Non-Life Insurance: Mathematics and Statistics

Similar documents
Non-Life Insurance: Mathematics and Statistics

Non-Life Insurance: Mathematics and Statistics

A Note On The Erlang(λ, n) Risk Process

Proving the central limit theorem

Choice under Uncertainty

Lecture 2: Convex Sets and Functions

Experience Rating in General Insurance by Credibility Estimation

VaR vs. Expected Shortfall

Two hours. To be supplied by the Examinations Office: Mathematical Formula Tables and Statistical Tables THE UNIVERSITY OF MANCHESTER.

Applying the proportional hazard premium calculation principle

Mathematical Preliminaries for Microeconomics: Exercises

Functions. Paul Schrimpf. October 9, UBC Economics 526. Functions. Paul Schrimpf. Definition and examples. Special types of functions

MONOTONICITY OF RATIOS INVOLVING INCOMPLETE GAMMA FUNCTIONS WITH ACTUARIAL APPLICATIONS

If g is also continuous and strictly increasing on J, we may apply the strictly increasing inverse function g 1 to this inequality to get

Severity Models - Special Families of Distributions

Chapter 13. Convex and Concave. Josef Leydold Mathematical Methods WS 2018/19 13 Convex and Concave 1 / 44

Corrections to Theory of Asset Pricing (2008), Pearson, Boston, MA

Simulating Exchangeable Multivariate Archimedean Copulas and its Applications. Authors: Florence Wu Emiliano A. Valdez Michael Sherris

Probability Transforms with Elliptical Generators

Math 576: Quantitative Risk Management

Modelling the risk process

Risk Aggregation with Dependence Uncertainty

Lecture 34: Recall Defn: The n-th Taylor polynomial for a function f at a is: n f j (a) j! + f n (a)

Nonlife Actuarial Models. Chapter 4 Risk Measures

Generalized quantiles as risk measures

Standard Error of Technical Cost Incorporating Parameter Uncertainty

Three hours. To be supplied by the Examinations Office: Mathematical Formula Tables and Statistical Tables THE UNIVERSITY OF MANCHESTER.

Monotone Function. Function f is called monotonically increasing, if. x 1 x 2 f (x 1 ) f (x 2 ) x 1 < x 2 f (x 1 ) < f (x 2 ) x 1 x 2

Mean-Scale Indifference Curves. For gambles with small variance, a second order Taylor s series expansion

Optimal Reinsurance Strategy with Bivariate Pareto Risks

Introduction and Overview STAT 421, SP Course Instructor

Pedantic Notes on the Risk Premium and Risk Aversion

Problem Sheet 1. You may assume that both F and F are σ-fields. (a) Show that F F is not a σ-field. (b) Let X : Ω R be defined by 1 if n = 1

1. Let X and Y be independent exponential random variables with rate α. Find the densities of the random variables X 3, X Y, min(x, Y 3 )

Exam C Solutions Spring 2005

Distributions of Functions of Random Variables. 5.1 Functions of One Random Variable

Notes on the Risk Premium and Risk Aversion

Claims Reserving under Solvency II

ST5215: Advanced Statistical Theory

Chapter 3: Unbiased Estimation Lecture 22: UMVUE and the method of using a sufficient and complete statistic

BMIR Lecture Series on Probability and Statistics Fall 2015 Discrete RVs

Continuous Random Variables and Continuous Distributions

Risk Aggregation. Paul Embrechts. Department of Mathematics, ETH Zurich Senior SFI Professor.

On the Bennett-Hoeffding inequality

,... We would like to compare this with the sequence y n = 1 n

3 Continuous Random Variables

1 Presessional Probability

On the Bennett-Hoeffding inequality

100 if α=red 0 if α=red f A,r = f A,b =

RMSC 2001 Introduction to Risk Management

Math Camp II. Calculus. Yiqing Xu. August 27, 2014 MIT

Econ 325: Introduction to Empirical Economics

Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus

Problem List MATH 5143 Fall, 2013

Lecture Notes on Risk Theory

Lecture 23: UMPU tests in exponential families

ON APPROXIMATIONS IN LIMITED FLUCTUATION CREDIBILITY THEORY VINCENT GOULET. Abstract

Expectation Maximization

The Cake-Eating problem: Non-linear sharing rules

Generalized quantiles as risk measures

Upper and lower bounds for ruin probability

1/37. Convexity theory. Victor Kitov

RMSC 2001 Introduction to Risk Management

Limiting Distributions

Module 3. Function of a Random Variable and its distribution

S n = x + X 1 + X X n.

