence Preceding analysis was an example of empirics based on calibration. Now we consider work that estimates learning dynamics (Milani 2005, 2007). The source of inflation persistence is subject to dispute. For good empirical fit, a backward-looking component is needed in the NK Phillips curve. The bulk of the literature assumes RE, but learning could be a reason for inflation persistence. Incorporate indexation to Calvo price setting: non-optimized prices indexed to past inflation. This yields π t γπ t 1 = δx t + βe t (π t+1 γπ t ) + u t, where x t is the output gap. Earlier work under RE finds γ 1.

Inflation under learning The preceding can be written as π t = γ 1 + βγ π t 1 + β 1 + βγ E t π t+1 + δ 1 + βγ x t + u t. For expectations assume a PLM π t = φ 0,t + φ 1,t π t 1 + ε t Agents use data {1, π i } t 1 0 to estimate φ 0, φ 1 using constant gain LS. The implied ALM is π t = βφ 0,t(1 + φ 1,t ) 1 + βγ + γ + βφ2 1,t 1 + βγ π t 1 + δ 1 + βγ x t + u t. Alternatively, could use with real marginal cost as the driving variable.

Empirical Model Data: GDP deflator, output gap is detrended GDP, real marginal cost is proxied by deviation of labor income share from 1960:01 to 2003:04. Initialization: agents initial parameter estimates obtained by using pre-sample data 1951-1959. Methodology: PLM estimated from constant-gain learning using ε = 0.015. Then estimate ALM using nonlinear LS, which separates learning effects from structural effects. Note: Simultaneous estimation of learning rule and the model would be much more ambitious.

Empirical Results PLM parameters: (i) φ 1,t initially low in 1950s and 60s, then higher (up to 0.958), then some decline to values above 0.8. (ii) φ 0,t initially low, then became much higher and then gradual decline after 1980. ALM structural estimates: Degree of indexation γ = 0.139 (with output gap & ε = 0.015) and declining for higher ε. Model fit criterion (Schwartz BIC) suggest values ε (0.015, 0.03), with best fit at ε = 0.02. Conclusion: Estimates for γ not significantly different from zero. Results are very different from those obtained under RE, which finds γ 1. Milani has also estimated full NK models under learning. He finds that also the degree of habit persistence is low in IS curve.

Learning by Policymakers So far have focused on learning by private agents and its implications for policy. However policymakers as well must learn about the economy. Beliefs of policymakers very influential, since they are large agents. Variation in beliefs or misspecification of model by policymakers can have a large impact on equilibrium dynamics. Sargent (1999) showed that misspecification and learning by policymakers can lead to temporary improvements in outcomes: Escaping Nash Inflation Model analyzed by Cho,, and Sargent (2002), Sargent and (2005), estimated by Sargent,, and Zha (2006)

The Conquest Model The economy is a simple rational expectations natural rate Phillips curve model: U n = u (π n ˆx n ) + σ 1 W 1n π n = x n + σ 2 W 2n ˆx n = x n Rational expectations: - Time consistency problem. - Nash inflation (u) > Ramsey inflation (0). Here: - Public has rational expectations. - Government doesn t know Phillips curve, learns adaptively.

The Government s Beliefs Government s Phillips curve model: Beliefs: γ = [γ 1, γ 1 ]. U n = γ 1 π n + γ 1 + η n, Can generalize to allow lags of inflation, unemployment in regression. Govt. treats regression error as orthogonal: ( [ ]) πn Ê η n = 0. 1 Use notation: Êg(γ, ξ n ) = 0.

The Government s Problem Based on estimates, each period government solves: ( ) min Ê U 2 x n + πn 2 n Results in feedback policy: x n = h(γ). A self-confirming equilibrium (SCE) is a vector γ such that the government s beliefs are confirmed by its observations: Eg(γ, ξ n ) = 0, where : - (U n, π n ) follow the true evolution given x n - x n solves government s problem given γ. Note: Unique SCE with Nash inflation level. If γ 1 = 0, x n = 0 : Ramsey outcome.

