Decentralisation and its efficiency implications in suburban public transport

Similar documents
Towards a Co-ordinated Planning of Infrastructure and Urbanization

Lecture 19: Common property resources

Subject: Note on spatial issues in Urban South Africa From: Alain Bertaud Date: Oct 7, A. Spatial issues

MODELING CITIES WITH CONGESTION AND AGGLOMERATION EXTERNALITIES: THE EFFICIENCY OF CONGESTION TOLLS, LABOR SUBSIDIES, AND URBAN GROWTH BOUNDARIES

Land Use Modeling at ABAG. Mike Reilly October 3, 2011

Leveraging Urban Mobility Strategies to Improve Accessibility and Productivity of Cities

Urban Economics City Size

The Tyndall Cities Integrated Assessment Framework

Race to the Top in Traffic Calming i

Foreword. Vision and Strategy

SPIMA Spatial dynamics and strategic planning in metropolitan areas

CIV3703 Transport Engineering. Module 2 Transport Modelling

The Design of a University System

Departure time choice equilibrium problem with partial implementation of congestion pricing

Forecasts from the Strategy Planning Model

Can Public Transport Infrastructure Relieve Spatial Mismatch?

Beginning to Enjoy the Outside View A Glance at Transit Forecasting Uncertainty & Accuracy Using the Transit Forecasting Accuracy Database

A New Central Station for a UnifiedCity: Predicting Impact on Property Prices for Urban Railway Network Extensions in Berlin

Congestion Externality and Autonomous Vehicles

Traffic Demand Forecast

Evidence on the linkages between productivity, agglomeration economies, and transport

Economic Benefit Study on Value of Spatial Information Australian Experience

THE LEGACY OF DUBLIN S HOUSING BOOM AND THE IMPACT ON COMMUTING

A MULTI-MODAL APPROACH TO SUSTAINABLE ACCESSIBILITY: A CASE STUDY FOR THE CITY OF GALWAY, IRELAND

CONGESTION TOLLING AND URBAN SPATIAL STRUCTURE. Richard Arnott. Department of Economics. Boston College. Chestnut Hill, MA U.S.A.

APPENDIX Should the Private Sector Provide Public Capital?

accessibility accessibility by-pass bid-rent curve bridging point administrative centre How easy or difficult a place is to reach.

Planning for Economic and Job Growth

Tackling urban sprawl: towards a compact model of cities? David Ludlow University of the West of England (UWE) 19 June 2014

Analysis of travel-to-work patterns and the identification and classification of REDZs

INTRODUCTION TO TRANSPORTATION SYSTEMS

Typical information required from the data collection can be grouped into four categories, enumerated as below.

Volume Author/Editor: Gregory K. Ingram, John F. Kain, and J. Royce Ginn. Volume URL:

Capital, Institutions and Urban Growth Systems

Committee Meeting November 6, 2018

ANNEX 3 SOFIA S DEVELOPMENT AND SPATIAL STRUCTURE. 1. Introduction

National Spatial Development Perspective (NSDP) Policy Coordination and Advisory Service

Document de treball de l IEB 2010/1

Assessing the Employment Agglomeration and Social Accessibility Impacts of High Speed Rail in Eastern Australia: Sydney-Canberra-Melbourne Corridor

Changes in Transportation Infrastructure and Commuting Patterns in U.S. Metropolitan Areas,

Thilo Becker

Connectivity. RTPI Scotland Annual Conference Edinburgh, 2nd October 2018

Chapter 4. Explanation of the Model. Satoru Kumagai Inter-disciplinary Studies, IDE-JETRO, Japan

I. M. Schoeman North West University, South Africa. Abstract

Thoughts toward autonomous land development. Introduction

Do new transit lines necessarily improve user cost in the transit system? DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES DPS15.15

Low Density Areas : Places of Opportunity. Enrique Garcilazo, OECD Directorate for Public Governance and Territorial Development

6 th GLOBAL SUMMIT ON URBAN TOURISM 4 6 December 2017, Kuala Lumpur (Malaysia)

Exemplar for Internal Achievement Standard. Geography Level 2

Estimating Transportation Demand, Part 2

First-Best Dynamic Assignment of Commuters with Endogenous Heterogeneities in a Corridor Network

Vincent Goodstadt. Head of European Affairs METREX European Network

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Land Use Planning and Agriculture: Austrian Experiences and Challenges I

Data Collection. Lecture Notes in Transportation Systems Engineering. Prof. Tom V. Mathew. 1 Overview 1

Simulating Mobility in Cities: A System Dynamics Approach to Explore Feedback Structures in Transportation Modelling

