Moral Hazard: Part 2. April 16, 2018

Similar documents
Moral Hazard: Part 1. April 9, 2018

Microeconomic Theory (501b) Problem Set 10. Auctions and Moral Hazard Suggested Solution: Tibor Heumann

Teoria das organizações e contratos

Some Notes on Moral Hazard

Linear Contracts. Ram Singh. February 23, Department of Economics. Ram Singh (Delhi School of Economics) Moral Hazard February 23, / 22

Moral Hazard: Hidden Action

Moral Hazard: Characterization of SB

General idea. Firms can use competition between agents for. We mainly focus on incentives. 1 incentive and. 2 selection purposes 3 / 101

Hidden information. Principal s payoff: π (e) w,

Contracts in informed-principal problems with moral hazard

Optimality of Quota Contract

The Principal-Agent Problem

1 Web Appendix: Equilibrium outcome under collusion (multiple types-multiple contracts)

Moral hazard with discrete soft information

EC476 Contracts and Organizations, Part III: Lecture 2

AJAE appendix for Risk rationing and wealth effects in credit markets: Theory and implications for agriculture development

Regulation Under Asymmetric Information

Game Theory and Economics of Contracts Lecture 5 Static Single-agent Moral Hazard Model

Limited liability constraints in adverse selection and moral hazard problems

5. Relational Contracts and Career Concerns

COSTLY STATE VERIFICATION - DRAFT

Moral Hazard in Teams

ECON INFORMATION ECONOMICS. Lecture 2 February 2016 Slides based on Laffont & Martimort UiO, Spring 2016

Organization, Careers and Incentives

Full Surplus Extraction and Costless Information Revelation in Dynamic Environments. Shunya NODA (University of Tokyo)

Decision, Risk and Operations Working Papers Series

1.1 A Simple Model of Price Discrimination Full Information Benchmark: First-Best Outcome or Perfect Price

Avoiding the Cost of a Bad Hire: On the Optimality of Pay to Quit Programs

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Slides to accompany 13. Markets and Efficient Risk-Bearing: Examples and Extensions

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction

Department of Economics, University of California, Davis Ecn 200C Micro Theory Professor Giacomo Bonanno ANSWERS TO PRACTICE PROBLEMS 18

arxiv: v1 [cs.gt] 16 Feb 2012

Optimal Insurance of Search Risk

Intrinsic and Extrinsic Motivation

The Early State: Hebrew University of Jerusalem. Royal Holloway University of London

A Principal-Agent Model of Sequential Testing

Technical Appendix for: Complementary Goods: Creating, Capturing and Competing for Value

Seniority, Bailouts and Effect of Lender of the Last Resort

Economics 210B Due: September 16, Problem Set 10. s.t. k t+1 = R(k t c t ) for all t 0, and k 0 given, lim. and

Introduction: Asymmetric Information and the Coase Theorem

14.05 Lecture Notes Crises and Multiple Equilibria

x ax 1 2 bx2 a bx =0 x = a b. Hence, a consumer s willingness-to-pay as a function of liters on sale, 1 2 a 2 2b, if l> a. (1)

Minimum Wages and Excessive E ort Supply

Informed Principal in Private-Value Environments

Optimal contract under adverse selection in a moral hazard model with a risk averse agent

On the Pareto Efficiency of a Socially Optimal Mechanism for Monopoly Regulation

Weather-based Insurance Market Development: Challenges and Potential Solutions. Raushan Bokusheva

Organizational Barriers to Technology Adoption: Evidence from Soccer-Ball Producers in Pakistan

Lecture 8: Incomplete Contracts

This is designed for one 75-minute lecture using Games and Information. October 3, 2006

Lecture Notes - Dynamic Moral Hazard

The Optimal Contract under Adverse Selection in a Moral-Hazard Model with a Risk-Averse Agent

"A Theory of Financing Constraints and Firm Dynamics"

EconS Microeconomic Theory II Midterm Exam #2 - Answer Key

Prizes versus Contracts as Incentives for Innovation

Advanced Microeconomics

Econ 101A Problem Set 6 Solutions Due on Monday Dec. 9. No late Problem Sets accepted, sorry!

The Cost of a Bad Hire: On the Optimality of Pay to Quit Programs

Collusion, Delegation and Supervision with Soft Information

Microeconomics II Lecture 4: Incomplete Information Karl Wärneryd Stockholm School of Economics November 2016

Weather Derivatives-Pricing and Design Issue in India

Public Provision of Scarce Resources when Preferences are Non-Linear

Fiscal Rules and Discretion under Self-Enforcement

Optimal Contract to Induce Continued Effort

Thus far, we ve made four key assumptions that have greatly simplified our analysis:

Module 8: Multi-Agent Models of Moral Hazard

Lecture Notes - Dynamic Moral Hazard

Incentives and Income Distribution in Tenancy Relationships

Moral Hazard and Persistence

Do Shareholders Vote Strategically? Voting Behavior, Proposal Screening, and Majority Rules. Supplement

Screening. Diego Moreno Universidad Carlos III de Madrid. Diego Moreno () Screening 1 / 1