Adaptation of Beliefs Government updates beliefs γ n based on data. Sets inflation as h(γ n ). Govt. believes data are generated by: U n = α n 1Φ n + η n, (Eη 2 n = σ 2 ) α n = α n 1 + Λ n, (cov(λ n ) = V ) where Φ n = [π n, 1]. Update beliefs using CG RLS: γ n+1 = γ n + ɛrn 1 g(γ n, ξ n ) R n+1 = R n + ɛ(φ n Φ n R n ), Implicitly assumes V = ɛ 2 σ 2 E(ΦΦ ) 1 and σ = σ 1 (regression error=unemployment shocks) In this case, Kalman filter and RLS have same limits, different transient behavior. Sargent and (2005) study more general priors on V.

Learning in the Model Stability of SCE governed by same E-stability results as before. Find that SCE is E-stable, suggests beliefs should converge to it. However in simulations observe repeated episodes of decreases in inflation from Nash level down to Ramsey/commitment level of zero. The low inflation episodes are driven by reductions in government s estimated Phillips curve slope to near zero. Analyze the escape dynamics characterizing movements away from the SCE.

Conquest of American Inflation

Escape Dynamics Escape = beliefs fixed distance from SCE Convergence theorem probability of escape 0 as ε 0. For fixed ε, may be rare escapes. If an unlikely event occurs, it is very likely to occur in the most likely way. (2002-14), CWS determine: - most likely escape direction and full time path - probability of escape and bounds on escape times

Characterzing Escapes To find most likely escape path, find least cost perturbations v that push the beliefs out of a set G containing the SCE. Solve the least-squares control problem: s.t. 1 T S = inf { v,t} 2 0 γ = R 1 g(γ) + v γ(0) = γ, γ(t) / G. v(s) Q(γ(s)) 1 v(s)ds Minimizing path is most likely as w.p.1 all escape paths become close to minimizing path as ε 0. Times between escapes increase exponentially as ε 0, minimized value S determines rate of increase.

Distribution of Escapes

Direction of Escapes

Escape Paths

Interpretation of Results Starting at SCE, central bank downweights past observations. Occasionally will get a sequence of correlated shocks to inflation and unemployment. Implies unemployment varies less for a given inflation rate. Government reads this as a shift in Phillips curve toward more vertical. In response will cut inflation. Since have been near SCE, movements in intended inflation rate very influential for belief estimates. Leads to (locally) self-reinforcing dynamics: government believes Phillips curve even more vertical, cuts inflation more.

Implications of Results Once Phillips curve slope is zero, inflation set to zero. Economy remains near there for a while. Eventually shocks to inflation and unemployment make government pick up on true Phillips curve slope. Increases inflation, revises beliefs. But this process is slow. Government can temporarily learn to set optimal policy even if model is misspecified. Suggests lower inflation in US since 1970s may not be driven by changes in Fed s model, but just changes in estimates of that model. Does this story fit empirically?

Sargent,, Zha (2006) How to explain the Great Inflation of the 1970s, the decline in 1980s and relative stability in 1990s to the present? Has policy changed? Was it luck (shocks)? Is the improvement in outcomes sustainable? Can policy be modeled in a optimizing manner, rationalizing and explaining rise and fall in US inflation?

What We Do Develop structural model of learning with optimizing government. Able to explain rise & fall of inflation. Estimate and analyze predictions. Analyze intermediate and long run behavior of model. Interpretation of US experience: - Policy objective unchanged, but beliefs change over time. As in Sargent (1999), Primiceri (2003a) but different mechanism - Large shocks in 1970s accommodated, led to large inflation. - Not shocks vs. policy, but shocks policy. - 1980s disinflation due to different govt. beliefs: Believed less or no Phillips curve tradeoff

A More General Model Economy: Expectational Phillips curve, govt. controls inflation u t u = θ 0 (π t E t 1 π t ) + θ 1 (π t 1 E t 2 π t 1 ) +τ 1 (u t 1 u ) + σ 1 w 1t, [w 1t N (0, 1)] π t = x t 1 + σ 2 w 2t, [w 2t N (0, 1)] Government problem: minê x t 1 β t ((π t π ) 2 + λ(u t u ) 2 ) t=1 subject to inflation equation and subjective model: u t = ˆα t t 1 Φ t + σw t, Φ t = [π t, π t 1, u t 1, π t 2, u t 2, 1] π t = f (ˆα t t 1 )Φ t