ACCESSIBILITY TO SERVICES IN REGIONS AND CITIES: MEASURES AND POLICIES NOTE FOR THE WPTI WORKSHOP, 18 JUNE 2013

PARTE SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION

Returns to Scale in Networks. Marvin Kraus * June Keywords: Networks, congestion, returns to scale, congestion pricing

The National Spatial Strategy

High speed network in Hauts-de-France Region. Värnamo, 17 th May 2018

Opportunities and challenges of HCMC in the process of development

Measuring connectivity in London

CORRIDORS OF FREEDOM Access Management (Ability) Herman Pienaar: Director City Transformation and Spatial Planning

Difference in regional productivity and unbalance in regional growth

Trade policy III: Export subsidies

LOCATIONAL PREFERENCES OF FDI FIRMS IN TURKEY

The socio-economic effects of the metro line U3 in Vienna (Austria) evaluated under the European research project TranSEcon (

Secondary Towns and Poverty Reduction: Refocusing the Urbanization Agenda

Parking Space Assignment Problem: A Matching Mechanism Design Approach

Data driven approaches to Urban Planning Experience from Derry/Londonderry

BROOKINGS May

Commuting, public transport investments and gentrification

Note on Transportation and Urban Spatial Structure

Urban Growth and Transportation Development Patterns for China s Urban Transition

Brian J. Morton Center for Urban and Regional Studies University of North Carolina - Chapel Hill June 8, 2010

Experience and perspectives of using EU funds and other funding for the implementation of district renovation projects

GIS Analysis of Crenshaw/LAX Line

COSTA RICA Limon City-Port Project

The Model Research of Urban Land Planning and Traffic Integration. Lang Wang

Economics 312: Urban Land Economics University of Victoria Midterm Examination #1 VERSION 1 SOLUTIONS Spring 2018 Instructor: Martin Farnham

Modern Urban and Regional Economics

MODULE 1 INTRODUCING THE TOWNSHIP RENEWAL CHALLENGE

A Simplified Travel Demand Modeling Framework: in the Context of a Developing Country City

Putting the U.S. Geospatial Services Industry On the Map

The 3V Approach. Transforming the Urban Space through Transit Oriented Development. Gerald Ollivier Transport Cluster Leader World Bank Hub Singapore

Problems In Large Cities

The TransPacific agreement A good thing for VietNam?

Metrolinx Transit Accessibility/Connectivity Toolkit

c. What is the most distinctive above ground result of high land costs and intensive land use? i. Describe the vertical geography of a skyscraper?

FOURTH URBAN RESEARCH SYMPOSIUM URBAN LAND USE AND LAND MARKETS. WASHINGTON D.C., U.S.A. May 2007

November 29, World Urban Forum 6. Prosperity of Cities: Balancing Ecology, Economy and Equity. Concept Note

Key Issue 1: Why Do Services Cluster Downtown?

Behavioural Analysis of Out Going Trip Makers of Sabarkantha Region, Gujarat, India

Employment Decentralization and Commuting in U.S. Metropolitan Areas. Symposium on the Work of Leon Moses

Location theory and clusters. Dr. Hans Koster Assistant professor

Abstract. 1 Introduction

Urbanization and spatial policies. June 2006 Kyung-Hwan Kim

Communities, Competition, Spillovers and Open. Space 1

SPIMA Spatial dynamics and strategic planning in metropolitan areas

Transcription:

Decentralisation and its efficiency implications in suburban public transport Daniel Hörcher 1, Woubit Seifu 2, Bruno De Borger 2, and Daniel J. Graham 1 1 Imperial College London. South Kensington Campus, SW7 2AZ London, United Kingdom 2 University of Antwerp. Stadscampus Prinsstraat 13., 2000 Antwerpen, Belgium Extended abstract submitted for the ITEA Annual Conference, 2018 15 February 2018 Introduction Suburban public transport services are used predominantly by regular commuters living in low-density residential areas outside of the political boundaries of large cities. The provision of such services is often perceived as a substitute for car commuting when major road links heading to the centre of employment areas are heavily congested, especially in the morning peak. One may distinguish four beneficiaries of suburban public transport provision: (1) suburban commuters who are either the actual users of the service, or drivers who enjoy lower travel time costs in the presence of substituting public transport capacity, (2) urban residents who experience less car externalities if some suburban commuters are diverted to alternative modes, (3) firms and workers who may benefit from increased agglomeration and productivity, and (4) the public transport provider as an individual economic agent. As the above listed beneficiaries usually belong to different political jurisdictions, the quality and pricing of suburban public transport supply may depend on what level of government is responsible for service provision. In this research we investigate four service provision regimes: 1. Centralised decision making, i.e. the economic objective is to maximise aggregate social welfare, including both the urban and suburban population. 2. Decentralised decision making by an urban government. 3. Decentralised decision making by a suburban government. 4. Profit maximising (monopolistic) service provision. Corresponding author Electronic address: d.horcher@imperial.ac.uk 1