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness. On-Line Appendix

Monopoly Regulation with Non-Paying Consumers

u(c t, x t+1 ) = c α t + x α t+1

Sharing aggregate risks under moral hazard

Game Theory, Information, Incentives

1 Moral Hazard: Multiple Agents 1.1 Moral Hazard in a Team

Consumption Risksharing in Social Networks

Lecture Notes on Solving Moral-Hazard Problems Using the Dantzig-Wolfe Algorithm

Pseudo-Wealth and Consumption Fluctuations

Some Lecture Notes on Auctions

Some Lecture Notes on Auctions

Other-Regarding Preferences in Organizational Hierarchies

Some Notes on Costless Signaling Games

The Effect of Opportunity Costs on Candidate Supply

Other-Regarding Preferences in Organizational Hierarchies

Crowdsourcing contests

Interbank Lending and Systemic Risk

Moral hazard in teams

Online Appendix for Sourcing from Suppliers with Financial Constraints and Performance Risk

Moral Hazard. Felix Munoz-Garcia. Advanced Microeconomics II - Washington State University

This work is distributed as a Discussion Paper by the STANFORD INSTITUTE FOR ECONOMIC POLICY RESEARCH

Entry under an Information-Gathering Monopoly Alex Barrachina* June Abstract

The Revenue Equivalence Theorem 1

Equations and Inequalities

Inflation traps, and rules vs. discretion

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

Organization based cross-subsidization: Who must pay to incentivize managers?

An Introduction to the Theory of Mechanism Design

Financial Intermediation and the Supply of Liquidity

Transcription:

Moral Hazard: Part 2 April 16, 2018

The basic model: A is risk neutral We now turn to the problem of moral hazard (asymmetric information), where A is risk neutral. When A is risk neutral, u (t) is linear. Assume u (t) = t. Then, u 1 (ψ) = ψ. The P now has to take into account the ICC of A. He needs to make sure that A is willing to exert the high effort.

The basic model: A is risk neutral P s problem becomes: max π 1 ( S t ) + (1 π 1 ) (S t) t, t s.t. PC : π 1 t + (1 π 1 ) t ψ 0 ICC : π 1 t + (1 π 1 ) t ψ π 0 t + (1 π 0 ) t, where S = S ( q) and S = S (q). As before, we still need to make sure that P prefers A to exert the high effort level, i.e. V 1 V 0. Strategy of P: spend as little as possible to incentivize A; and ensure A with the outside option, E (U) = 0.

PC and ICC Both constraints can be made binding! First, rewrite the ICC as: π 1 t π 0 t + (1 π 1 ) t (1 π 0 ) t ψ (π 1 π 0 ) t + (1 π 1 1 + π 0 ) t ψ (π 1 π 0 ) t (π 1 π 0 ) t ψ t ψ π Assume PC is binding, i.e. E (u) = 0: π 1 t + (1 π 1 ) t ψ = 0 or t = 1 π 1 t ψ π 1 π Then, one can increase (decrease) t and correspondingly reduce (increase) t by 1 π1 π 1 until t = ψ π.

Optimal contract, with A risk neutral P optimally chooses t and t to satisfy PC and ICC. This is a system of 2 equations with 2 unknowns: π 1 t + (1 π 1 ) t ψ = 0 π 1 t + (1 π 1 ) t ψ π 0 t + (1 π 0 ) t. The solution is: t = 1 π 0 π 1 π 0 ψ (Reward); t = π 0 π 1 π 0 ψ (Punishment). P is able to first best incentivize A! P incurs no extra cost to induce A to exert the high effort: the expected transfer to P is π 1 t + (1 π 1 ) t = ψ, i.e. exactly covering the disutility of effort of A. A s expected gain from exerting effort is t π = ψ, i.e. exactly compensating for the disutility of effort.

A risk neutral: discussion Even with moral hazard, when A is risk neutral it is possible to induce the first best effort: if effort is optimal under complete information, P can incentivize effort at no extra cost; if effort is not optimal, P can just give no transfers. No moral hazard related issues emerge for P: optimal effort can be decentralized. Here, delegating optimal effort is costless. However, now t t : A is not perfectly insured against risk! Luckily, A is risk neutral...

P s final choice As before, we still need to discuss whether P wants to induce A to exert high effort or not. As in the complete information case, V 1 V 0 iff: π S u 1 (ψ) = ψ.

A risk neutral: a sell-off implementation Up to now, we assumed ICC is met with equality: A is indifferent between exerting high or low effort. Yet, one can implement first best effort also by making A strictly prefer exerting effort. Consider the transfers: t = S T and t = S T, where T is an upfront payment made by A before output realizes. These transfers strictly satisfy ICC since: π ( t t ) = π S > ψ, provided exerting effort is optimal. Note that T is P s ex-ante expected payoff: π 1 S + (1 π1 ) S ψ and, also, the ex-ante payment from A to P. In fact, P is selling off her property rights over production to A.