Chapter 3: Random Variables 1

CLASSICAL PROBABILITY MODES OF CONVERGENCE AND INEQUALITIES

Lecture 1: August 28

Chapter 3: Random Variables 1

Scenario Aggregation

Von Neumann Morgenstern Expected Utility. I. Introduction, Definitions, and Applications. Decision Theory Spring 2014

Financial Econometrics and Quantitative Risk Managenent Return Properties

Preference and Utility

Transitive Regret over Statistically Independent Lotteries

University Of Calgary Department of Mathematics and Statistics

Polynomial Rings. (Last Updated: December 8, 2017)

FINAL EXAM: Monday 8-10am

Lecture 2: Repetition of probability theory and statistics

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Advanced Herd Management Probabilities and distributions

Part IA Probability. Theorems. Based on lectures by R. Weber Notes taken by Dexter Chua. Lent 2015

Preliminary Statistics. Lecture 3: Probability Models and Distributions

Example continued. Math 425 Intro to Probability Lecture 37. Example continued. Example

ECON4510 Finance Theory Lecture 2

Limiting Distributions

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Notes for lectures 3. Risk Aversion

HW1 solutions. 1. α Ef(x) β, where Ef(x) is the expected value of f(x), i.e., Ef(x) = n. i=1 p if(a i ). (The function f : R R is given.

Math 362, Problem set 1

Extreme Negative Dependence and Risk Aggregation

STAT Chapter 5 Continuous Distributions

Higher monotonicity properties of q gamma and q-psi functions

Introduction to Rare Event Simulation

Corollary 1.1 (Chebyshev's Inequality). Let Y be a random variable with finite mean μ and variance ff 2. Then for all ffi>0 P [ jy μj ffiff]» 1 ffi 2

2. Variance and Higher Moments

ECEN 5612, Fall 2007 Noise and Random Processes Prof. Timothy X Brown NAME: CUID:

Lecture 22: Variance and Covariance

Errata for the ASM Study Manual for Exam P, Fourth Edition By Dr. Krzysztof M. Ostaszewski, FSA, CFA, MAAA

DELTA METHOD and RESERVING

CIMPA SCHOOL, 2007 Jump Processes and Applications to Finance Monique Jeanblanc

Transcription:

ETH Zürich, D-MATH HS 08 Prof. Dr. Mario V. Wüthrich Coordinator Andrea Gabrielli Non-Life Insurance: Mathematics and Statistics Solution sheet 9 Solution 9. Utility Indifference Price (a) Suppose that there exist two utility indifference prices π = π (u, S, c 0 ) and π = π (u, S, c 0 ) with π π. By definition of a utility indifference price, we have Eu(c 0 + π S)] = u(c 0 ) = Eu(c 0 + π S)]. () Without loss of generality, we assume that π < π. Then, we have c 0 + π S < c 0 + π S a.s., which implies u(c 0 + π S) < u(c 0 + π S) since u is a utility function and, thus, strictly increasing by definition. Finally, by taking the expectation, we get Eu(c 0 + π S)] < Eu(c 0 + π S)], which is a contradiction to (). We conclude that if the utility indifference price π exists, then it is unique. Moreover, being a risk-averse utility function, u is strictly concave by definition. Hence, we can apply Jensen s inequality to get a.s., u(c 0 ) = Eu(c 0 + π S)] < u(ec 0 + π S]) = u(c 0 + π ES]). Note that we used that S is non-deterministic and, thus, Jensen s inequality is strict. Since u is strictly increasing, this implies π ES] > 0, i.e. π > ES]. (b) Note that E Y () ] = γ c = 0 0.0 = 000 and that ] E Y () = 0.005 = 00. Since S and S both have a compound Poisson distribution, Proposition. of the lecture notes gives and We conclude that ES ] = λ v E ES ] = λ v E Y () Y () ] = 000 000 = 000 000 ] = 0 000 00 = 00 000. 0 ES] = ES + S ] = ES ] + ES ] = 00 000. (c) The utility indifference price π = π(u, S, c 0 ) is defined through the equation u(c 0 ) = Eu(c 0 + π S)]. Updated: November 0, 08 / 8