The research question here is essentially how the choice between these institutional regimes affects service quality and pricing of suburban public transport, and the economic well-being of user groups and society as a whole. Practical experience shows that the ownership structure of suburban public transport is by far not consistent across Europe; examples can be found for all four regimes enlisted above. Moreover, the ownership of commuter services may even change over time. The direct motivation behind this research includes recent developments in London (UK) and Budapest (Hungary). In the former case Transport for London (TfL), the public transport agency of the British capital has just taken over a large portion of its suburban rail network operated as part of the national rail franchise framework up until now. Plans include further expansion by TfL in London s rail market. In case of the Hungarian capital, recent policy interventions were even more drastic: the entire suburban rail network of the city of 2 million inhabitants has been overtaken by the state railway operator (MÁV) from the incumbent operator fully owned by the local government of Budapest. Note that this intervention points towards centralisation as opposed to what happened in London. In both cities the changes in ownership structure were intensively debated in the local media and caused severe debates among transport professionals as well. This research is built on a number of earlier contributions on multimodal interaction, including Arnott and Yan (2000), Pels and Verhoef (2007) and Parry and Small (2009). The direct predecessors of this paper, such as Borck and Wrede (2008), De Borger et al. (2005), Proost and Sen (2006) and De Borger and Proost (2016), modelled public transport provision at different political levels of decision making without uncovering all relevant features of suburban public transport. Modelling framework This paper assesses the decentralization of public transport provision and pricing in a tworegion federation, a city and suburb. We develop a simplified model where traffic originates from the suburb (separate administrative jurisdictions from the city) and the city and travels to the central business district (CBD) located within the city. CBD CITY Origin 2 road l 2 l 1 SUBURB Dest. rail Origin 1 Figure 1: Network layout 2

While the city gains from incoming traffic in terms of employment, it also suffers from transport-related externalities. That is, private car users impose externalities (e.g. congestion, pollution, accident risk, parking.) on city residents. Suburban commuters can choose between two modes of transportation, private car and public transport, while local commuters within the city only travel via car. In addition, the road within the city s jurisdiction is subject to congestion. The topology of the overall network is reflected in figure 1. Residents of both regions commute to the CBD which is located in the city. There are two modes of transportation, car and public transport. Given that the city network is used by local traffic as well as drivers from the suburb, we assume that the city network is subjected to congestion. As the mode choice of suburban commuters is endogenous, the price and quality of suburban public transport services may affect the magnitude of external costs imposed on city residents. We start with the case where there is no congestion toll. First, we study the outcomes when a federal government, who takes into account society s welfare, decides on the optimal fare and supply of public transport. This serves as a benchmark. Second, we delve into the decentralization of public transport supply and pricing. Under decentralisation, we analyse the outcomes when the city and suburb are given the authority to decide on the optimal pricing and provision of public transport. In addition, we will also assess the outcomes when a profit-maximising private operator supplies public transport. This allows us to evaluate whether decentralization or privatization makes the society better off. Preliminary insights Preliminary numerical analyses have been conducted with the following specification. For the sake of simplicity we assume inelastic demand, N L and N S representing the number of local (urban) and suburban users, respectively. The values may be considered as hourly flows. User costs on the rail link (c r ) are specified as ( c r = v w 0.5F 1 + vt r 1 + ϕ q ) r, (1) F S where the two additive components are the cost of waiting and in-vehicle travelling, respectively, the latter being multiplied by a crowding dependent factor. Notation: v w and v are the value waiting and in-vehicle travel time, t r is the exogenous train running time, and q r (F S) 1 denotes the occupancy rate. F and S are the two capacity variables, frequency and vehicle size, set by the public transport operator. Road user costs on link l comes as ( c l = vt 0 l 1 + α q ) l, (2) K l in which t 0 l is the free-flow travel time, q l represents the number of users on link l, as K denotes an abstract capacity variable which allows travel times to increase linearly in demand. On the operational and investment cost side we assume that road capacity is exogenous and rail costs are simply linear in the frequency provided, C op (F ) = zf. In this preliminary model we keep vehicle size constant. In other words, the only decision variable in this setting the 3