Extention: Limited liability The first best implementation requires a punishment (negative transfer t < 0) in the bad state of the world. The availability of punishment may not be taken for granted. Limited liability is the condition by which shareholders are legally responsible for the debts of a company only to the extent of the nominal value of their shares. In our model, limited liability takes the form of two additional inequality constraints: t l, t l, where l 0 captures the liability constraint. If l is large, nothing happens and the first best contract may still be feasible, i.e. if t = π0 π 1 π 0 ψ l. If l is sufficiently small, the first best contract may not be feasible, i.e. t < l.

Extention: limited liability Assume t < l, i.e. l < π0 π 1 π 0 ψ and our first best contract is not feasible. The constraints are now: PC : π 1 t + (1 π 1 ) t ψ 0 ICC : π 1 t + (1 π 1 ) t ψ π 0 t + (1 π 0 ) t LLC : t l LCC : t l. Assume optimal mechanism is of the reward/punishment type. Then: LCC implies LLC; and PC cannot be binding. In fact, LCC and ICC are now the only relevant and binding constraints: t SB = l; and t SB = l + ψ π.

Extention: limited liability We next show that the other constraints hold: LLC: t SB = l + ψ l. π PC: when l π 0 ψ, π π 1 t SB + (1 π 1) t SB ψ = l + π 1 ψ π 1 ψ π 0 ψ > 0 π π π A now gets a positive liability rent. Mechanism: P is here limited in punishment in the bad state of the world; without enough punishment capacity, the only way to induce high effort of A is to increase the reward in the good state liability rent!

Extension: limited liability l = 0 At the extreme scenario for no punishment possibilities, i.e. l = 0, the indirect utilities of P are as follows: V 1 = π 1 S + (1 π1 ) S π 1 π ψ; V 0 = π 0 S + (1 π0 ) S. Thus, the optimal effort inducing choice depends on V 1 V 0, which requires: π S }{{} expected gain of effort π 1 π ψ = ψ }{{}}{{} FB cost of effort expected cost of effort + π 0 π ψ }{{} liability rent

Example: agriculture in developing countries Consider an agriculture-based economy A Landlord owns the land, which is farmered by risk-neutral peasants By exerting effort, the farmer increases the probability of high output: q {q, q}; e = {0, 1}; Pr ( q = q e = 1 ) = π1 > π 0 = Pr ( q = q e = 0 ). Moreover, assume that high effort is socially optimal with complete information, i.e. π q ψ. Consider different contract arrangements: which one is optimal? when? why? SB contract (non-linear contract) rental contract: the landlord rents the land to the farmer Sharecropping: the landlord and the farmer share the output of the land (common in some European regions since middle-age, in Africa since colonial age, in US South after abolition of slavery)

Agriculture: non-linear contract The problem of P is: max π 1 ( q t) + (1 π 1 ) (q t) t, t s.t. PC : π 1 t + (1 π 1 ) t ψ 0 ICC : π 1 t + (1 π 1 ) t ψ π 0 t + (1 π 0 ) t Solving for the constraints gives: t = 1 π 0 π ψ; and t = π 0 π ψ With LLC, i.e. the farmer is extremely poor (hand-to-mouth), t, t 0. Then, t LL = ψ π ; and tll = 0

Agriculture: rental contract The farmer gives a rent R to the landlord and keeps all the output. P solves: max R R s.t. PC : π 1 q + (1 π 1 ) q ψ R 0 ICC : π 1 q + (1 π 1 ) q ψ R π 0 q + (1 π 0 ) q R ICC always holds since π q ψ. Also, R cancels out of ICC. R SB emerges from PC being binding: R SB = π 1 q + (1 π 1 ) q ψ. Assume limited liability, i.e. R q and the farmer cannot pay more than the product of land. Then, LLC is binding, while PC is not. PC not binding comes from: R SB = π 1 q + (1 π 1 ) q ψ π 0 q + (1 π 0 ) q > q. R LL = q.

Agriculture: sharecropping contract Here, the farmer keeps a share α (0, 1) of output, while the landlord gets the rest. The problem of P is now: max α (1 α) [π 1 q + (1 π 1 ) q] s.t. PC : απ 1 q + α (1 π 1 ) q ψ 0 ICC : απ 1 q + α (1 π 1 ) q ψ απ 0 q + α (1 π 0 ) q ICC implies PC: the right hand side of ICC is positive! Then, ICC must be binding: α SB = ψ π q What with limited liability? Never an issue: the farmer always gets a reward.

Agriculture: optimal contract without LL Compute the indirect utility of the landlord corresponding to each contract: EV non linear = π 1 q + (1 π 1) q ψ; EV Rental = π 1 q + (1 π 1) q ψ; and EV Sharecropping = π 1 q + (1 π 1) q ψ (π1 q + (1 π1) q). π q All contracts incentivize high effort Then: EV non linear = EV Rental > EV Sharecropping

Agriculture: optimal contract with LL Compute the indirect utility of the landlord corresponding to each contract: EV non linear,ll = π 1 q + (1 π 1) q π 1 π ψ; EV Rental,LL = q; and EV Sharecropping,LL = π 1 q + (1 π 1) q ψ (π1 q + (1 π1) q). π q All contracts incentivize high effort. Then: EV non linear,ll > EV Rental,LL EV non linear > EV Sharecropping,LL