Government s Model Govt doesn t account for expectations misspecified model. Key identifying assumption: E [ Φ t (u t Φ tα) ] = 0 Govt always assumes it holds. Actually holds in a self-confirming equilibrium. Govt bases estimates ˆα t t 1 = E t 1 (α) on: u t = α tφ t + σw t, w t N (0, 1) α t = α t 1 + Λ t, Λ t N (0, V ) Updates ˆα t t 1 (and P t t 1 ) via Kalman filter

Estimation Estimate govt prior beliefs σ 2 and V along with structure. Fix β =.9936, λ = 1, π = 2, u = 1. Fix ˆα 1 0 on pre-sample regression from 1948-1959. Estimate remaining: u, τ 1, θ 0, θ 1, ζ 1 = σ 2 1, ζ 2 = σ 2 2, and C P, C V s.t. C P C P = P 1 0, C V C V = V. Need to normalize σ 2 : would scale with beliefs P t t 1 and V. Set σ = σ 1 : Govt. prior var of u t shocks = true var. Use Bayesian methods (MLE similar). Gaussian likelihood L(I T φ), specify prior p(φ), maximize posterior: p(φ I T ) L (I T φ) p(φ)

Inference: Inflation 14 12 Actual Lower band Higher band 10 8 6 4 2 0 2 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 From March 1960 to December 2003 Actual vs one-step forecast with 90% error bands

Medium Run Dynamics So far have focused on fit one step ahead. Now look out to horizon of 4+ years. Take estimated initial conditions at each date, run 5000 Monte Carlo simulations going forward 50 periods. Focus on 1970s high inflation episodes and early 1980s disinflation. Assess model s implications for rise & fall.

Initial Condition: January, 1974 15 Actual Median forecast 10 Inflation rate (percent) 5 0 5 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 Forecast months after 74:01

Initial Condition: April, 1980 15 Actual Median forecast 10 Inflation rate (percent) 5 0 5 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 Forecast months after 80:04

Interpretation (Our) Previous research in this line has emphasized the time-consistency problem. [In contrast to Blinder (1998).] Not a major issue here: estimate small responses to inflation surprises. Nash inflation close to Ramsey (2.25 % vs. 2%). Government beliefs are still important, but so are shocks. Throughout early 1970s govt believed in Phillips curve tradeoff. One diagnostic: sum of coefficients on inflation. Implied very high perceived sacrifice ratio: very costly in unemployment terms to bring inflation down in response to a shock. Large shocks in 1970s were accommodated.

Government Beliefs 1 Sum of π coefs 0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 From March 1960 to December 2003 Sum of coefficients on π. If 0 no LR tradeoff.

Government s Perceived Sacrifice Ratio Perceived LR u u from switching to 2% inflation

Comparison to Literature Primiceri (2006): Different learning with same basic aim. - His fit is more comparable to a VAR. - Emphasizes high perceived sacrifice ratio, but also mismeasurement of natural rate. - Key difference theoretical: his main model is Keynesian, backward-looking. Cogley-Sargent (2006): Government has three different models, adapts weight it puts on them over time. Weight on Samuelson-Solow model low by mid-70s but very high losses if cut inflation, dominates.

South American Inflation: Sargent,, Zha (2009) In last 30 years several Latin American countries experienced repeated hyperinflations of 100-400% per month. What led to these, and how could they re-occur? Conventional view: Hyperinflation is a fiscal problem. But weak direct empirical results. Unorthodox view: Fiscal/monetary aspects not important. Our approach: Adaptive learning by private sector, time varying seignorage needs, time varying volatility. Minor departure from rational expectations allows us to fit data, provides insights on causes and consequences of hyperinflations. Rehabilitation of fiscal causes.