frequency of suburban rail services affecting operational costs on the one hand and waiting time as well as crowding costs on the other hand. Even though the number of suburban users is inelastic, their mode choice is of course endogenous. We apply the simplest Wardrop equilibrium conditions, i.e. users are distributed in such a way that user costs get equalised on the two modes (c r = c 1 + c 2 ), except if one of them is not used at all. With our basic set of parameters 1 this specification leads to zero rail market share below around 1 train per hour, and full rail market share above 8 trains per hour. For the first three ownership regimes centralised decision (3a), local urban supplier (3b), and suburban supplier (3c) one can define the following objective functions: min F C W = N L c 2 + q r c r + (N S q r )(c 1 + c 2 ) + C op (F ), (3a) min F C L = N L c 2 + C op (F ), (3b) min F C S = q r c r + (N S q r )(c 1 + c 2 ) + C op (F ). (3c) Our preliminary simulation results are summarised in Table 1. Under the current set of parameters the local (urban) government would not supply suburban public transport at all. In case of a suburban supplier service quality would remain lower than what is socially optimal. The deadweight loss of decentralised decision making is moderate under suburban supply and significant (around 20%) with no public transport option at all. Table 1: Baseline simulation results Scenario F Rail share C L C S C op C W Social 6.49 86.8% 17,149 22,811 6,487 33,473 Local 0 0 15,000 25,000 0 40,000 Suburban 4.75 72.5% 16,119 22,491 4,746 33,864 By changing certain key parameters we have identified the following interesting features of the mechanism: Local users are interested in public transport provision as we reduce K 2, i.e. the capacity of the urban road section. At K 2 = 800, for example, the optimal frequency set by a local operator is 3.19 trains per hour. Interestingly, the above mentioned capacity reduction leads to less congestion on the urban road section. As some of suburban road users switch to public transport, the user cost on the urban section drops from c 2 = 15.0 to 13.6. Similarly, a reduction in operational costs (z) also makes public transport provision 1 Preliminary analyses were conducted with the following set of baseline parameters: N l = N s = 1000 users/h; v = 20 $/h; v w = 30 $/h; z = 1000 $/h; ϕ = 0.15; α = 1; K 1 = K 2 = 1000; t 1 = t 2 = 0.25 h; t r = t 1 + t 2 = 0.5 h, and finally S = 50 m 2 4

attractive for local users. Increasing vehicle size (S) has the same effect, because the same frequency implies more modal shift due to reduced crowding costs for rail users. Capacity reduction on the suburban road section (K 2 ) does not imply higher than socially optimal frequency provision by the suburban operator. This suggests that frequency under decentralised decision making cannot exceed the social optimum, which may be explained by the importance of how operational costs as split between the two groups. Upcoming research agenda The preliminary analysis presented above is currently being extended in multiple directions, as part of an ongoing research project. The core model components include Pricing, predominantly for the public transport service, which leads to important research questions about subsidisation under decentralised service provision. Agglomeration economies (see e.g. Arnott, 2007) and labour taxation (De Borger and Van Dender, 2003) in the urban area, which may create an additional incentive for the urban government to attract suburban commuters with better public transport. Endogenous residential location, modelling the trade-off between suburban housing conditions with the cost of commuting. From a methodological point of view, our plans include a thorough analytical investigation of the economic rationale behind decentralised supply-side decisions. Later on the analytical models will be calibrated to derive meaningful conclusions for the case studies of London and Budapest. References Arnott, R. (2007), Congestion tolling with agglomeration externalities, Journal of Urban Economics 62(2), 187 203. Arnott, R. and Yan, A. (2000), The two-mode problem: Second-best pricing and capacity, Review of urban & regional development studies 12(3), 170 199. Borck, R. and Wrede, M. (2008), Commuting subsidies with two transport modes, Journal of Urban Economics 63(3), 841 848. De Borger, B. and Proost, S. (2016), The political economy of pricing and capacity decisions for congestible local public goods in a federal state, International Tax and Public Finance 23(5), 934 959. De Borger, B., Proost, S. and Van Dender, K. (2005), Congestion and tax competition in a parallel network, European Economic Review 49(8), 2013 2040. 5

De Borger, B. and Van Dender, K. (2003), Transport tax reform, commuting, and endogenous values of time, Journal of Urban Economics 53(3), 510 530. Parry, I. W. and Small, K. A. (2009), Should urban transit subsidies be reduced?, The American Economic Review 99(3), 700 724. Pels, E. and Verhoef, E. T. (2007), Infrastructure pricing and competition between modes in urban transport, Environment and Planning A 39(9), 2119 2138. Proost, S. and Sen, A. (2006), Urban transport pricing reform with two levels of government: a case study of Brussels, Transport Policy 13(2), 127 139. 6