HS 08 Solution sheet 9 Using that in this exercise the utility function u is given by for all x R, with α =.5 0 6, we get u(x) = exp { αx}, α u(c 0 ) = Eu(c 0 + π S)] α exp { αc 0} = E ] α exp { α(c 0 + π S)} exp { αc 0 } = E exp { α(c 0 + π S)}] exp {απ} = E exp {αs}] π = log E exp {αs}]. α Note that we can write S = S + S and use the independence of S and S to get π = α log E exp {α(s + S )}] = α log (E exp {αs }] E exp {αs }]) = α (log E exp {αs }] + log E exp {αs }]) = α log M S (α) + log M S (α)], where M S and M S denote the moment generating functions of S and S, respectively. Moreover, since S and S both have a compound Poisson distribution, Proposition. of the lecture notes gives where M Y () π = α and M Y () (λ v M Y () ] (α) + λ v M Y () ]) (α), denote the moment generating functions of Y () and Y (), respectively. Using that Y () Γ(γ = 0, c = 0.0) and that Y () expo(0.005), we get and ( ) γ ( c 0.0 M () Y (α) = = c α 0.0.5 0 6 M () Y (α) = 0.005 0.005 α = 0.005 0.005.5 0 6. In particular, since α < c and α < 0.005, both M () Y (α) and M () Y (α) and thus also M S (α) and M S (α) exist. Inserting all the numerical values, we find the utility indifference price π = 3 06 = 03 3. Note that we have ( 000 π ES] ES] ) 0 ( ) 0 0.0 0.0.5 0 6 ] + 0 0 000 = 03 3 00 000 00 000 = 3 3 00 000 0.46%. 0.005 0.005.5 0 6 Thus, the loading π ES] is given by approximately 0.46% of the pure risk premium. ] ) Updated: November 0, 08 / 8

HS 08 Solution sheet 9 (d) The moment generating function M X of X N (µ, ) with µ R and > 0 is given by M X (r) = exp {rµ + r }, for all r R. Hence, if we assume Gaussian distributions for S and S, then we get π = α log M S (α) + log M S (α)] = ) (αes ] + α α Var(S ) + αes ] + α Var(S ) = ES ] + ES ] + α Var(S ) + Var(S )] = ES] + α Var(S), where in the last equation we used that S and S are independent. We see that in this case the utility indifference price is given according to a variance loading principle. Since here we assume Gaussian distributions for S and S with the same corresponding first two moments as in the compound Poisson case in part (c), in order to calculate Var(S ) and Var(S ), we again assume that S and S have compound Poisson distributions. Note that ( ) ] E Y () γ(γ + ) 0 = c = 0.0 = 4 00 000, and that E ( ) ] Y () = 0.005 = 80 000. Then, Proposition. of the lecture notes gives ( ) ] Var(S ) = λ v E Y () = 000 4 00 000 = 4 00 000 000 and Var(S ) = λ v E ( ) ] Y () = 0 000 80 000 = 80 000 000, 0 which leads to Var(S) = Var(S + S ) = Var(S ) + Var(S ) = 4 80 000 000. We conclude that the utility indifference price is given by Note that we have π = ES] + α.5 0 6 Var(S) = 00 000 + 4 80 000 000 = 03 0. π ES] ES] = 03 0 00 000 00 000 = 3 0 00 000 0.46%. Thus, as in part (c), the loading π ES] is given by approximately 0.46% of the pure risk premium. The reason why we get the same results in (c) and (d) is the Central Limit Theorem. In particular, neither the gamma distribution nor the exponential distribution are heavy-tailed distributions. Moreover, the skewness ς S of S and also the skewness ς S of S are rather small (ς S 0.034 and ς S 0.067). Thus, λ v = λ v = 000 are large enough for the normal approximations to be valid approximations for the compound Poisson distributions. Updated: November 0, 08 3 / 8