Adaptive and REE dynamics Mean adaptive dynamics and REE dynamics. π t β t G(β t ) π 1 π 2 β t H(β t )

Adaptive and REE dynamics Mean adaptive dynamics and REE dynamics. π t β t G(β t ) π 1 π 2 β t H(β t )

Adaptive dynamics and escapes Adaptive dynamics and the escape event. π t β t G(β t ) π 1 π 2 β t

Adaptive dynamics and escapes Adaptive dynamics and the escape event. π t β t G(β t ) π 1 π 2 β t

The Model Money demand: M t P t = 1 γ λ γ Government budget constraint: P e t+1 P t M t = θm t 1 + d t (s t )P t Deficit process, with regimes s t = [m t, v t ] (fiscal policy): d t (m t, v t ) = d(m t ) + η d t (v t ) Pr(m t+1 = i m t = j) = qij m, i, j = 1,..., m h Pr(v t+1 = i v t = j) = qij, v i, j = 1,..., v h {γ,d t (s t )} not identified, so normalize γ = 1 in estimation.

Beliefs Private sector forecasts inflation in setting money demand. Assume learns adaptively from past inflation observations. πt+1 b = β t β t = β t 1 + ε(π t 1 β t 1 ) ε is called the gain, giving weight on past observations. We assume it s constant: agents discount past data.

No-Breakdown Conditions Equilibrium inflation: π t = θ(1 λβ t 1) 1 λβ t d t (s t ) Makes sense only if numerator and denominator are both positive: Positive prices and positive real balances. For moments of inflation to exist, need denominator bounded away from zero. Thus we require, for some δ > 0: 1 λβ t 1 > 0, 1 λβ t d t (s t ) > δθ(1 λβ t 1 ), Leads to truncated normal distribution for η d.

Reforms Possible that a sequence of seignorage shocks pushes beliefs β t above high SS π2. Escape from domain of attraction of lower, stable equilibrium. Makes model unstable. May eventually threaten the no-breakdown conditions. Our solution: Reset inflation (to lower REE plus noise) after threatened breakdowns: π t = π t (s t ) π 1(s t ) + η π t (s t ) where η π is truncated normal. Stands in for cosmetic reforms (exchange rates, capital controls) which did not alter seignorage process. Beliefs may be slow to adjust reforms not immediately credible.

Estimation Our parameter estimates maximize the likelihood of a history of inflation, π t, t = 1,..., T. We use the model s joint density and the inflation data to estimate money creation rates and compare to data. The likelihood function is challenging numerically. Blocking and parallel computing come to our rescue.

Argentina Conditional SCEs Log Belief log β t 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.1 0 0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 βt 0.3 Deficits Data Model 0.2 0.1 0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 1 Probability 0.8 L deficit Escape 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 1 log π t Actual Prediction 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

Argentina: Beliefs

Argentina: Deficits

Argentina: Escapes and Regimes

Argentina: Inflation

Argentina Conditional SCEs Log Belief log β t 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.1 0 0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 βt 0.3 Deficits Data Model 0.2 0.1 0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 1 Probability 0.8 L deficit Escape 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 1 log π t Actual Prediction 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

Brazil 0.5 Conditional SCEs 0.5 Log Belief 0.4 0.4 log β t 0.3 0.2 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.1 0 0.5 0 0.5 0 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 βt Data Model 0.1 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0 Deficits 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 1 Probability 0.8 L & M deficit Escape 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 log π t 0.6 Actual Prediction 0.4 0.2 0 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

The Rise and Fall of Hyperinflation Different hyperinflations were driven by different factors (escapes, shocks) and ended by different factors (monetary reform, fiscal deficit reform, smaller shocks). Table: Causes of the rise and fall of hyperinflation across countries Escape No Escape Monetary Reform Brazil (87-91) Peru (87-92) Fiscal Deficit Reform Argentina (87-91) Bolivia (82-86) Brazil (92-95) No Reform (Driven by Chile (71-78) Argentina (76-86) Deficit Shocks)

Conclusion Expectations play a large role in modern macroeconomics. People are smart, but boundedly rational. Cognitive consistency principle: economic agents should be about as smart as (good) economists, e.g. model agents as econometricians. Stability of RE under private agent learning is not automatic. Monetary policy must be designed to ensure both determinacy and stability under learning. Policymakers may need to use policy to guide expectations. Under learning there is the possibility of persistent deviations from RE. Appropriate policy design can minimize these risks. Learning dynamics can also help explain persistence of inflation and output dynamics, volatility of inflation, and rises and falls of inflation.