HS 08 Solution sheet 9 Solution 9. Value-at-Risk and Expected Shortfall (a) Since S LN(µ, ) with µ = 0 and = 0.05, we have } ES] = exp {µ + 488 87 64. Let z denote the VaR of S ES] at security level q = 99.5%. Then, since the distribution function of a lognormal distribution is continuous and strictly increasing, z is defined via the equation PS ES] z] = q. By writing Φ for the distribution function of a standard Gaussian distribution, we can calculate z as follows PS ES] z] = q PS z + ES]] = q ] log S µ log(z + ES]) µ P = q ] log(z + ES]) µ Φ = q log(z + ES]) = µ + Φ ( q) For q = 99.5%, we have Φ ( q).576. Thus, we get In particular, π CoC is then given by Note that we have z = exp { µ + Φ ( q) } ES] ( z = exp{µ} exp { Φ ( q) } { }) exp. z 76 99 86. π CoC = ES] + r CoC z 488 87 64 + 0.06 76 99 86 499 395 57. π CoC ES] ES] 499 395 57 488 87 64 488 87 64 = 0 577 957 488 87 64.64%. Thus, the loading π CoC ES] is given by approximately.64% of the pure risk premium. (b) For all u (0, ), let VaR u and ES u denote the VaR risk measure and the expected shortfall risk measure, respectively, at security level u. Note that actually in part (a) we found that and that by a similar computation we get for all u (0, ). In particular, we have VaR u (S ES]) = exp { µ + Φ (u) } ES], VaR u (S) = exp { µ + Φ (u) }, VaR u (S ES]) + ES] = VaR u (S), Updated: November 0, 08 4 / 8

HS 08 Solution sheet 9 for all u (0, ). Since the distribution function of S is continuous and strictly increasing, according to Example 6.6 of the lecture notes, we have ES q (S ES]) = E S ES] S ES] VaR q (S ES])] = E S ES] S VaR q (S)] = E S S VaR q (S)] ES] = ES q (S) ES]. By definition of the mean excess function e S ( ) of S, we have ES q (S) = E S VaR q (S) S VaR q (S)]+VaR q (S) = e S VaR q (S)]+VaR q (S). Moreover, according to the formula given in Chapter 3..3 of the lecture notes, the mean excess function e S VaR q (S)] above level VaR q (S) for the log-normal distribution S is given by ] e S VaR q (S)] = ES] Φ log VaR q(s) µ ] VaR q (S). log VaR q(s) µ Φ Using the formula calculated above for VaR u (S) with u = q, we get ] ES q (S) = ES] Φ log VaR q(s) µ ] log VaR q(s) µ Φ ] = ES] Φ µ+ Φ ( q) µ ] Φ µ+ Φ ( q) µ ( Φ Φ ( q) ] ) = ES] Φ Φ ( q)] = ES] q ( Φ Φ ( q) ]). In particular, we have found For q = 99% we get ES q (S ES]) = q ES] ( Φ Φ ( q) ]) ES] Finally, π CoC is then given by = q ES] ( q Φ Φ ( q) ]) = { } q exp µ + ( q Φ Φ ( q) ]). ES 99% (S ES]) 84 9 56. π CoC = ES] + r CoC ES 99% (S ES]) 488 87 64 + 0.06 84 9 56 499 864 769. Note that we have π CoC ES] ES] 499 864 769 488 87 64 488 87 64 = 047 55 488 87 64.6%. Thus, the loading π CoC ES] is given by approximately.6% of the pure risk premium. In particular, the cost-of-capital price in this example is higher using the expected shortfall risk measure at security level 99% than using the VaR risk measure at security level 99.5%. Updated: November 0, 08 5 / 8

HS 08 Solution sheet 9 (c) In parts (a) and (b) we found that VaR 99.5% (S ES]) < ES 99% (S ES]). Let q = 99%. Now the goal is to find u 0, ] such that which is equivalent to From part (b) we know that for all u (0, ), and that VaR u (S ES]) = ES q (S ES]), VaR u (S) = ES q (S). VaR u (S) = exp { µ + Φ (u) }, ES q (S) = q ES] ( Φ Φ ( q) ]). Hence, we can solve for u to get u = Φ log q ES] ( Φ Φ ( q) ])] µ 99.6%. We conclude that in this example the cost-of-capital price using the VaR risk measure at security level 99.6% is approximately equal to the cost-of-capital price using the expected shortfall risk measure at security level 99%. (d) Since S LN(µ, ) with µ = 0 and = 0.05 and U and V are assumed to be independent, we have U N (µ, ), V N (µ, ) and U + V N (µ, ). Let X N ( µ, ) for some µ R and > 0. Then, VaR q (X) can be calculated as X µ P X VaR q (X)] = q P VaR ] q(x) µ = q ] VaR q (X) µ Φ = q This implies that VaR q (X) = µ + Φ ( q). VaR q (U) + VaR q (V ) = µ + Φ ( q) + µ + Φ ( q) = µ + Φ ( q) and that Since VaR q (U + V ) = µ + Φ ( q). VaR q (U + V ) > VaR q (U) + VaR q (V ) Φ ( q) > Φ ( q) one can see that in this example for all q ( 0, ), and that Φ ( q) < 0, VaR q (U + V ) > VaR q (U) + VaR q (V ), VaR q (U + V ) < VaR q (U) + VaR q (V ), for all q (, ). In particular, the assertions on the exercise sheet follow readily. Updated: November 0, 08 6 / 8

HS 08 Solution sheet 9 Solution 9.3 Esscher Premium (a) Let α (0, r 0 ) and M S and M S denote the first and second derivative of M S, respectively. According to the proof of Corollary 6.6 of the lecture notes, the Esscher premium π α can be written as π α = M S (α) M S (α). Hence, the derivative of π α can be calculated as d dα π α = d M S (α) dα M S (α) = M S (α) ( ) M M S (α) S (α) = E S exp{αs} ] ( E S exp{αs}] M S (α) M S (α) M S (α) = x ] exp{αx} df (x) x exp{αx} df (x) M S (α) M S (α) = x df α (x) x df α (x)], where we define the distribution function F α by F α (s) = M S (α) s exp{αx} df (x), for all s R. Let X be a random variable with distribution function F α. Then, we get d dα π α = x df α (x) x df α (x)] = E X ] EX] = Var(X) 0. Hence, the Esscher premium π α is always non-decreasing. Moreover, if S is non-deterministic, then also X is non-deterministic. Thus, in this case we get d dα π α = Var(X) > 0. In particular, the Esscher premium π α then is strictly increasing in α. (b) Let α (0, r 0 ). According to Corollary 6.6 of the lecture notes, the Esscher premium π α is given by π α = d dr log M S(r). r=α For small values of α, we can use a first-order Taylor approximation around 0 to get π α d ( dr log M S(r) d + α r=0 dr log M S(r) = M S (0) r=0 M S (0) + α M S (0) ] ) M M S (0) S (0) M S (0) = ES] + α ( E S ] ES] ) = ES] + αvar(s). We conclude that for small values of α, the Esscher premium π α of S is approximately equal to a premium resulting from a variance loading principle. (c) Since S CompPoi(λv, G), we can use Proposition. of the lecture notes to get log M S (r) = λv M G (r) ], where M G denotes the moment generating function of a random variable with distribution function G. Since G is the distribution function of a gamma distribution with shape parameter γ > 0 and scale parameter c > 0, we have ( ) γ c M G (r) =, c r Updated: November 0, 08 7 / 8 )

HS 08 Solution sheet 9 for all r < c. In particular, also M S (r) is defined for all r < c, which implies that the Esscher premium π α exists for all α (0, c). Now let α (0, c). Then, the Esscher premium π α can be calculated as π α = d dr log M S(r) = d ( ) γ ] c r=α dr λv = d ( c r dr λv r ) γ ] c r=α = λv γ ( r ) γ = λv γ ( ) γ+ c. c c c c α r=α Note that since c > c α and γ > 0, we have ( ) γ+ c >, c α r=α and, thus, π α = λv γ c ( ) γ+ c > λv γ c α c = ES]. Solution 9.4 Utility Indifference Price and the Uncertainty in the Number of Claims In Exercise 9. we have shown that π = π (u, S, ) c 0 = { α log E exp α S }]. From this we can calculate { }] π = λv exp α log E α Y i = λv log E exp {αy i }] = α α λv log M Y (α). We then have We define i= i= π > π M Y (α) > log M Y (α). g(x) = x and h(x) = log x. For x = we have g() = 0 = h(). Since g is linear and h is strictly concave, we get g(x) > h(x) for all x in the domain of g and h. Since for the claim sizes we assume Y > 0, P-a.s., and since α > 0, we have M Y (α) >. If follows that M Y (α) > log M Y (α) and, thus, π > π. This does not come as a surprise: in the compound Poisson model we have randomness in the number of claims and under risk aversion we do not like this uncertainty. This explains why π > π. Updated: November 0, 08 8 / 8